Commerce Division Discussion Paper No. 48. Long Run Overreaction on the New Zealand Stock Exchange. Simon Swallow Mark A. Fox.

Similar documents
Systematic liquidity risk and stock price reaction to shocks: Evidence from London Stock Exchange

Profitability of Contrarian Strategies: Evidence from the Stock Exchange of Mauritius

The rise and fall of the Dogs of the Dow

British Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences 42 November 2011, Vol. 2 (2)

Journal of Asian Business Strategy. Overreaction Effect in the Tunisian Stock Market

Daily Stock Returns: Momentum, Reversal, or Both. Steven D. Dolvin * and Mark K. Pyles **

Peter J. BUSH University of Michigan-Flint School of Management Adjunct Professor of Finance

CHAPTER 12: MARKET EFFICIENCY AND BEHAVIORAL FINANCE

International Journal of Management Sciences and Business Research, 2013 ISSN ( ) Vol-2, Issue 12

Information Content of PE Ratio, Price-to-book Ratio and Firm Size in Predicting Equity Returns

A Study of Contrarian and Momentum Profits in Indian Stock Market

Journal of Finance and Banking Review. Single Beta and Dual Beta Models: A Testing of CAPM on Condition of Market Overreactions

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

Testing Short-Term Over/Underreaction Hypothesis: Empirical Evidence from the Egyptian Exchange

REVIEW OF OVERREACTION AND UNDERREACTION IN STOCK MARKETS

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/02

The month of the year effect explained by prospect theory on Polish Stock Exchange

Tests of the Overreaction Hypothesis and the Timing of Mean Reversals on the JSE Securities Exchange (JSE): the Case of South Africa

Anomalous Price Behavior Following Earnings Surprises: Does Representativeness Cause Overreaction?

LAPPEENRANTA UNIVERSITY OF TECHNOLOGY School of Business Finance MOMENTUM AND CONTRARIAN INVESTMENT STRATEGIES

Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements

The Value Premium and the January Effect

Value Investing in Thailand: The Test of Basic Screening Rules

Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended Analysis

Behavioral Finance 1-1. Chapter 4 Challenges to Market Efficiency

Market Behaviour of Foreign versus Domestic Investors. Following a Period of Stressful Circumstances

Ulaş ÜNLÜ Assistant Professor, Department of Accounting and Finance, Nevsehir University, Nevsehir / Turkey.

Volatility Risk and January Effect: Evidence from Japan

The Role of Industry Effect and Market States in Taiwanese Momentum

Systematic Liquidity Risk and Stock Price Reaction to Large One-Day Price Changes: Evidence from London Stock Exchange.

Debt/Equity Ratio and Asset Pricing Analysis

CHAPTER 2. Contrarian/Momentum Strategy and Different Segments across Indian Stock Market

Discussion of Information Uncertainty and Post-Earnings-Announcement-Drift

PROFITABILITY OF CAPM MOMENTUM STRATEGIES IN THE US STOCK MARKET

ARE LOSS AVERSION AFFECT THE INVESTMENT DECISION OF THE STOCK EXCHANGE OF THAILAND S EMPLOYEES?

Comparison in Measuring Effectiveness of Momentum and Contrarian Trading Strategy in Indonesian Stock Exchange

The January Effect: Still There after All These Years

Underreaction, Trading Volume, and Momentum Profits in Taiwan Stock Market

TESTING FOR MARKET ANOMALIES IN DIFFERENT SECTORS OF THE JOHANNESBURG STOCK EXCHANGE

CORPORATE ANNOUNCEMENTS OF EARNINGS AND STOCK PRICE BEHAVIOR: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

THE CODING OF OUTCOMES IN TAXPAYERS REPORTING DECISIONS. A. Schepanski The University of Iowa

NCER Working Paper Series

Does the Stock Market Overreact?

Short-Term Contrarian Investing Is it Profitable? Yes and No

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 2 Summer 1997 AN ANALYSIS OF VALUE LINE S ABILITY TO FORECAST LONG-RUN RETURNS

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Individual Analysts Earnings Forecasts: Evidence for Overreaction in the UK Stock Market (a)

Arvydas Paškevičius *, Rūta Mickevičiūtė International Business School at Vilnius University

Outline. The Impact of Share Repurchases on Closed-End Funds. Repurchases: Stylised Facts. Repurchases Now Equal Dividends in Magnitude

An Empirical Study of Serial Correlation in Stock Returns

ESTIMATING THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM IN NEW ZEALAND THROUGH THE SIEGEL METHODOLOGY

The Conditional Relationship between Risk and Return: Evidence from an Emerging Market

Comparison of Disposition Effect Evidence from Karachi and Nepal Stock Exchange

Abnormal Return in Growth Incorporated Value Investing

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 3 Fall 1996 THE JANUARY SIZE EFFECT REVISITED: IS IT A CASE OF RISK MISMEASUREMENT?

The Accrual Anomaly in the Game-Theoretic Setting

Technical Anomalies: A Theoretical Review

Portfolio performance and environmental risk

On the Profitability of Volume-Augmented Momentum Trading Strategies: Evidence from the UK

Trading Volume and Momentum: The International Evidence

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

Analysis of Firm Risk around S&P 500 Index Changes.

The Anomalous Stock Market Behavior of Big and Low Book-to-Market Equity Firms in April: New Evidence from Japan

Early evidence on the efficient market hypothesis was quite favorable to it. In recent

ABNORMAL RETURNS AFTER LARGE STOCK PRICE CHANGES: EVIDENCE FROM THE VIETNAMESE STOCK MARKET

Systematic patterns before and after large price changes: Evidence from high frequency data from the Paris Bourse

Chapter 13. Efficient Capital Markets and Behavioral Challenges

Investor Reaction in Stock Market Crashes and Post-Crash Market Reversals

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Liquidity skewness premium

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 3 Fall 1997 CORPORATE MANAGERS RISKY BEHAVIOR: RISK TAKING OR AVOIDING?


A Behavioristic Study on Overreaction and Underreaction: When and Why Does it Occur?

A Random Walk Down Wall Street

REVISITING THE ASSET PRICING MODELS

MOMENTUM STRATEGIES AND TRADING VOLUME TURNOVER IN MALAYSIAN STOCK EXCHANGE. Tafdil Husni* A b s t r a c t

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS

IDIOSYNCRATIC RISK AND AUSTRALIAN EQUITY RETURNS

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang*

THE PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIVERSITY SCHREYER HONORS COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection

Existence of short term momentum effect and stock market of Turkey

Rebalancing the Simon Fraser University s Academic Pension Plan s Balanced Fund: A Case Study

Empirical Research of Asset Growth and Future Stock Returns Based on China Stock Market

Medium-term and Long-term Momentum and Contrarian Effects. on China during

Asian Economic and Financial Review AN ANALYSIS FOR CREDIT RATING AND MOMENTUM STRATEGY

The Vasicek adjustment to beta estimates in the Capital Asset Pricing Model

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

Behavioral Finance. Understanding the Social, Cognitive, and Economic Debates EDWIN T. BURTON SUNIT N. SHAH

High Frequency Autocorrelation in the Returns of the SPY and the QQQ. Scott Davis* January 21, Abstract

Discussion of Value Investing: The Use of Historical Financial Statement Information to Separate Winners from Losers

How High A Hedge Is High Enough? An Empirical Test of NZSE10 Futures.

Asian Economic and Financial Review AN EMPIRICAL VALIDATION OF FAMA AND FRENCH THREE-FACTOR MODEL (1992, A) ON SOME US INDICES

EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS

Analysis of Stock Price Behaviour around Bonus Issue:

Monthly Seasonality in the New Zealand Stock Market

MISPRICING FOLLOWING PUBLIC NEWS: OVERREACTION FOR LOSERS, UNDERREACTION FOR WINNERS. Ferhat Akbas, Emre Kocatulum, and Sorin M.

An Introduction to Behavioral Finance

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis

Transcription:

Commerce Division Discussion Paper No. 48 Long Run Overreaction on the New Zealand Stock Exchange Simon Swallow Mark A. Fox March 1998 Commerce Division PO Box 84 Lincoln University CANTERBURY Telephone No: (64) (3) 325 2811 Fax No: (64) (3) 325 3847 E-mail: foxm@kea.lincoln.ac.nz ISSN 1174-5045 ISBN 1-877176-25-7

Abstract The purpose of this paper is to determine whether New Zealand capital markets are efficient. To do this we investigate two competing models of investor decision making in the context of the New Zealand Stock Exchange. The first model views investors as economically rational individuals who make decisions based on all available information. The second model proposes that investors systematically overreact to good and bad information events. The results are consistent with the notion of overreaction, showing that investors overreact to both good and bad news.

Contents List of Tables List of Figures i i 1. Introduction 1 2. Method 4 3. Results 6 3.1 Preliminary analysis 6 3.2 The directional effect 8 3.3 The magnitude effect 9 3.4 The small firm effect 10 4. Summary 12 References 13

List of Tables 1. Average returns for winner and loser portfolios and portfolio differences at the end of years 1, 2, and 3, for the Conrad and Kaul method and the DeBondt and Thaler method 1 2. Average returns for winner and loser portfolios and portfolio differences for differing formation strategies 8 10 List of Figures 1. Cumulative average residuals for winner and loser portfolios of six stock with the test period lasting 36 months after portfolio formation 2. Cumulative average residuals for high market capitalisation winner and loser stocks with the test period lasting 36 months after portfolio formation 7 11 1 The buy and hold returns are calculated separately at the end of each year. Therefore, the first year represents the average of the buy and hold returns in the first year after formation. The second year represents the returns for the first two years from a buy and hold strategy that would buy the shares immediately after the formation period and sell them at the end of the second year. Similarly, the three year strategy would buy the shares after formation and sell them at the end of the third year. So the yearly returns are not cumulated but separately assessed. i

1. Introduction Traditional economic literature has viewed sharemarket investors as rational decision makers (Fama, 1970) who - when faced with uncertainty - apply Bayesian decision making criteria (Brown, Harlow and Tinic, 1988). Under Bayesian decision making previous information is used to give probabilities to likely outcomes. Decision making then proceeds on the basis of these probabilities. However, Tversky and Kahneman (1974) provide evidence that people do not always follow the laws of mathematical statistics. Rather, people rely on a limited number of heuristic principles, thereby reducing the complex tasks of assessing probabilities and predicting values to more simple judgemental operations. In general these heuristics are very useful but they may lead to serious systematic errors. If sharemarket investors apply heuristics when making investment decisions, then this could lead to systematic error in the sharemarket. The possibility of this error provides the impetus for the research presented in this paper. Following early speculation of overreaction in financial markets (Keynes, 1930), a substantial body of literature on overreaction has developed. DeBondt and Thaler (1985, 1987) were the first to attempt to use a behavioural principle i.e., overreaction to explain a market anomaly (why the volatility of stock increased after information releases). They sought to test two hypotheses, namely that: (1) extreme movements in stock prices would be followed by a subsequent adjustment in the opposite direction; (2) the more extreme the initial price movement, the greater the subsequent adjustment would be. DeBondt and Thaler s hypotheses differed from previous hypotheses on overreaction (Arrow, 1982; Einhorn and Hogarth, 1978) in that they sought to investigate whether overreaction was predictive. That is, they sought to establish whether initial overreaction was followed by a subsequent mean reversion of the stock price and - if this was the case - how quickly the reversion occured. Therefore, the initial assumption of DeBondt and Thaler (1985) implied that at sometime in the future the true situation is revealed to all - that is, Bayesian and non- Bayesian - investors. In order to test their hypotheses DeBondt and Thaler (1985) formed portfolios based on previous stockmarket performance and then subsequently measured the performance of these portfolios. The portfolios consisted of stocks that were considered winners and stocks that were considered losers. These stocks can be considered the equivalent of what Keynes 1

(1930) referred as good news (winners) and bad news (losers). However, the important distinction is that DeBondt and Thaler (1985) formed winner and loser portfolios conditional on past excess returns, rather than firm-generated informational variables such as earnings, used by Keynes (1930) and Arrow (1982). DeBondt and Thaler create a trading strategy that would be in violation of the weak-form EMH (efficient markets hypothesis) which states that all previous stock return information is fully reflected in the current stock price (Fama, 1970). DeBondt and Thaler (1985) hypothesised that the reason for this assymmetry was that winner shares had established a reputation that is generally based on several years of outstanding and widely publicised growth. This good reputation is not easily dissipated, and the company could be looking to consolidate on the position that it has gained. However, the loser shares have experienced years of disappointing results which leads to a stereotyping of the company. This stereotype takes time for the company to overcome. However, the expectations of the company are not as high as companies that perform well, therefore, the good results for loser companies would be treated with more optimism, while bad results for winner companies might initially be passed off by investors as an anomaly. It was for these reasons that DeBondt and Thaler (1985) believed that most of the abnormal returns occurred in the later years of the portfolio. Subsequent research by Fama and French (1988), Poterba and Summers (1988) and Keim and Stambaugh (1986) also find predictability in long-term stock-returns, corroborating the findings of DeBondt and Thaler (1985). In fact, Fama and French (1988) report that between 25 and 45 per cent of the variation in three to five year monthly returns could be predicted from past returns. Vermaelen and Verstringe (1986), Dark and Kato (1986), Clare and Thomas (1992), Alonso and Rubio (1990) and Stock (1990) all use the same empirical method as DeBondt and Thaler (1985) to document overreaction on the Belgian, Japanese, English, Spanish and German stock markets respectively. Dark and Kato (1986) find that the three year returns for loser portfolios exceed the comparable winner portfolios by, on average, 70 per cent. These studies present compelling evidence that the overreaction effect is not isolated to the United States. 2

The aim of this paper is to investigate the overreaction effect on the New Zealand Stock Exchange and in doing so provide evidence as to the efficiency of the local sharemarket. 1 From the preceeding studies we derived the following hypotheses. H1 can be thought of as a directional effect hypothesis, whereas H2 can be thought of as a magnitude effect hypothosis: H1: Extreme movements in price will be followed by subsequent adjustments in the opposite direction. H2: The more extreme the initial movement the more extreme the subsequent adjustment will be. The small firm effect A widely investigated anomaly in the area of sharemarket efficiency is the small firm effect (Pettengill and Jordan, 1990). In essence the small firm effect states that investments in a portfolio of small firms yield greater returns than large firms, even following adjustments for risk (Chan, 1988). It has been proposed that overreaction does not exist as it is subsumed by the small firm effect (Zarowin, 1990). The rationale for this is that portfolios of losers are typically comprised of stocks of smaller firms than are portfolios of winners. Thus in order to ascertain whether there is an independent overreaction effect, a size adjustment is necessary (Zarowin, 1990; Reinganum, 1992; Kryzanowski and Zhang 1992). However, DeBondt and Thaler (1987) have debated the small firm effect, feeling that their own requirement that 85 subsequent returns must be available shows sample bias towards large, established firms. Subsequent studies (see Chopra, Lakoniskok and Ritter, 1992) have confirmed an overreaction effect independent of the size effect. Therefore, our third hypothesis is that: 1 It has been noted that The NZSE is generally accepted by investment analysts to be efficient in the semistrong form, despite a public opinion survey which showed that forty-four per cent of respondents believe that the sharemarket is manipulated, compared to sixteen per cent who did not. A total of seventy-seven per cent said that big investors can manipulate the market, and only three per cent stated that all shareholders were treated fairly : B. Birchall, The New Zealand Stock Exchange and the Securities Markets in New Zealand in G. Walker and B. Fisse, eds., Securities Regulation in Australia and New Zealand (1994), 113, 123. 3

H3: Even after firm size has been controlled for, there will exist a persistent overreaction in the New Zealand Stock Exchange. 2. Method In order to test the propositions of overreaction, all New Zealand Stock Exchange companies were examined over a twenty year period (August 1975 to July 1995). The following model was applied to all the share price data in the sample to determine the returns on the stock: R jt P ln P jt jt 1 where: R jt is the monthly return for month t (including dividends) P jt is the share price on month t P jt-1 is the share price on month t-1 t is the month. 100 (1) Therefore, the returns data would approximate the monthly percentage increase or decrease experienced by the stock. The arithmetic mean of these returns provides a monthly market return that can be used for the purposes of analysis. Once this market return had been created then the analysis of the abnormal returns can take place. The abnormal returns are then given by Equation 2: ujt Rjt Rmt (2) where: u jt is the abnormal monthly return for month t (including dividends) R jt is the share return for month t R mt is the equally weighted market return for month t-1 Equation 2 presents a simple market adjustment procedure that does not involve relative weightings of the stocks to the index. That is, the adjustment made is the same for all stocks. The simplicity of the model means that it does not suffer from any of the methodological drawbacks involved in applying beta to stock that are associated with other models such as CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model). Furthermore, DeBondt and Thaler (1985) state that... whichever of the... residuals are used [either CAPM or simple market adjustments], the results of the empirical analysis are similar and that the choice does not effect our main conclusions (pp.796-797). Therefore, the analysis proceeds based on the residuals produced by Equation 2. 4

In order to test for long-run overreaction a similar method to that of DeBondt and Thaler (1985) was used. This is achieved through the following procedures: For every stock j, starting in July 1978, (the portfolio formation period, months 1 through 36) (t = 0) the cumulative excess returns Cu j = for the prior 36 months are computed. The step is repeated 15 times for each year until July 1992, therefore, the three year formation periods overlap. On each of the relevant portfolio formation dates (July 1978, July 1979,..., July 1992), the Cu j s are ranked from low to high and portfolios are formed. Firms in the top 6 stocks are assigned to the winner portfolio W; firms in the bottom 6 stocks to the loser portfolio L. 2 t 0 u t 35 jt Thus, the portfolios are formed conditional upon past excess return behaviour prior to t = 0, the portfolio formation date. For both portfolios in each of the 15 overlapping three-year periods (n = 1,..., N; N = 15), starting in August 1978 and finishing in August 1992, the cumulative average returns of all securities in the portfolio, for the next 36 months (the test period, months 85 through 120), i.e., from t = 1 through t = 36, are computed. This provides CAR W,n,t and CAR L,n,t. If a security s return was missing in a month subsequent to the portfolio formation then, from that moment on, the stock is permanently dropped from the portfolio and the CAR is an average of the available residual returns. This, therefore, implies a rebalancing of the portfolio. If the stock dropped out because of bankruptcy then the returns were recorded as minus 100 per cent. That is, no returns were further available. Then using the CAR s from the 16 test periods, average CAR s were calculated for both portfolios and each month from t = 1 to t = 36. These were denoted ACAR W,t and ACAR L,t. The overreaction hypothesis then predicted that, when t > 0, ACAR W,t < 0 and ACAR L,t > 0, so that, by implication a portfolio that went long on losers and short on winners would give returns greater than zero, i.e., (ACAR L,t - ACAR W,t ) > 0. Conrad and Kaul (1993) challenged the method employed by DeBondt and Thaler (1985), stating that their long-term strategies suffer from methodological drawbacks that spuriously inflate their profitability (p.40). Conrad and Kaul (1993) demonstrate that the measurement 2 While DeBondt and Thaler (1985) use 35 stocks in each of their winner and loser portfolios, the small number of stocks listed on the New Zealand Stock Exchange would preclude this level from the study. The use of 6 stocks is considered proportional, with reference to the New Zealand Stock Exchange, to the 35 used in DeBondt and Thaler, with reference to the New York Stock Exchange. 5

errors in observed prices due to bid-ask errors, non-synchronous trading, and/or price discreteness, lead to substantial spurious returns to the long-term zero investment contrarian strategies because single-period returns are upwardly biased. In order to correct for this error Conrad and Kaul advocate the use of a buy and hold strategy over the three year subsequent period. Therefore, this technique is also used in this study as a comparison to the method of DeBondt and Thaler. 3. Results 3.1 Preliminary analysis The results of the tests, as developed from the DeBondt and Thaler method, are shown in Figure 1. Over the past twenty years, loser portfolios are shown to outperform the market by an average of 34.5 per cent, thirty-six months after portfolio formation. In contrast, the winners outperform the market by only 1.5 per cent. Furthermore, for most of the three year periods after formation (27 out of 36 months) the winners actually underperform the market. These results appear to support the contention of DeBondt and Thaler (1985) that extreme movements in share price will be followed by subsequent adjustments in the opposite direction. The other notable aspect of the results is the apparent agreement with Graham s (1959) proposition that the interval required for a substantial underevaluation to correct itself averages approximately one and a half to two and a half years. The results show that the majority of the loser returns occur between the first year and the second and a half year. 6

35.00 30.00 25.00 20.00 15.00 10.00 Loser Winner 5.00 0.00-5.00 July Sept Nov Jan March May July Sept Nov Jan March May July Sept Nov Jan March May Figure 1 Cumulative average residuals for winner and loser portfolios of six stock with the test period lasting 36 months after portfolio formation While these initial results appear to provide compelling evidence of overreaction amongst loser shares on the New Zealand Stock Exchange, the results may be attributable to an upward drift bias. Therefore, we decided to contrast these results with those of a buy and hold strategy - see Table 1. The results of this analysis demonstrate that the overreaction experienced by losers under a buy and hold strategy would be even greater than that experienced following the DeBondt and Thaler method. This difference is apparent in each of the three years for which data were analysed. Thus, the cumulation of average returns actually lessens the returns experienced by losers. This directly contrasts the assertion of Conrad and Kaul (1993) who hold that the loser returns are caused by an upward drift in the stocks caused by the cumulation method. (The use of cumulative average returns in the New Zealand Stock Exchange actually lessens the overreaction effect, biasing the results in favour of market efficiency). The winner portfolios, however, actually experience smaller negative results for year's one and two and a slightly smaller positive result at the end of the third year, although the differences are not significant. 7

Table 1 Average returns for winner and loser portfolios and portfolio differences at the end of years 1, 2, and 3, for the Conrad and Kaul method and the DeBondt and Thaler method 3 Returns Method Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Conrad and Kaul Loser 14.2** 30.3** 40.7** Winner -1.4-1.6 1.4 Difference 15.6** 31.9** 39.3** DeBondt and Thaler Loser 11.7* 25.3** 34.5** Winner -1.6-2.1 1.5 Difference 13.3* 27.4** 33.0** Note: Conrad and Kaul denotes a buy and hold strategy based on a number of years after formation; DeBondt and Thaler denotes A cumulative average residual strategy based on monthly returns; *denotes significance at the 10 % level, and **denotes significance at the 5 % level. 3.2 The directional effect The directional effect, refers to hypothesis H1 developed previously and - as already mentioned - is supported by the findings. However, the results are worthy of elucidation as the winners do start to experience a reversal of fortune toward the end of the three year period investigated. Furthermore, the actual negative returns experienced by losers are not vastly significant and never reach in excess of negative 2.5 per cent. This suggests that the winner shares may not be prone to overreaction, as the loser shares obviously are. Thus the results indicate that the directional effect may only exist for loser shares in the New Zealand Stock Exchange. However, this only minimally effects the findings, as the lack of short sales in the New Zealand Stock Exchange means that no trading strategy can be developed to exploit any potential downside falls in the winner stock. It could be this lack of short sales that actually causes the lack of return reversal in winner stocks. 3 The buy and hold returns are calculated separately at the end of each year. Therefore, the first year represents the average of the buy and hold returns in the first year after formation. The second year represents the returns for the first two years from a buy and hold strategy that would buy the shares immediately after the formation period and sell them at the end of the second year. Similarly, the three year strategy would buy the shares after formation and sell them at the end of the third year. So the yearly returns are not cumulated but separately assessed. 8

3.3 The magnitude effect The magnitude effect is perhaps of the most interest in this study. The hypothesis (H2) states that more extreme initial movements will be followed by more extreme adjustments. The results demonstrate that when winners and losers are compared that this is not the scenario. The average initial cumulative returns of winners is 99 per cent, whereas the average initial cumulative returns of losers is -51 per cent. In the first instance winners almost double in value, while losers lose over half their value. Therefore, a loose interpretation of these results is that the winners and losers moved by the same amount only in opposite directions. Given the similarity in initial movements it is reasonable to expect that the overreaction present in both the winner and losers would be similar. Rather, as seen before, overreaction is present only in losers. Given the asymmetry of overreaction in New Zealand, the magnitude effect can only be studied with respect to the loser shares. In order to test for the magnitude effect, with respect to the loser portfolios, two techniques are employed. First, the formation period is shortened, so that abnormal returns experienced are greater relative to time. Second, the number of stocks that qualify for entry into the portfolio is reduced, hence only those stocks with higher abnormal returns will be selected. The results of each technique are presented in Table 2. The results confirm the magnitude hypothesis - that is, as the loser returns become more extreme the subsequent returns also increase in magnitude. Furthermore, this increase occurs both when the formation period is shortened, and when the number of stock in each portfolio is decreased. However, the reduction stock contained within each portfolio may not be as sound a method as reducing the time span, as the portfolios may be left containing only highly volatile stock. The use of three stocks in long-run portfolios is low when practitioners suggest the use of at least 30 stocks in a long-run market portfolio (Reilly, 1989). 9

Table 2 Average returns for winner and loser portfolios and portfolio differences for differing formation strategies RETURNS (%) Formation Strategy Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 3 Year Formation Winner -1.6-2.1 1.5 Loser 11.7* 25.3** 34.5** Difference 13.3* 27.4** 33.0** 1 Year Formation 4 Winner -2.2-3.5-0.7 Loser 12.3* 27.6** 38.2** Difference 14.5* 31.1** 38.9** Three stock per portfolio 5 Winner -3.1-3.8-4.6 Loser 16.5** 40.3** 55.1** Difference 19.6** 44.1** -59.7** Note: *denotes significance at the 10 per cent level, **denotes significance at the 5 per cent level. 3.4 The small firm effect In order to test the hypothesis H3, i.e., that small firms featured predominantly in the overreaction sample a simple test was devised. The test coded all 180 stock from the 15 winner and 15 loser portfolios with a 1 if they were in the top forty firms, by market capitalisation, at the time of formation. Otherwise the firms were coded 0 to indicate that they were small firms. Therefore, a 1 represented a large firm and 0 a small firm. The columns of ones and zeros were then summed for each the winners and losers. If the sum of the columns was greater than 45 then this would suggest a predominance of large firms, and vice versa for a sum of less than 45. The scores were for winners was 28 and for losers 24; that is, the winner portfolios contained 28 large firms and 62 small firms, while the loser portfolios contained 24 large firms and 66 small firms. Therefore, apparently small firms dominate the sample used in this study. Moreover, the predominance of small firms in both the winner and loser portfolios suggests that small firms probably do not cause the overreaction found in the loser shares. In order to test this hypothesis, the large firms, those denoted by a one were analysed separately and the returns after formation were plotted in Figure 2. The results demonstrate that the large firms exhibit classic mean reverting tendencies typical of overreaction. The losers, in the first year 4 5 The average abnormal return value of the loser and winner portfolio formation periods are -57.8 per cent and 112.6 per cent respectively. The average abnormal return value of the loser and winner portfolio formation periods are -65.4 per cent and 128.9 per cent respectively. 10

after formation, outperformed the market by over 30 per cent. Additionally the winners actually significantly underperform the market in the first year after portfolio formation. These results indicate that overreaction is more significant among large firms in the New Zealand Share Market although the portion of large firms experiencing overreaction is greatly less than small firms. Therefore, the results also confirm the hypothesis H3 that states that even after firm size has been controlled for, there will exist a persistent overreaction in the New Zealand Stock Exchange. 40.00 30.00 20.00 10.00 Winners Losers 0.00 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35-10.00-20.00 Figure 2 Cumulative average residuals for high market capitalisation winner and loser stocks with the test period lasting 36 months after portfolio formation 11

4. Summary The results of this research indicate that New Zealand can be included among those countries that exhibit long-run overreaction in their stock exchanges. However, only losers experience significant overreaction; winner portfolios show almost no abnormal market returns. Consistent with the literature it is also shown that the more extreme the initial movements the greater the subsequent rebound. Furthermore, overreaction is shown to exist independently of the small-firm and seasonal effects, however, there is a predominance of small firms in both the winner and loser portfolios. The results also show that the methodological criticisms of the DeBondt and Thaler method by Conrad and Kaul may be unfounded, as a buy and hold strategy actually yields higher returns than the cumulation of average residuals. Furthermore, the employment of the buy and hold strategy would over the last twenty years have yielded the investor abnormal returns of, on average, 39.7 per cent after transaction costs. 12

References Alonso, A. and Rubio, G. (1990). Overreaction in the Spanish equity market. Journal of Banking and Finance, 14, 2-3, 469-81. Arrow, K.J. (1982). Risk perception in psychology and economics. Economic Inquiry, 20, 3, 1-9. Brown, K.C., Harlow, W.V. and Tinic, S.C. (1988) Risk aversion, uncertain information and market efficiency. Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 2, 355-385. Chan, K.C. (1988). On the contrarian investment strategy. Journal of Business, 61, 2, 147-163. Chopra, N., Lakonishok, J. and Ritter, J.R. (1992). Measuring abnormal performance: Do stocks overreact? Journal of Financial Economics, 31, 2, 235-268 Clare, A. and Thomas, S. (1992). Winners and losers: UK evidence for the overreaction hypothesis. University of Southampton Discussion Paper in Economics and Econometrics, 9229, November. Conrad, J. and Kaul, G. (1993). Long-term market overreaction or biases in computed returns? Journal of Finance, 48, 1, 39-63. Dark, F.H. and Kato, K. (1986). Stock Market Overreaction in the Japanese stock market. Working Paper, Iowa State University. DeBondt, W.F.M. and Thaler, R. (1987). Further evidence of stock market overreaction and seasonality. Journal of Finance, 42, 3, 557-581. DeBondt, W.F.M. and Thaler, R. (1985). Does the stock market overreact? Journal of Finance, 40, 3, 793-805. Einhorn, H. and Hogarth, R.M. (1978). Confidence in judgement: persistence of the illusion of validity. Psychological Review, 85, 3, 395-416. Fama, E. (1970). Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25, 2, 383-417. Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (1988). Permanent and temporary components of stock prices. Journal of Political Economy, 96, 2, 246-273. Graham, B. (1959). The intelligent investor: A book of practical counsel. New York: Harper & Bros. Publications. Keim, D.B. and Stambaugh, R.F. (1986). Predicting returns in the stock and bond markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 17, 4, 357-390. Keynes, J.M. (1930). A treatise on money, Vol. 2, London, MacMillan. 13

Kryzanowski, L. and Zhang, H. (1992). The contrarian investment strategy strategy does not work in Canadian markets. Journal of Financial and Quantiative Analysis, 27, 3, 383-395. Pettengill, G.N. and Jordan, B. (1990). The overreaction hypothesis, firm size and stock market seasonality. Journal of Portfolio Management, 16, 3, 60-64. Poterba, J.M. and Summers, L.H. (1988). Mean Reversion in Stock Prices. Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 1, 27-59. Reilly, F.K. (1989). Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management, third ed. Dryden Press, Florida. Reinganum, M. (1992). A revival of the small firm effect. Journal of Portfolio Management, 18, 3, 56-62. Stock, D. (1990). Winner and Loser anomalies in the German stock market. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 146, 3, 518-29. Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgement under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185, 1124-31. Vermaelen, T. and Verstringe, M. (1986). Do Belgains overreact? Working Paper, Catholic University of Lovain, Belgium. Zarowin, P. (1990). Size, seasonality and stock market overreaction. Journal of Financial and Quantiative Analysis, 25, 1, 113-125. 14