Electrodynamical model of quasi-efficient financial market

Similar documents
Quantitative relations between risk, return and firm size

Graduate School of Information Sciences, Tohoku University Aoba-ku, Sendai , Japan

The rst 20 min in the Hong Kong stock market

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

arxiv:cond-mat/ v3 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 11 May 1998

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 4 Mar 1999

Universal Properties of Financial Markets as a Consequence of Traders Behavior: an Analytical Solution

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 22 Nov 2000 Universal Structure of the Personal Income Distribution Wataru Souma

Volatility Clustering in High-Frequency Data: A self-fulfilling prophecy? Abstract

The distribution and scaling of fluctuations for Hang Seng index in Hong Kong stock market

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 3 Jun 2003

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 1 Aug 2003

. Large-dimensional and multi-scale effects in stocks volatility m

EMH vs. Phenomenological models. Enrico Scalas (DISTA East-Piedmont University)

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 5 Mar 2001

Optimal Option Pricing via Esscher Transforms with the Meixner Process

STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF HIGH FREQUENCY FINANCIAL TIME SERIES: INDIVIDUAL AND COLLECTIVE STOCK DYNAMICS

Using Fractals to Improve Currency Risk Management Strategies

Bin Size Independence in Intra-day Seasonalities for Relative Prices

Scaling power laws in the Sao Paulo Stock Exchange. Abstract

arxiv:cond-mat/ v3 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 1 Mar 2002

LONG MEMORY IN VOLATILITY

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 7 Apr 2003

Assessing Regime Switching Equity Return Models

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 8 May 2001

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 6 Jan 2004

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.str-el] 5 Nov 2002

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 11 Jul 1999

CHAPTER-3 DETRENDED FLUCTUATION ANALYSIS OF FINANCIAL TIME SERIES

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 1 Aug 1997

Assessing Regime Switching Equity Return Models

Yale ICF Working Paper No First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, Safety First Portfolio Insurance

Forecasting Stock Index Futures Price Volatility: Linear vs. Nonlinear Models

STAT758. Final Project. Time series analysis of daily exchange rate between the British Pound and the. US dollar (GBP/USD)

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

Arbitrage and Asset Pricing

Introduction Credit risk

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

Large-scale simulations of synthetic markets

Correlation structure of extreme stock returns

Energy Price Processes

Study on Dynamic Risk Measurement Based on ARMA-GJR-AL Model

A statistical analysis of product prices in online markets

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

High-Frequency Data Analysis and Market Microstructure [Tsay (2005), chapter 5]

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios

GARCH Models for Inflation Volatility in Oman

A Scientific Classification of Volatility Models *

Agents Play Mix-game

STEX s valuation analysis, version 0.0

12. Conditional heteroscedastic models (ARCH) MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, 2006.

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Does my beta look big in this?

Walter S.A. Schwaiger. Finance. A{6020 Innsbruck, Universitatsstrae 15. phone: fax:

Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Trends in currency s return

UNIVERSITY OF. ILLINOIS LIBRARY At UrbanA-champaign BOOKSTACKS

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

MARKET DEPTH AND PRICE DYNAMICS: A NOTE

Volatility Spillovers and Causality of Carbon Emissions, Oil and Coal Spot and Futures for the EU and USA

Quantal Response Equilibrium with Non-Monotone Probabilities: A Dynamic Approach

An Introduction to Market Microstructure Invariance

Modelling the Term Structure of Hong Kong Inter-Bank Offered Rates (HIBOR)

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 27 Sep 2007

The Two Sample T-test with One Variance Unknown

Research on Modern Implications of Pairs Trading

Estimating term structure of interest rates: neural network vs one factor parametric models

Analysis of Realized Volatility for Nikkei Stock Average on the Tokyo Stock Exchange

Pricing Implied Volatility

The value of foresight

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms

On Effects of Asymmetric Information on Non-Life Insurance Prices under Competition

How High A Hedge Is High Enough? An Empirical Test of NZSE10 Futures.

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 23 Jan 2004

INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF ADVANCED RESEARCH IN ENGINEERING AND TECHNOLOGY (IJARET)

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 30 Jul 2001

John Maynard Keynes was a observer of financial markets, and a successful investor in his own right. His investing success, however, was uneven, and

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

The accuracy of the escrowed dividend model on the value of European options on a stock paying discrete dividend

The Nonlinear Real Interest Rate Growth Model: USA

Hedging Effectiveness of Currency Futures

A market risk model for asymmetric distributed series of return

THE INFORMATION CONTENT OF IMPLIED VOLATILITY IN AGRICULTURAL COMMODITY MARKETS. Pierre Giot 1

Microscopic Models of Financial Markets

Value at risk might underestimate risk when risk bites. Just bootstrap it!

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

Volatility Analysis of Nepalese Stock Market

Entropic Derivative Security Valuation

Relative Risk Perception and the Puzzle of Covered Call writing

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM

Semester / Term: -- Workload: 300 h Credit Points: 10

ARCH Models and Financial Applications

Market dynamics and stock price volatility

The Analysis of ICBC Stock Based on ARMA-GARCH Model

Mathematics in Finance

Transcription:

arxiv:cond-mat/9806138v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 10 Jun 1998 Electrodynamical model of quasi-efficient financial market Kirill N.Ilinski and Alexander S. Stepanenko School of Physics and Space Research, University of Birmingham, Edgbaston B15 2TT, Birmingham, United Kingdom August 26, 2011 Abstract The modelling of financial markets presents a problem which is both theoretically challenging and practically important. The theoretical aspects concern the issue of market efficiency which may even have political implications [1], whilst the practical side of the problem has clear relevance to portfolio management [2] and derivative pricing [3]. Up till now all market models contain smart money traders and noise traders whose joint activity constitutes the market [4, 5]. On a short time scale this traditional separation does not seem to be realistic, and is hardly acceptable since all high-frequency market participants are professional traders and cannot be separated into smart and noisy. In this paper we present a microscopic model with homogenuous quasi-rational behaviour of traders, aiming to describe short time market behaviour. To construct the model we use an analogy between screening in quantum electrodynamics and an equilibration process in a market with temporal mispricing [6, 7]. As a result, we obtain the time-dependent distribution function of the returns which is in quantitative agreement with real market data and obeys the anomalous scaling relations recently reported for both high-frequency exchange rates [8], S&P500 [9] and other stock market indices [10, 11]. E-mail: kni@th.ph.bham.ac.uk E-mail: ass@th.ph.bham.ac.uk 1

When a mispricing appears in a market, market speculators and arbitrageurs rectify the mistake by obtaining a profit from it. In the case of profitable fluctuations they move into profitable assets, leaving comparably less profitable ones. This affects prices in such a way that all assets of similar risk become equally attractive, i.e. the speculators restore the equilibrium. If this process occurs infinitely repidly, then the market corrects the mispricing instantly and current prices fully reflect all relevant information. In this case one sais that the market is efficient. However, clearly it is an idealization and does not hold for small enough times [12]. Here, we propose a microscopic model to describe the money flows, the equilibration and the corresponding statistical dynamics of prices. The general picture, sketched above, of the restoration of equilibrium in financial markets resembles screening in electrodynamics. Indeed, in the case of electrodynamics, negative charges move into the region of the positive electric field, positive charges get out of the region and thus screen the field. Comparing this with the financial market we can say that a local virtual arbitrage opportunity with a positive excess return plays a role of the positive electric field, speculators in the long position behave as negative charges, whilst the speculators in the short position behave as positive ones. Movements of positive and negative charges screen out a profitable fluctuation and restore the equilibrium so that there is no arbitrage opportunity any more, i.e. the speculators have eliminated the arbitrage opportunity. The analogy is apparently superficial, but it is not. It was shown in [6] that the analogy emerges naturally in the framework of the Gauge Theory of Arbitrage (GTA). The theory treats a calculation of net present values and asset buying and selling as a parallel transport of money in some curved space, and interpret the interest rate, exchange rates and prices of asset as proper connection components. This structure is exactly equivalent to the geometrical structure underlying the electrodynamics where the components of the vector-potential are connection components responsible for the parallel transport of the charges. The components of the corresponding curvature tensors are the electromagnetic field in the case of electrodynamics and the excess rate of return in case of GTA. The presence of uncertainty is equivalent to the introduction of noise in the electrodynamics, i.e. quantization of the theory. It allows one to map the theory of the capital market onto the theory of quantized gauge field interacting with matter (money flow) fields. The gauge transformations of the matter field correspond to a change of the 2

par value of the asset units which effect is eliminated by a gauge tuning of the prices and rates. Free quantum gauge field dynamics (in the absence of money flows) is described by a geometrical random walk for the assets prices with the log-normal probability distribution. In general case the consideration maps the capital market onto Quantum Electrodynamics where the price walks are affected by money flows. To drop technicalities and put it in simple terms, we consider a composite system of price and money flows. In this model money represents high frequency traders with a short characteristic trading time (investment horizon) (for the case of S&P500 below we use 0.5 min as the smallest horizon). The participants trade with each other and investors with longer time horizons. This system is characterized by the joint probability distribution of money allocation and price. If we neglect the money, the price obeys the geometrical random walk which is due to incoming information and longer time horizons traders. The trader s behaviour on time step at price S is described by the decision matrix of non-normalized transition probabilities [6]: π( ) = ( 1 S β( ) S β( ) 1 where the upper row corresponds to a transition to cash from cash and shares and lower row gives corresponding probabilities for a transition to shares. The parameter β is a fitting parameter playing the role of the effective temperature. At this stage different traders are independent of each other. We introduce an interaction by making hopping elements depending additionally on change in traders configuration. This interaction models the herd behaviour for large changes and mean-reversion anticipation for small changes. Each trader possesses lot of shares or the equivalent cash amount. The formulation of the model is completed by saying that the transition probability for the market is a product of the geometrical random walk weight for price and the matrices (1) for each participant. The matrix π( ) has exactly the same form as the hopping matrix for charged particles in Quantum Electrodynamics. This form can also be derived from the assumption that traders want to maximize their profit [6]. This seems to be realistic for the small times that we are interested in. It can be shown that a model with just one time horizon cannot correctly describe effects which have characteristic times of more than 5 minutes. To ) (1) 3

improve the model we have to include traders with other characteristic time horizons. It is known that there are conventional intra-day time horizons like 1, 10, 30, 60, 480 mins which, however, have certain measure of idealization. We use a continuous set of time horizons between 30 seconds and 480 minutes to describe the spread and uncertainty in the time horizons definition. It means that the model contains a set of money flows defined by the matrices (1) with the corresponding parameters and β. The suggested model thereby consists of the Fractional Market Hypothesis (FMH) [13] (which states that a stable market consists of traders with different time horizons but with identical dynamics) and the microscopical electrodynamical model for the dynamics. Hence the FMH substitutes in our approach the information cascade suggested recently to explain the scaling properties of the $/DM exchange rate [8]. The use of the FMH is not the only feature of this model which differs from the ones proposed earlier. The other feature is the homogeneity of the traders set. In earlier models traders have always been divided into smart (who trade rationally) and noisy (who follow a fad) [4, 5]. We believe that for the consideration of short times trades this differentiation is not appropriate. Indeed, all high-frequency market participants are professional traders with years of experience. Unsuccessful traders quickly leave the market and do not affect the dynamics. At the same time, each of the traders has their own view on the market and their own anticipations. That is why their particular decision can be only modeled in a probabilistic way. In this sense the traders are not strictly rational but quasi-rational and the corresponding market where the quasi-rational investors deal, can be called a quasi-effective market. Let us turn to the results. First of all, the constructed model allows us to explain quantitatively the observed high-frequency return data. In Ref [9] Figs.1,2 show the form of the distribution function for changes in the S&P500 market index, which is a price of the portfolio consisting of the main 500 stocks traded on the New York Stock Exchange. The changes in price have been normalized by the standard deviation. In the approximation that the changes are much smaller than the index itself, which is obeyed with very high accuracy, the distribution function of the normalized changes can be considered as the distribution function of the return on the portfolio, normalized by the standard deviation of the return. The return on the portfolio during the period is defined as r( ) = (S(t+ ) S(t))/S(t). In Ref [9] it was also shown that the distribution function obeys the scaling property and 4

that this property is reflected in the dependence on time of the probability to return to the origin. It was demonstrated that for a time period between 1 min and 1000 min (two trading days) the probability decrease as t α with the exponent α = 0.712±0.25 (see Fig.1). Similar results have been obtained in Ref. [8] for the high-frequency return for the $/DM exchange rate with slightly different values of the exponent. We choose parameters of our model to get the correct scaling behaviour and define β( ) as β( ) = 30/ 0.71. We also take the number of traded lots infinite. Fig.1 clearly demonstrates the correct scaling property of the model constructed above and gives the same scaling exponent α = 0.71 which is technically due to the scaling form of β( ). Now we can plot also the probability distribution function of returns for S&P500 as depicted on Fig.2. The same analysis leads to similar results for the $/DM exchange rate [8] with slightly different values of the parameters. It is easy to see that the theoretical and observed distribution functions coincide exactly with the observed data accuracy. The shape of the distribution function does not characterize it completely. Indeed, a similar form can be obtained using the GARCH/ARCH models [14, 15], which still are phenomenological rather than microscopic. However, those models cannot explain the scaling properties obeyed by the real data [8, 9]. In the proposed model both the shape of the distribution function and scaling properties are presented. It is interesting to add that the swings of the real data on Fig.1 can be interpreted as a sign of the inhomoginuity of the distribution of traders across time horizons, with a larger number of traders on 15 mins, 60 mins and a day investment horizons. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS. We thank R.Mantegna for sending us experimental data used in Figs 1,2. References [1] K. Cuthbertson, Quantitative financial economics, Jonh Wiley & Sons, 1996; [2] E.J. Elton, M.J. Gruber, Modern portfolio theory and investment analysis, Jonh Wiley & Sons, 1995; [3] J.C. Hull, Options, futures and other derivatives, Prentice Hall International, Inc, 1997; 5

[4] J.B. De Long, A. Shleifer, L.H. Summers and R.J. Waldmann: Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets, Journal of Political Economy, 98, N4, (1990), 703-738; [5] P. Bak, M. Paczuski, M. Shubik: Price variations in a stock market with many agents, PHYSICA A 246, N.3-4, (1997) 430-453; [6] K. Ilinski: Physics of Finance, to appear in Edited Volume on Econophysics, Kluwer publishing; available at http://xxx.lanl.gov/abs/hepth/9710148; [7] N. Dumbar: Market forces, New Scientist, N2128, (1998), 42-45; [8] S. Ghashghaie, W. Breymann, J. Peinke, P. Talkner and Y. Dodge: Turbulent cascades in foreign-exchange markets, Nature 381, (1996) 767-770; [9] R.N. Mantegna and H.E. Stanley: Scaling behavior in the dynamics of an economical index, Nature, 376, (1995) 46-49; [10] J.P. Bouchaud, D. Sornette: The Black-Scholes option pricing in mathematical finance - generalization and extensions for a large class of stochastic processes, Journal de Physique I (France), 4 (1994) 863-881; [11] A. Matacz: Financial Modelling and Option Theory with the Truncated Levy Process, preprint cond-mat/9710197; available at http://xxx.lanl.gov/abs/cond-mat/9710197; [12] G. Sofianos: Index Arbitrage Profitability, NYSE working paper 90-04; The Journal of Derivatives, 1, N1 (1993); [13] E.E. Peters, Fractional Market Analysis, John Wiley & Sons,Inc., 1995; [14] R.F. Engle: Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity with Estimates of the Variance of United Kingdom Inflation, Econometrica 50, (1982) 987-1007; [15] T. Bollerslev, R.Y. Chous, K.F. Kroner: ARCH Modeling in Finance: A Review of the Theory and Empirical Evidence, J.Econometrics 52, (1992) 5-59. 6

Figure caption FIG.1 Theoretical (solid line) and experimental (squares) probability of return to the origin (to get zero return) P(0) as a function of time. The slope of the best-fit straight line is -0.712±0.025 [9]. The theoretical curve converges to the Brownian value 0.5 as time tends to one month. FIG.2 Comparison of the = 1 min theoretical (solid line) and observed [9] (squares) probability distribution of the return P(r). The dashed line (long dashes) shows the gaussian distribution with the standard deviation σ equal to the experimental value 0.0508. Values of the return are normalized to σ. The dashed line (short dashes) is the best fitted symmetrical Levy stable distribution [9]. 7

1.5 1 0.5 log(p(0)) 0 8-0.5-1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 log(t/min)

2 1 0 log(p(r)) -1 9-2 -3-4 -20-15 -10-5 0 5 10 15 20 r