THE ECONOMICS OF CHILD LABOR: AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION. Eric Edmonds Dartmouth, IZA, NBER Norbert Schady The World Bank

Similar documents
Cash transfers, conditions, school enrollment, and child work: Evidence from a randomized experiment in Ecuador. Norbert Schady Maria Caridad Araujo

The effects of non-contributory social protection on adults labour decisions.

Are Cash Transfers Made to Women Spent Like Other Sources of Income?

The Role of Conditional Cash Transfers in the Process of Equitable Economic Development

Conditional Cash Transfers: Helping reduce poverty in the short- and long-term. Ariel Fiszbein Chief Economist Human Development Network World Bank

The impact of cash transfers on school enrollment: Evidence from Ecuador * Hessel Oosterbeek Juan Ponce Norbert Schady

School Attendance, Child Labour and Cash

The Impact of Cash Transfers on School Enrollment:

Antipoverty transfers and growth

Motivation. Conditional cash transfer (CCT) programs have become very popular: first in Latin America and now across the world

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

Estimating Rates of Return of Social Protection

Impact of Global Financial Crisis and Assessment of Policy Responses. Suzanne Duryea November 18, 2010

RESOURCE POOLING WITHIN FAMILY NETWORKS: INSURANCE AND INVESTMENT

FACT SHEET - LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN

Medium-term Impacts of a Productive Safety Net on Aspirations and Human Capital Investments

Review of CCT Impact Evaluations

How Do Ex Ante Simulations Compare with Ex Post Evaluations?

Gone with the Storm: Rainfall Shocks and Household Wellbeing in Guatemala

Do Conditional Cash Transfers (CCT) Really Improve Education and Health and Fight Poverty? The Evidence

Hit and Run? WPS8344. Policy Research Working Paper Income Shocks and School Dropouts in Latin America

The Effects of a Conditional Transfer Program on the Labor Market: The Human Development Bonus in Ecuador

POVERTY, GROWTH, AND PUBLIC TRANSFERS IN TANZANIA PROGRESS REPORT ON THE NATIONAL SAFETY NET STUDY

WELFARE REFORM AND THE BEHAVIOUR OF THE UNEMPLOYED. Sarah Brown and Karl Taylor Department of Economics University Of Sheffield InstEAD and IZA

Working with the ultra-poor: Lessons from BRAC s experience

LABOR MARKET SHOCKS AND THEIR IMPACTS ON WORK AND SCHOOLING: EVIDENCE FROM URBAN MEXICO

Tanzania Community-Based Conditional Cash Transfer (CB-CCT) Pilot

Social Protection From Protection to Production

GENDER EQUITY IN THE TAX SYSTEM FOR FISCAL SUSTAINABILITY

Nicholas Mathers Why a universal Child Grant makes sense in Nepal: a four-step analysis

Living Arrangements, Doubling Up, and the Great Recession: Was This Time Different?

The Effects of Financial Inclusion on Children s Schooling, and Parental Aspirations and Expectations

Frequently asked questions Dependent Care Spending Account (DCSA)

Integrating Simulation and Experimental Approaches to Evaluate Impacts of SCTs: Evidence from Lesotho

Technical Track Title Session V Regression Discontinuity (RD)

Marginal Benefit Incidence of Pubic Health Spending: Evidence from Indonesian sub-national data

Income Risk and Schooling Decisions in Burkina Faso

Investing on Human Development: More than Conditioning Cash Transfers. Woodrow Wilson Center September 25, 2008

Well-being and Income Poverty

Health Shocks and Consumption Smoothing in Rural Households: Does Microcredit have a Role to Play?

Financing strategies to achieve the MDGs in Latin America and the Caribbean

How Much? Spending on SSN Programs

Formal Financial Institutions and Informal Finance Experimental Evidence from Village India

MDGs Example from Latin America

Integrating transfers and services to address child poverty: Human development programmes in middle-income countries

Consumer Boycott, Household Heterogeneity and Child Labor

Heterogeneous Program Impacts in PROGRESA. Habiba Djebbari University of Maryland IZA

Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates

Empirical Approaches in Public Finance. Hilary Hoynes EC230. Outline of Lecture:

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Colombia. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

Assessing Development Strategies to Achieve the MDGs in the Arab Region

Impact Evaluation of the Land Certification Program in Ethiopia: Challenges and Opportunities. Daniel Ayalew Ali 19 April 2011

Trade Adjustment and Human Capital Investments: Evidence from Indian Tariff Reform

EC989 Behavioural Economics. Sketch solutions for Class 2

Education Choices in Mexico: Using a Structural Model and a Randomized Experiment to Evaluate PROGRESA

David Newhouse Daniel Suryadarma

Trade Adjustment and Human Capital Investments: Evidence from Indian Tariff Reform

Business Building, Stillwater, OK

Conditional Cash Transfers for Improving Utilization of Health Services. Health Systems Innovation Workshop Abuja, January 25 th -29 th, 2010

Balancing Adequacy and Sustainability Insights from the Global Aging Preparedness Index

Distributional Impacts of the Self Sufficiency Project

Quasi-Experimental Methods. Technical Track

The (Positive) Effect of Macroeconomic Crises on the Schooling and Employment Decisions of Children in a Middle-Income Country 1

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1. Module Objectives

Online Appendix Table 1. Robustness Checks: Impact of Meeting Frequency on Additional Outcomes. Control Mean. Controls Included

The Implications of a Greying Japan for Public Policy.

Trade Adjustment and Human Capital Investments: Evidence from Indian Tariff Reform

While real incomes in the lower and middle portions of the U.S. income distribution have

Long-term Impacts of Poverty Programs: A Local-economy Cost-benefit Analysis of Lesotho's Child Grants Programme

Making Conditional Cash Transfer Programs More Efficient: Designing for Maximum Effect of the Conditionality

Reaching out: Thorsten Beck, Asli Demirguc-Kunt and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria

Impact of Economic Crises on Health Outcomes & Health Financing. Pablo Gottret Lead HD Economist, SASHD The World Bank March, 2009

Urbanization, Human Capital, and Cross-Country Productivity Differences

Heterogeneous Program Impacts in PROGRESA. Habiba Djebbari University of Maryland IZA

Economics 270c. Development Economics Lecture 11 April 3, 2007

Development Economics: Microeconomic issues and Policy Models

ANALYSIS OF THE LINKAGE BETWEEN DOMESTIC REVENUE MOBILIZATION AND SOCIAL SECTOR SPENDING

Broad and Deep: The Extensive Learning Agenda in YouthSave

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that

Trading Places: A Decade of Earnings Mobility in Chile and Nicaragua

Activation and Graduation of Social Assistance Beneficiaries in Developing Countries Istanbul

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SUSTAINING IMPACTS WHEN TRANSFERS END: WOMEN LEADERS, ASPIRATIONS, AND INVESTMENT IN CHILDREN. Karen Macours Renos Vakis

Effects of Increased Elderly Employment on Other Workers Employment and Elderly s Earnings in Japan. Ayako Kondo Yokohama National University

Income smoothing, child labor and schooling: a randomized field experiment in the Nampula province of Mozambique.

POVERTY, INEQUALITY AND PUBLIC CASH TRANSFERS: LESSONS FROM LATIN AMERICA

Fiscal Incidence Analysis. B. Essama-Nssah World Bank Poverty Reduction Group Washinton D.C. June 03, 2008

Moving toward markets? Labor allocation in rural China

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Testing the Solow Growth Theory

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PUBLIC POLICY, HEALTH INSURANCE AND THE TRANSITION TO ADULTHOOD. Phillip B. Levine Robin McKnight Samantha Heep

Does Trade Liberalization Increase the Labor Demand Elasticities? Evidence from Pakistan

h Edition Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries

The Effects of the Colombian Trade Liberalization on Urban Poverty *

Calibrating the 2018 Social Progress Index to the Sustainable Development Goals

Setting the scene. Benjamin Davis Jenn Yablonski. Methodological issues in evaluating the impact of social cash transfers in sub Saharan Africa

THE SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT GOALS AND SOCIAL PROTECTION

EVALUATING INDONESIA S UNCONDITIONAL CASH TRANSFER PROGRAM(S) *

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Brazil. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

Transcription:

THE ECONOMICS OF CHILD LABOR: AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION Eric Edmonds Dartmouth, IZA, NBER Norbert Schady The World Bank

Percent 10-14 Economically Active 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 Tanzania Nigeria Mali Nepal Nicaragua 317 Million Working Children Guatemala Brazil Columbia Ecuador CostaRica Mexico Peru Venezuela 500 1000 1500 2500 5000 10000 20000 40000 Real PPP GDP Per Capita, Chain Index, 2000 Children work more in poor countries The cross country picture in 2000. From Child Labor in the Global Economy, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Winter 2005. 75 percent of the cross country variation in economic activity rates can be explained by variation in GDP per capita.

Will work decline with poverty? The problem of evidence Children are less apt to work in richer households Behrman and Knowles 2001; Dammert 2006; Dammert 2008; Edmonds 2006; Edmonds, Pavcnik, and Topalova 2008; Wahba 2006 Children becomes less likely to work as households grow richer Beegle, Dehejia, and Gatti 2006; Duryea, Lam, and Levison 2007; Edmonds 2005; Edmonds and Pavcnik 2005; Glewwe and Jacoby 2004; Jacoby and Skoufias 1997; Yang 2007 But not always Bhalotra and Heady, 2003; Deb and Rosati 2002; Ennew 1992; Ersado 2005; Kambahampati and Rajan 2005; Maitra and Ray 2005; Psacharopoulos 1997; Ray 2000; Swaminathan 1998 Basu, Das, Dutta 2007; Fafchamps and Wahba 2006; Kruger 2007; Manacorda and Rosati 2007; Mueller 1984; Rosenzweig and Evenson 1977; Schady 2004 Attributing causation is difficult: child time allocation and family living standards are joint outcomes of one decision making process

Theory has strong implications The conical model is Basu & Van (AER, 1998) Child and adult labor are perfect substitutes subject to a productivity shifter The absence of child labor is a luxury that can be realized when families cover their subsistence needs. Much stronger than just an income elasticity of child labor supply Together, the raise the possibility of: Child labor as a coordination failure Extremely large adult income elasticities of child labor supply in the neighborhood of perceived subsistence Other factors important outside of that neighborhood

This study Review of the Basu Van Model Discuss it s implications for household responses to cash transfer programs Evidence from Ecuador Randomized field experiment in Ecuador $15/month on randomly selected households 1/10 of monthly income for recipients Declines in paid employment concentrated at school transition ages Total household expenditures decline because of decline in paid employment

The Basu and Van Model A review

Can I afford for my child to not work? 1 child, 1 decision maker The Luxury Axiom Lexicographic preferences Can I afford NOT to send my child away for work? c is consumption, s is perceived basic needs ( ) ( δ ) c,0 c +,1 if c s i i i i ( δ ) ( ) c +,1 c,0 if c < s i i i i

Children work when their family income (absent child labor) is too low The substitution axiom: child and adult labor are perfect substitutes subject to a productivity shifter, α < = 1 wc αwa The budget constraint: Consumption: c i c eαw + w + t i i A A i ( w ) A + ti if wa + ti si = (( 1 + α ) w + t ) if w + t < s A i A i i Child labor: e i 0 if = 1 if w + t s A i i w + t < s A i i

Empirical Implications of Basu and Van The impact of an increase in income depends on how close the family is to subsistence absent the child s contribution Child s time allocation is revelatory Increases in non child labor income can lead to declines in income Perceptions of subsistence are important Expect to have some distribution in the population What goes into them? Costs of alternative uses of child time Greatest response at normal school transition ages

The Economics of Child Labor in Ecuador Testing these predictions in family responses to a cash transfer program in Ecuador

Participation Rate 0 20 40 60 80 100 6 8 10 12 14 16 Age Enrolled in School Unpaid market work Paid Market Work Domestic Work Time allocation by age in Ecuador: June August 2003 Growth in paid employment starts at ages when schooling declines Data: BDH Evaluation Baseline

Annual school expenditures by student age Schooling costs increase dramatically at the end of primary Data from BDH baseline survey (avg. annual income in treated pop is $2000)

Paid employment (away from home) is child labor in this context Why is paid work different in Ecuador? Hours do not appear flexible (8, 40, and 60 / wk) Is rarely combined with schooling 3 in 20 also attend school 12 in 20 in family market work also attend school Across countries, can be explained by greater total hours worked School re entry is rare In the control population, 10 percent of children out of schooling and working at baseline re enter school in the follow up

The experiment Bono de Desarrollo Humano (BDH) in Ecuador Replaces Bono Solidario (1998 2003) Starting in 2001 Ecuador invests in creating a Selben Index Bottom two quintiles of population eligible for BDH $15/month per eligible family (1/10 of monthly income for recipients, GNI per month per capita is $720) BDH gets underway in 2003 Very important launched with a social marketing campaign about the import of human capital investments The evaluation: in 4 provinces, BDH allocated randomly to eligible households for purpose of evaluation Randomization is at the household level (balanced) BDH is an unconditional cash transfer (with social marketing) Baseline data collected in June August 2003 Follow up collected 1.5 years later on average

Age 10 and older Variable Treatment Control Enrolled in School 0.71 0.71 Highest Grade Completed 5.67 5.60 Any Market Work 0.52 0.51 Paid Market Work 0.12 0.12 Unpaid market work 0.43 0.42 Domestic Work 0.82 0.83 Works without school 0.27 0.28 Sample Size 1083 994 Child time allocation at baseline No substantive or significant differences between treatment and control Our focus will be on 10+ and paid market work

The experiment Take up is imperfect Winning the lottery doubles the probability of receipt of the transfer, but there is considerable leakage. Attrition is low and uncorrelated with the lottery 94.1 percent of households recaptured at follow up Focus on follow up sample (effectively, a balanced panel) Other studies of the BDH experiment Paxson & Schady (2008 ) preschool nutrition Schady & Rosero (2008) food in preschool sample Schady & Araujo (2007) school enrollment

Implications of Basu and Van in Ecuador The impact of an increase in income depends on how close the family is to subsistence absent the child s contribution Child s time allocation at baseline is revelatory With rising subsistence costs with age, children working at baseline are unlikely to be affected by the transfer The response to an increase in income is largest at school transition ages Students in school at near end of primary school most apt to be affected Starting at age 12 (age 10 at baseline) Additional adult or transfer income can lead to declines in total family income Discussion and analysis will assume no general equilibrium effects or spillovers on local labor markets

Main findings At school to work transition ages, market work and work for pay decline with additional income Schooling expenditures increase but total expenditures do not in this population

Paid Emp Partic Rate 2 4 6 8 10 4 5 6 7 8 LN PCX Baseline Treat Control Paid employment by treatment status and PCX Paid employment participation rate in follow up plotted against log per capita expenditures at baseline. Treat refers to BDH lottery winners, Control to loosers.

Decline in Paid Employment Participation Rate -2 0 2 4 6 8 4 5 6 7 8 LN PCX Baseline Declines in paid employment largest for poor Pr[e(t)=1 PCX(t 1),D=0] Pr[e(t)=1 PCX(t 1), D=1]

Difference in Baseline Paid Employment Partic Rate -6-4 -2 0 2 4 5 6 7 8 LN PCX Baseline Difference by treatment status is not in baseline Pr[e(t 1)=1 PCX(t 1),D=0] Pr[e(t 1)=1 PCX(t 1), D=1]

Identifying marginal children Children 10 and above with high predicted probability of transitioning from school to paid employment Restrict sample to control population Block full sample on predicted probability of transitioning to paid work eˆ = α + λ + λ + βg + E + π PCX * a * g In text (not in presentation): Full sample Stratify by baseline characteristics ( ) ip1 p1 a1 i i0 i0 i1 i Age 10+ at baseline (follow up is 1.5 years after baseline) Age 10+ nearing end of primary school Age 10+ not in paid employment at baseline

Empirical Methods e = α + λ + λ + βg + γ tˆ + ε ip p a i r i ip Adult wages in the local labor market captured by parish fixed effects Maintenance and education costs vary by age and gender Gender effect Age dummies Standard errors clustered by parish Targeting errors instrument for take up with lottery award Take up is not random 39 percent of ineligible households receive the transfer 68 percent of lottery winners take up the transfer Use lottery assignment as instrumental variable for take up decision Reduced forms in text

Market Work for Work Pay Unpaid Market Domestic Work Work Enrolled in School Per Child School Expend. Total Hh Expend. Highest probability of transitioning from schooling to paid employment (692 children) Receives BDH (2SLS) -0.245* -0.365** 0.00634 0.121 0.426** 77.19** -430.0 (0.134) (0.130) (0.104) (0.115) (0.162) (37.59) (470.3) Middle third of transition probabilities (692 children) Receives BDH (2SLS) -0.316** 0.00543-0.336** 0.0447 0.125 40.60-232.5 (0.0907) (0.0707) (0.0862) (0.0936) (0.0958) (37.83) (495.8) Lowest transition probability (693 children) Receives BDH (2SLS) -0.218** 0.0674-0.262** -0.0101 0.0804 34.62 158.9 (0.101) (0.0493) (0.106) (0.100) (0.133) (49.16) (430.2) Impact of BDH on child labor and spending Children 10 and older at baseline Instrumental variables results. Each cell is from a different regression. Standard errors in parenthesis. Tables 7 and 9 in paper.

Market Work for Work Pay Unpaid Market Domestic Work Work Enrolled in School Per Child School Expend. Total Hh Expend. Highest probability of transitioning from schooling to paid employment (692 children) Receives BDH (2SLS) -0.245* -0.365** 0.00634 0.121 0.426** 77.19** -430.0 (0.134) (0.130) (0.104) (0.115) (0.162) (37.59) (470.3) Average wage for working children is $84/month.37*84=$31 foregone income per month 1.8 children per household * $31 = $56 foregone per month $56 $15 = $41 per month decline $430/12=$36 per month actual Impact of BDH on child labor and spending Children 10 and older at baseline Instrumental variables results. Each cell is from a different regression. Standard errors in parenthesis. Tables 7 and 9 in paper.

Conclusion

Summary Bono de Desarrollo Humano (BDH) in Ecuador $15/month, 1/10 monthly income for recipients Negligible effects on time allocation for the young or those already out of school at baseline Large effects on paid employment for children vulnerable to transitioning from school to work Families appear to use almost entire transfer to maintain schooling between primary and secondary Schooling expenditure rise absorb most of transfer Total expenditures fall because of the loss of child labor income Average wage for working children is $84/month Probability works for pay declines by 37 percentage points $31 foregone income per child 1.8 children per household, $56 in foregone income per month $56 $15 = $41 per month decline Data suggest decline is $36 per month

Summary Bono de Desarrollo Humano (BDH) in Ecuador $15/month, 1/10 monthly income for recipients Large effects on paid employment for children vulnerable to transitioning from school to work Results consistent with predictions of Basu & Van model Why? Basu and Van Preferences & income change Is the transfer transitory or permanent? Social marketing campaign change perceptions of subsistence Lessons Suggests small, well targeted transfers can have large effects on child labor and schooling Transfer does not need to fully cover direct and opportunity costs to have an effect Experiment with size of transfer, explicitly test conditionality, marketing message, etc.