The federal tax code. The Brookings Institution POLICY BRIEF

Similar documents
POLICY BRIEF. Tax legislation enacted in 2001 increased the value of the Child Tax

REFORMING CHARITABLE TAX INCENTIVES: ASSESSING EVIDENCE AND POLICY OPTIONS

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride

Unemployment Insurance Primer: Understanding What s At Stake as Congress Reopens Stimulus Package Debate. Wayne Vroman January 2002

Universal Savings Account Proposal in New Republican Tax Bill Is Ill-Conceived

Income Taxes and Tax Rates for Sample Families, 2006 Greg Leiserson. December 2006

Taxing Capital Income Once * Leonard E. Burman

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

How Could We Improve the Federal Tax System?

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

The Potential Effects of Retirement. Security Project. Proposals on Private and National Saving: Exploratory Calculations

How Do the Presidential Candidates Tax Plans Affect Taxpayers Marginal Tax Rates?

July 17, Summary

xiii Executive Summary

center for retirement research

SHOULD THE BUDGET RULES BE CHANGED SO THAT LARGE-SCALE BORROWING TO FUND INDIVIDUAL ACCOUNTS IS LEFT OUT OF THE BUDGET? 1

Tax Reform Options: Promoting Retirement Security. Testimony Submitted to United States Senate Committee on Finance. September 15, 2011

July 31, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

WOULD RAISING IRA CONTRIBUTION LIMITS BOLSTER RETIREMENT SECURITY FOR LOWER AND MIDDLE-INCOME FAMILIES? by Peter Orszag and Jonathan Orszag 1

Qualified Research Activities

DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF PUBLIC AFFAIRS

The unprecedented surge in tax receipts beginning in fiscal

THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE MINIMUM TAX: HISTORICAL DATA

STRUCTURAL REFORM REFORMING THE PENSION SYSTEM IN KOREA. Table 1: Speed of Aging in Selected OECD Countries. by Randall S. Jones

March 12, 2009 KEY FINDINGS

PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS OF THE FAMILY FAIRNESS AND OPPORTUNITY TAX REFORM ACT

The Budget Outlook. Auerbach, Gale, Orszag. no. June The Ten-Year Budget Outlook

General Explanations of the Administration s Fiscal Year 2014 Revenue Proposals

Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy Discussion Questions

HOW DO PHASEOUTS WORK?

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND

Tax Policy Issues and Options

WHAT WOULD IT SAY ABOUT CONGRESS S PRIORITIES TO WAIVE PAYGO FOR THE AMT PATCH? By Aviva Aron-Dine

Testimony to the President s Tax Reform Panel

FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH REFORM BILL STILL MORE PROBLEMATIC

MORE THAN HALF OF BLACK AND HISPANIC FAMILIES WOULD NOT BENEFIT FROM BUSH TAX PLAN. by Isaac Shapiro, Allen Dupree and James Sly

The Bush Tax Cut: One Year Later

A Dynamic Analysis of President Obama s Tax Initiatives

continue to average 0.2 percent of GDP from 2018 through 2028, CBO projects.

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are tax expenditures and how are they structured?

TAX EXPENDITURES FOR RETIREMENT PLANS

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy

Obama s Tax Hikes on High-Income Earners Will Hurt the Poor and Everyone Else

Verifying Incomes of All EITC Filers Would Delay Refunds, Raise Costs, Divert IRS Resources from More Effective Uses

Revised December 7, 2006

ISSUE. Evaluate several options for expanding eligibility for North Carolina s Earned Income

SPECIAL REPORT. IMPACT. Many of the changes to the Internal Revenue Code in the

HOW DOES THE PROPOSED LEVEL OF FOREIGN ECONOMIC AID UNDER THE BUSH BUDGET COMPARE WITH HISTORICAL LEVELS?

INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES

FISCAL FACT No. 516 July, 2016 Director of Federal Projects Key Findings Embargoed

GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES FISCAL RESEARCH CENTER May 14, 1999

Lyle E. Gramley MEMBER, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM. Conrnunity Leaders in Seattle

Rewarding Work Through State Earned Income Tax Credits in 2018

The misplaced debate about job loss and a $15 minimum wage

17. Social Security. Congress should allow workers to privately invest at least half their Social Security payroll taxes through individual accounts.

There are several types of tax-favored retirement

The Changing Composition of Tax Incentives

U.S. House of Representatives COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS

Senator Kerry s Tax Proposals. Leonard E. Burman and Jeffrey Rohaly 1 Revised July 23, 2004

Revised January 6, 2006

Removing Inflation from the Base is Fair, Pro-Growth Concept

Giving in a Post-Tax Reform World Strategies to maximize the value of charitable gifts 1

ARE TAXES TOO CONCENTRATED AT THE TOP? Rapidly Rising Incomes at the Top Lie Behind Increase in Share of Taxes Paid By High-Income Taxpayers

The Wrong Way to Fix Social Security. Peter R. Orszag 1 Joseph A. Pechman Senior Fellow The Brookings Institution

Lydian Journal. PYMNTS.com/journal

Chapter 15. Government Spending and its Financing Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

The Growth and Investment Tax Plan

Donald L Kohn: Asset-pricing puzzles, credit risk, and credit derivatives

Written Testimony of Scott A. Hodge, President, Tax Foundation

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAPPING INDIVIDUAL TAX EXPENDITURE BENEFITS. Martin Feldstein Daniel Feenberg Maya MacGuineas

The Minimum Wage Ain t What It Used to Be

Client Tax Letter. Income Tax Rates Hold Steady. What s Inside. Still a Bargain. April/May/June 2011

Personal Income Tax Weakness & Possible Remedies: Outdated and Inequitable Tax Provisions

Investing in Children

Special Report. Using Dynamic Analysis Makes Tax Reform 30 Percent Less Challenging. Key Findings. August 2013 No. 210

ECONOMIC SURVEY OF NEW ZEALAND 2007: TWO BROAD APPROACHES FOR TAX REFORM

HOUSE WAYS AND MEANS OFFSET FOR REPEALING AFFORDABLE CARE ACT S TAX REPORTING REQUIREMENT WOULD WEAKEN HEALTH REFORM

THE CHANGING BUDGET OUTLOOK: CAUSES AND IMPLICATIONS

Two New Indexes Offer a Broad View of Economic Activity in the New York New Jersey Region

Chart Book: TANF at 20

An Analysis of Potential Tax Incentives to Increase Charitable Giving in Puerto Rico

Five Easy Pieces Scorecard

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in describing budget numbers are fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and ar

the debate concerning whether policymakers should try to stabilize the economy.

2010 Social Security Trustees Report: Reform Needed Now

An Analysis of the 2004 House Tax Cuts. Leonard E. Burman 1 The Urban Institute and The Tax Policy Center. June 2004

Preparing for Tax Reform in the Municipal Market

Retirement Savings and Tax Expenditure Estimates

The Economic Effects of the Estate Tax

EFFECTS OF THE TAX REFORM PANEL S PROPOSALS ON LOW- AND MODERATE-INCOME HOUSEHOLDS By Aviva Aron-Dine and Joel Friedman 1

Discussion Comments on Rebecca Blank, What Did the 1990s Welfare Reform Accomplish? Robert Haveman University of Wisconsin-Madison

When Interest Rates Go Up, What Will This Mean For the Mortgage Market and the Wider Economy?

PRINCIPLES FOR ECONOMIC STIMULUS. By Andrew Lee

1102 Longworth House Office Building 1106 Longworth House Office Building Washington, DC Washington, DC 20515

Distributional Impact of Social Security Reforms: Summary

Summary An issue in the development of the new health care reform plan is the effect on small business. One concern is the effect of a pay or play man

These are tough times, especially for low- and

Federal Taxation of Earnings versus Investment Income in 2004

Transcription:

The Brookings Institution POLICY BRIEF August 2006 Policy Brief #156 Related Brookings Resources Improving Opportunities and Incentives for Saving by Middleand Low-Income Households William G. Gale, Jonathan Gruber, and Peter R. Orszag (April 2006) Improving the Saver s Credit William G. Gale, J. Mark Iwry, and Peter R. Orszag Brookings Policy Brief #131 (July 2004) A longer academic version of this work will appear in the Stanford Law Review at 59 Stan. L. Rev. (2006). When possible and appropriate, please cite to that version. To receive a weekly e-mail about Brookings news, events, and publications, sign up for the Brookings Alert at www.brookings.edu. The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Ave. N.W. Washington, DC 20036 Reforming Tax Incentives into Uniform Refundable Tax Credits BY LILY L. BATCHELDER, FRED T. GOLDBERG, JR., AND PETER R. ORSZAG The federal tax code provides about $500 billion each year in incentives intended to encourage socially-valued activities, including homeownership, charitable contributions, health insurance, and education. The vast majority of these incentives operate through deductions or other approaches that link the size of the tax break to a household s marginal tax bracket, which means that higher-income taxpayers receive larger incentives than lower-income taxpayers. Such an approach is often appropriate for provisions, such as deductions for business expenses, designed to measure income or ability to pay. But such an approach for incentives intended to promote socially-valued activities excludes more than a third of America, and misses an important opportunity to increase efficiency and economic growth. We propose a dramatic change in how the government provides these tax incentives, which could be done on a revenue-neutral basis. Under our proposal, the default for all tax incentives intended to promote socially-beneficial behavior would be a uniform refundable tax credit, which would be available to qualifying households even if they owe no income tax. These tax credits would provide a much more even and widespread motivation for socially-valued behavior than the current set of tax incentives, and could help smooth out fluctuations in household income and macroeconomic demand, all of which would improve economic efficiency. All Policy Briefs are available on the Brookings website at www.brookings.edu.

Lily L. Batchelder, who received her M.P.P. from Harvard s Kennedy School of Government and her J.D. from Yale Law School, is an assistant professor of law and public policy at New York University School of Law, where she specializes in the areas of income taxation, social insurance, and tax policy. REFUNDABLE TAX CREDITS VERSUS OTHER FORMS OF TAX INCENTIVES Policymakers have created tax incentives for homeownership, retirement saving, education, and medical expenses. Other tax incentives seek to promote work, charitable giving, and investment in life insurance, annuities, and state and local bonds. Together, these tax incentives reduce federal tax revenues by about $500 billion a year, or roughly 4 percent of Gross Domestic Product. Structuring these tax incentives most efficiently is therefore an immensely important policy matter. Approximately $420 billion of these existing tax incentives operate through deductions, exemptions, or exclusions. Such tax incentives tie the size of the tax break to an individual s marginal tax bracket: A deduction of $1, for example, is worth 35 cents to someone in the 35 percent marginal bracket but only 15 cents to someone in the 15 percent marginal bracket. Such incentives thus provide relatively weak incentives to those in low tax rate brackets. Furthermore, these types of tax incentives fail to reach the increasingly significant share of lowand moderate-income individuals and families who do not have any federal income tax liability to offset in any given year. More than 35 percent of households during any given year have no income tax liability; these households are home to almost half of all American children. Refundable tax credits represent a different approach. Since they are a credit, rather than a deduction or exclusion, they do not depend on a household s marginal tax bracket. A tax credit of $1, for example, reduces taxes by $1 and thus is worth the same to households in the 35 percent bracket or the 15 percent 2 Copyright Carol Clayton Photography. Fred T. Goldberg, Jr., who received his J.D. from Yale Law School, is a partner in the Washington, D.C. office of Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom LLP where he represents his clients in matters involving a wide range of tax issues, and has served as IRS Commissioner and Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for Tax Policy under President George W. Bush. Billions of 2006 dollars $100 $90 $80 $70 $60 $50 $40 $30 $20 $10 $0 Figure 1 Growth in Refundable Credits over Time Non-Refundable Element of CTC Refundable Element of CTC Non-Refundable Element of EITC Refundable Element of EITC 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 Tax Year Sources: Authors calculations based on tax credit data from the Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income; Ways and Means 2004 Green Book; and the Joint Committee on Taxation. Policy Brief #156 April 2006

bracket. And since they are refundable, they provide benefits to all tax filers, regardless of whether they owe income taxes on net. THE GROWTH OF REFUNDABLE TAX CREDITS Currently the tax code contains three main refundable tax credits: the Earned Income Tax Credit, the Child Tax Credit, and a small health insurance credit. The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) is the largest anti-poverty program for the nonelderly in the country. In inflationadjusted terms, the budgetary cost of the EITC has risen by a factor of nine since it was enacted in 1975, and it tripled between 1990 and 2000 alone. More recently, the partially refundable Child Tax Credit (CTC) and the fully refundable health insurance credit were enacted, and the refundability of the CTC was expanded and accelerated. Several factors likely contributed to the dramatic growth of refundable credits over the past three decades (see Figure 1). For example, policymakers have increasingly relied on the tax code rather than direct government expenditures to subsidize households and influence their behavior as a result of perceived or real incentives within the tax legislative process, a development that has supported the rise of refundable credits. THE CASE FOR UNIFORM REFUNDABLE CREDITS Despite the growth in refundable credits, most tax incentives intended to promote socially-beneficial behavior take the form of deductions or other approaches linked to marginal tax rates. Yet if policymakers want to broadly promote socially-valued behavior through the tax code, refundable credits are generally necessary. As illustrated in Figure 2, in any given year more Peter R. Orszag, who obtained his A.B. in economics from Princeton University and his Ph.D. in economics from the London School of Economics, is the Joseph A. Pechman Senior Fellow in Economic Studies at the Brookings Institution and Co-Director of the Tax Policy Center. Figure 2 Federal Income Tax Liability Positive Household Tax Liability No Household Tax Liability 80% 37% 49% 59% All Tax Units Annually All Children Annually All Tax Units Over 20 Years (Zero Tax Liability in 1 or More Years) Children in Single- Parent Households Annually Sources: Peter R. Orszag & Matthew G. Hall, Nonfilers and Filers with Modest Tax Liabilities, 100 Tax Notes 723 (2003); authors calculations based on a simple model of 2003 law and longitudinal earnings data from the Panel Survey of Income Dynamics. 3

We propose a dramatic change in how the government provides these tax incentives, which could be done on a revenue-neutral basis. than one-third of households do not have any federal income tax liability. About a quarter of tax units file a tax return but have no income tax liability, and another 13 percent do not file. Moreover, almost half of all children, and 80 percent of children in single parent households, live in tax units with no income tax liability in any given year. As a result, if policymakers want to create incentives through the individual income tax for all or most tax units to engage in certain behavior every year, such as saving or obtaining education for themselves or their children, refundability should not only be considered an acceptable instrument of tax policy it is imperative. Furthermore, unless there is evidence that certain households are more responsive to the incentive than others or generate larger social benefits from engaging in the activity, tax incentives are most efficient if they provide the same incentive to all households and that can only be accomplished in a straightforward manner through a uniform (and refundable) credit. The reason that a uniform incentive is the most efficient approach in the absence of evidence regarding differences in responsiveness or social benefits is that a small number of large mistakes in under- or over-subsidizing an activity are more costly in efficiency terms than a large number of small mistakes. For example, imagine that certain behavior, perhaps charitable contributions, on average generates 5 cents of social benefits per dollar contributed per year and policymakers have determined to subsidize contributions by, on average, 5 cents per dollar. Imagine further that there is a 50 percent chance that a dollar of contributions by a high-income household generates 10 cents of social benefits, while a dollar of contributions by a lowincome household generates none, and a 50 percent chance that this pattern is reversed. A uniform subsidy of 5 cents would leave 5 cents of lost social benefits in both cases. Meanwhile, a subsidy of 10 cents given to one group would result in 10 cents of lost social benefits in one case and none in the other. The uniform subsidy is more efficient it technically minimizes the expected deadweight loss because a small number of big errors (one case of 10 cents) is more costly than a large number of small errors (two cases of 5 cents). We acknowledge that many behavioral tax incentives may be bad policy regardless of whether they take the form of uniform refundable credits, perhaps because the behavior in question does not actually generate social benefits or because such social benefits are best addressed through direct government provision of the good or regulation. Even taking these limitations into account, however, assuming the continued existence of a tax incentive, our default structure is generally preferable because it minimizes the expected social losses from the tax incentive, regardless of whether the behavior actually is socially beneficial. 4

We also acknowledge that tax incentives should not provide the same incentive to all households in all circumstances. If there is evidence that the associated social benefits vary systematically by income class, or that different income groups exhibit different levels of responsiveness to the subsidy, the tax incentive should not be identical for all households. Indeed these differences between various income groups surely exist in reality. But when, as is frequently the case, the evidence on these issues is non-existent or inconclusive, the most efficient form for a tax incentive is a uniform refundable credit. The burden of proof should therefore be on those who prefer some other form of tax incentive to demonstrate that such deviations from a uniform refundable credit are justified by empirical evidence. Thus, if policymakers wish to use the tax system to create incentives for certain socially-valued behavior, it makes no sense to exclude more than a third of American individuals and families from their reach, or to provide smaller benefits to some households than others, absent evidence that those Americans would be relatively unresponsive or that their behavior generates fewer societal benefits. Moreover, even when there is empirical evidence suggesting that the optimal tax incentive should not be the same for all households, the most efficient incentive is almost certainly still some type of refundable credit. It is extremely unlikely that there is a sharp break in social benefits or responsiveness to an incentive exactly at the point of no income tax liability, and these types of discontinuities are inherent in the application of all other basic forms of tax incentives. The potential benefits of refundable credits are magnified further by a second feature: Their ability to help smooth household income. That is, during hard years, transforming existing tax incentives into uniform refundable credits would boost after-tax income, and thus help to cushion the blow of a drop in earnings, unemployment, or other hardships. Such income smoothing is desirable for several reasons. It can reduce the costs associated with economic instability and offset failures in insurance markets. It also allows families to plan their expenditures more confidently and avoids the additional costs (such as moving costs and credit card debt) of financing constant changes in household living standards. Income smoothing is particularly beneficial for lower-income households because they generally don t have easy access to credit to make it through tough times, because they tend to have more volatile incomes than other families in general, and because income shocks can result in declines in their economic circumstances that persist over a long periods of time and are passed on to their children. The final element of the case for uniform refundable credits is their ability to smooth the macroeconomy. Like household income smoothing, macroeconomic Furthermore, unless there is evidence that certain households are more responsive to the incentive than others or generate larger social benefits from engaging in the activity, tax incentives are most efficient if they provide the same incentive to all households and that can only be accomplished through a uniform (and refundable) credit. 5

The potential benefits of refundable credits are magnified further by a second feature: Their ability to help smooth household income. smoothing can enhance economic efficiency. In particular, macroeconomic demand fluctuations make it difficult for companies to optimize their investment and production functions, resulting in adjustment costs. These difficulties can inhibit domestic and foreign investment, which is correlated with economic growth. As a result, there is broad consensus in support of taxing and spending policies that are automatically countercyclical. Uniform refundable credits can help stabilize macroeconomic demand fluctuations by raising cash payments to families during recessionary periods, which then helps to boost spending precisely the desired response during such periods. A SPECIFIC EXAMPLE: RETIREMENT CONTRIBUTIONS TO 401(K)S AND IRAS William Gale of Brookings, Jonathan Gruber of MIT, and Peter Orszag of Brookings have recently proposed a specific example that is similar in spirit to our broader policy suggestion. They note that current incentives for contributions to 401(k) plans and IRAs deliver their largest immediate benefits to higher-income individuals in the highest tax brackets. Gale, Gruber, and Orszag would replace the existing tax deductions for contributions to retirement saving accounts with a 30 percent government matching contribution. Unlike the current system, workers contributions to employer-based 401(k) accounts would no longer be excluded from income subject to taxation, and contributions to IRAs would no longer be tax deductible. Furthermore, any employer contributions to a 401(k) plan would be treated as taxable income to the employee (just as current wages are). However, all qualified employer and employee contributions would be eligible for the 30 percent government matching contribution regardless of the employee s income. This proposal would be roughly revenue neutral for the federal government, according to estimates from the Tax Policy Center microsimulation model. This proposal provides a specific example of how a tax deduction or exclusion could be transformed, on a revenue neutral basis, into a uniform refundable credit. Our analysis generally supports this transformation as the default structure for retirement savings incentives, assuming such incentives are intended to promote the social benefits generated by retirement savings and that no other aspects of the tax code are intended to play that role. OPPOSITION TO REFUNDABLE CREDITS Opponents of refundable credits typically raise four main concerns. First, some question the extent to which government should engage in redistribution between different income groups. Second, some argue that the tax system should be used only to raise revenue, not to provide subsidies. Third, some believe that all Americans should pay at least some tax, 6

even if just one dollar, as a duty of citizenship and so that they feel some stake in governmental decisions. Finally, some argue that refundable credits would increase administrative and compliance costs on net and are particularly subject to fraud and abuse. Concerns about the extent of governmental redistribution, however, do not justify rejecting refundable credits that are enacted to enhance economic efficiency by subsidizing sociallybeneficial behavior. And concerns about delivering subsidies through the tax system instead of the transfer system are generally objections to tax incentives overall, not to structuring tax incentives as refundable credits specifically. The third objection that all Americans should pay some tax ignores the fact that most households claiming refundable credits pay a variety of federal, state and local taxes other than income taxes. Moreover, if one is interested strictly in federal income taxes, it seems likely that most refundable credit beneficiaries pay a positive amount of federal income tax over time as a result of the income variations that people tend to experience over their lives. Indeed, a simplified model of 2003 federal income tax law using data from the Panel Survey of Income Dynamics suggests that about threequarters of tax units who are eligible for the refundable element of the EITC or CTC at some point during a 20-year period would nevertheless have positive net federal income tax liability over that period if historic earnings patterns are any guide. Thus, even if one accepts the principle that paying some income tax is necessary for feeling a stake in government decisions (which we do not), this principle would not necessarily preclude refundable credits once income tax liabilities are examined over longer time periods. The final objection to refundable credits is that they could increase fraud and related compliance problems. Yet there is no reason in theory, and no empirical evidence in practice, why there should be a cliff effect in fraud precisely at the point of positive income tax liability. If anything, fraud may be easier to hide when it comes in the form of a deduction or exclusion, which reduces taxable income, as opposed to a refundable credit. Instead, reducing fraud and related compliance problems for all tax incentives, including refundable credits, requires structuring the incentives simply, relying on third-party reporting, and investing in enforcement staffing. We recognize that increasing the prevalence of refundable credits may create incentives for tax units who are currently non-filers to begin filing, thereby increasing administrative costs for the government and compliance costs for these households. These costs are real and should be taken into account. Nevertheless, they should not be overstated. Currently only about 13 7

Recent Policy Briefs International Volunteering: Smart Power Lex Rieffel, Sarah Zalud (June 2006) Untangling China s Quest for Oil through State-backed Financial Deals Peter C. Evans, Erica S. Downs (May 2006) The Effects of Investing in Early Education on Economic Growth William T. Dickens, Isabel V. Sawhill, Jeffrey Tebbs (April 2006) Pragmatic Reform of Global Governance: Creating an L20 Summit Forum Johannes F. Linn, Colin I. Bradford, Jr. (April 2006) Building Automatic Solvency into U.S. Social Security: Insights from Sweden and Germany James C. Capretta (March 2006) percent of tax units are non-filers. As a result, non-filers represent a relatively small share of the households who stand to gain from structuring tax incentives as uniform refundable credits. Moreover, all tax incentives are elective and, even for non-filers, the administrative and compliance costs associated with claiming them are likely to be swamped in many instances by the dollar value of the credit. CONCLUSION Uniform refundable tax credits are generally the most efficient structure for a tax incentive to encourage desired behavior when, as frequently occurs, evidence of how the desired behavior and its associated social benefits vary across the income distribution is unavailable or inconclusive. Indeed refundable tax credits are generally the only way to ensure a tax incentive reaches the roughly two-fifths of tax units with no positive income tax liability in a given year. These efficiency benefits are magnified by the ability of refundable credits to help smooth income at a household level and by their ability, to a greater or less extent, to bolster the role of the tax system as an automatic stabilizer of macroeconomic demand. The United States spends almost 4 percent of GDP each year subsidizing socially-valued activities through the tax code. Our proposal would dramatically improve the effectiveness and fairness of this substantial investment. Tell us what you think of this Policy Brief. E-mail your comments to feedback@brookings.edu. Production/Layout MillerCox Design Vice President of Communications Melissa T. Skolfield The Brookings Office of Communications (202) 797-6105 communications@brookings.edu The views expressed in this Policy Brief are those of the authors and are not necessarily those of the trustees, officers, or other staff members of the Brookings Institution. Copyright 2006 The Brookings Institution The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Ave., NW Washington, DC 20036 NONPROFIT ORG. U.S. POSTAGE PAID FREDERICK, MD PERMIT NO. 225 8 Policy Brief #156 Augsust 2006