Heavy-tailedness and dependence: implications for economic decisions, risk management and financial markets

Similar documents
EXTREME CYBER RISKS AND THE NON-DIVERSIFICATION TRAP

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets

Measuring Risk. Review of statistical concepts Probability distribution. Review of statistical concepts Probability distribution 2/1/2018

Business Statistics 41000: Probability 3

Interplay of Asymptotically Dependent Insurance Risks and Financial Risks

INDIAN INSTITUTE OF SCIENCE STOCHASTIC HYDROLOGY. Lecture -5 Course Instructor : Prof. P. P. MUJUMDAR Department of Civil Engg., IISc.

Asymptotic methods in risk management. Advances in Financial Mathematics

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 8

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

Asset Allocation Model with Tail Risk Parity

Non-Diversification Traps in Markets for Catastrophic Risk

Lecture 1: The Econometrics of Financial Returns

Some Characteristics of Data

Probability and Random Variables A FINANCIAL TIMES COMPANY

Dependence Modeling and Credit Risk

Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Online Appendix for Variable Rare Disasters: An Exactly Solved Framework for Ten Puzzles in Macro-Finance. Theory Complements

Lecture 6: Non Normal Distributions

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

MEASURING PORTFOLIO RISKS USING CONDITIONAL COPULA-AR-GARCH MODEL

Basic Procedure for Histograms

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Operational Risk Quantification and Insurance

Insurance Equilibrium with Monoline and Multiline Insurers

Case Study: Heavy-Tailed Distribution and Reinsurance Rate-making

Analysis of truncated data with application to the operational risk estimation

CHAPTER 5. Introduction to Risk, Return, and the Historical Record INVESTMENTS BODIE, KANE, MARCUS. McGraw-Hill/Irwin

EE365: Risk Averse Control

Value at Risk with Stable Distributions

Estimating Value at Risk of Portfolio: Skewed-EWMA Forecasting via Copula

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

Cambridge University Press Risk Modelling in General Insurance: From Principles to Practice Roger J. Gray and Susan M.

ECO220Y Continuous Probability Distributions: Normal Readings: Chapter 9, section 9.10

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Homework Assignments

SYSM 6304 Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 2: Fitting Distributions to Data

CHAPTER II LITERATURE STUDY

CPSC 540: Machine Learning

Chapter 4: Asymptotic Properties of MLE (Part 3)

Statistics for Business and Economics

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Economics 424/Applied Mathematics 540. Final Exam Solutions

Lecture 17: More on Markov Decision Processes. Reinforcement learning

Chapter 5. Continuous Random Variables and Probability Distributions. 5.1 Continuous Random Variables

Risk measures: Yet another search of a holy grail

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 9 Extreme Value Theory

Financial Models with Levy Processes and Volatility Clustering

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Extreme Return-Volume Dependence in East-Asian. Stock Markets: A Copula Approach

Modeling Co-movements and Tail Dependency in the International Stock Market via Copulae

Financial Economics 4: Portfolio Theory

A Theory of Asset Prices based on Heterogeneous Information and Limits to Arbitrage

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Probability Weighted Moments. Andrew Smith

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Lecture Notes 6. Assume F belongs to a family of distributions, (e.g. F is Normal), indexed by some parameter θ.

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

CHAPTER 5. Introduction to Risk, Return, and the Historical Record INVESTMENTS BODIE, KANE, MARCUS

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Mathematics in Finance

CPSC 540: Machine Learning

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Modeling of Price. Ximing Wu Texas A&M University

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Outline. Simple, Compound, and Reduced Lotteries Independence Axiom Expected Utility Theory Money Lotteries Risk Aversion

Value at Risk and Self Similarity

ADVANCED OPERATIONAL RISK MODELLING IN BANKS AND INSURANCE COMPANIES

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

Project Proposals for MS&E 444. Lisa Borland and Jeremy Evnine. Evnine and Associates, Inc. April 2008

Chapter 5 Finite Difference Methods. Math6911 W07, HM Zhu

University of California Berkeley

Financial Econometrics (FinMetrics04) Time-series Statistics Concepts Exploratory Data Analysis Testing for Normality Empirical VaR

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk

Financial Risk Management

GRANULARITY ADJUSTMENT FOR DYNAMIC MULTIPLE FACTOR MODELS : SYSTEMATIC VS UNSYSTEMATIC RISKS

A market risk model for asymmetric distributed series of return

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Microeconomic Theory III Spring 2009

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics

Linda Allen, Jacob Boudoukh and Anthony Saunders, Understanding Market, Credit and Operational Risk: The Value at Risk Approach

The Real World: Dealing With Parameter Risk. Alice Underwood Senior Vice President, Willis Re March 29, 2007

Fatness of Tails in Risk Models

X i = 124 MARTINGALES

Lecture notes on risk management, public policy, and the financial system. Credit portfolios. Allan M. Malz. Columbia University

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid

Optimal Stopping. Nick Hay (presentation follows Thomas Ferguson s Optimal Stopping and Applications) November 6, 2008

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Multiline Insurance with Costly Capital and Limited Liability

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

BONDS AND OTHER INSTRUMENTS WITH PAYMENTS LINKED TO EXPLICIT EVENTS ARE GROW-

Introduction to Computational Finance and Financial Econometrics Introduction to Portfolio Theory

Idiosyncratic Risk and Higher-Order Cumulants: A Note

The Black-Scholes Model

Transcription:

Heavy-tailedness and dependence: implications for economic decisions, risk management and financial markets Rustam Ibragimov Department of Economics Harvard University Based on joint works with Johan Walden and Dwight Jaffee (Haas School of Business, University of California at Berkeley)

1 Dependence vs. marginals in finance and risk management Heavy-tailedness in portfolio choice and value at risk theory Empirical evidence (Non-)diversification for bounded risks 2 Implications for markets for catastrophic risks Equilibria in reinsurance markets for catastrophe riks Diversification game Non-diversification traps: summary 3 From independence to dependence through copulas What is wrong with variances & correlations? Copulas and dependence 4 Conclusion

Dependence vs. marginals Fundamental problems in finance & risk management: Solution is affected by both Properties of marginal distributions (heavy-tailedness, skewness) Dependence (cross- and auto-covariances, mixing, long-range dependence, positive or negative dependence, dependence asymmetry)

Heavy-tailedness in portfolio choice and value at risk theory Portfolio choice and value at risk (VaR) theory Marginal effects under independence: degree of heavy-tailedness of risks or returns (not extremely heavy-tailed vs. extremely heavy-tailed) = Opposite solutions Certain dependent risks: diversification pays off even under extreme heavy-tailedness in marginals Different solutions: Positive vs. negative dependence

Value at risk (VaR) VaR Risk X ; positive values = losses Loss probability q VaR q (X ) = z : P(X > z) = q Risks X 1,..., X n Z w = n i=1 w ix i : return on portfolio with weights w = (w 1,..., w n ) Problem of interest: s.t. w i 0, n i=1 w i = 1 MinimizeVaR q (Z w ) When diversification decrease in portfolio riskiness (VaR)?

Problem: Minimize VaR q (Z w ) s.t. w i 0, n i=1 w i = 1 w = ( 1 n,..., 1 n) : equal weights; most diversified w = ( 1, 0,..., 0 ) : one risk; least diversified Normal (light-tailed) case: X 1,..., X n i.i.d. N (0, σ) Z w = 1 n n i=1 X i = d 1 n X 1 = 1 n Z w VaR q (Z w ) = 1 n VaR q (Z w ) < VaR q (Z w ) VaR q (Z w ) : as n (Diversification ) For all w and fixed n, VaR q (Z w ) VaR q (Z w ) VaR q (Z w ) Optimal choice is w = ( 1 n,..., 1 n) (full diversification)

Extremely heavy-tailed (Lévy) case X 1,..., X n i.i.d. Lévy distribution with density f (x) = σ 2π x 3/2 exp( 1 2x ) for x > 0; f (x) = 0 for x 0 Lévy distribution: α stable with α = 1/2 Main properties of stable distributions: X S α (σ) : symmetric stable distribution, α (0, 2] CF: E(e ixx ) = exp { σ α x α} Normal N (0, σ): α = 2 Cauchy: α = 1, f (x) = σ π(σ 2 +x 2 ) Lévy: α = 1/2, support [0, ) Power law tails: P( X > x) C x α α (0, 2) : heavy-tailedness index Moments E X p : finite iff p < α Infinite first moment for α < 1; infinite variances for α < 2

Extremely heavy-tailed (Lévy) case X 1,..., X n i.i.d. Lévy distribution with density f (x) = σ 2π x 3/2 exp( 1 2x ) for x > 0; f (x) = 0 for x 0 Z w = 1 n n i=1 X i = d [ n i=1 ( 1 n )1/2] 2 X1 = nx 1 = nz w VaR q (Z w ) = nvar q (Z w ) > VaR q (Z w ) VaR q (Z w ) : as n (Diversification ) For all w and fixed n, VaR q (Z w ) VaR q (Z w ) VaR q (Z w ) Optimal choice is w = ( 1, 0,..., 0 ) invest only into one risk: no diversification Heavy-tailedness (marginals) matters: diversification = opposite effects on portfolio riskiness

Heavy-tailedness & portfolio diversification X 1,..., X n i.i.d. α stable with α > 1: Power law tails: P( X > x) C x α with α (1, 2) Finite first moments: E X i < Diversification = Decrease in riskiness VaR q (Z w ) < VaR q (Z w ) < VaR q (Z w ) Optimal portfolio: w: most diversified; equal weights Worst portfolio: w: least diversified; one risk

Heavy-tailedness & portfolio diversification X 1,..., X n i.i.d. α stable with α < 1: Extremely heavy power law tails: P( X > x) C α (0, 1) x α with Infinite first moments: E X i = Diversification = Increase in riskiness! VaR q (Z w ) < VaR q (Z w ) < VaR q (Z w ) Optimal portfolio: w: least diversified; one risk Worst portfolio: w: most diversified; equal weights

What happens for intermediate heavy-tails? A very specific and uninteresting case of α = 1 X 1,..., X n i.i.d. stable with α = 1: Cauchy distribution Density f (x) = σ π(σ 2 +x 2 ) Heavy power law tails: P( X > x) C x Infinite first moment Z w = n i=1 w ix i = d X 1 w = (w 1,..., w n ) : w i 0, Diversification: no effect at all!

A tale of two tails Simulated data from Normal, Cauchy and Levy distributions, n=25 Normal Cauchy α=1 Levy α=1/2 5 10 15 20 25 Figure: Heavy-tailed distributions: more extreme observations

A tale of two tails 0.5 0.45 0.4 Light vs. heavy tails Cauchy distributiion Levy distribution α=1/2 Normal distribution α=1 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Figure: Tails of Cauchy distributions are heavier than those of normal distributions. Tails of Lévy distributions are heavier than those of Cauchy or normal distributions.

Summary so far: Heavy-tailedness and diversification "Value" of a portfolio A. Light-tailed i.i.d. Zi with α>1. Example: Traditional situation with normal Zi C. Specific boundary case: i.i.d. Cauchy Z i with α=1 B.Extremely heavy-tailed i.i.d. Zi with α<1. Example: Levy distribution with α=1/2 1 10 70 100 Number of risks in portfolio, n Figure: Value of diversification. A: Traditional case: Diversification pays for light-tailed risks. B: Extremely heavy-tailed risks: value always decreases with diversification. C: Cauchy risks with tail index α = 1 : diversification has no effect on the portfolio value at risk.

Empirical evidence Many economic & financial time series: heavy-tailed distributions with power law tails: P( X > x) C x α Returns from technological innovations: α << 1 (infinite first moment) Loss distributions of a number of operational risks: α < 1 Economic losses from earthquakes: α [0.6, 1.5], interval contains the threshold 1 (calculations based on seismic theory) Economic losses from hurricanes: α 1.56; α 2.49 Profit in motion pictures: 1 < α < 2 (finite mean, infinite variance) Firm sizes, sizes of largest mutual funds, city sizes: α 1 Returns on many stocks & stock indices: α (2, 4) (finite variance, infinite fourth moment)

Which world (α > 1 or α < 1) we are in? One may argue that all the economic, financial and insurance variables observed are bounded Framework of stable distributions: robust to the concerns (Ibragimov and Walden, 2007) Same VaR results: valid for large class of distributions with bounded support Diversification may fail if the number of risks available is small comparing to the length of support of risks Contrast with unbounded case: Number of risks available enters equation

Non-diversification for bounded risks Risk Z Value at risk and safety-first Roy s (1952) safety-first: z: disaster level Value at risk: q : loss probability P(Z > z) min VaR q [Z] min

Non-diversification for bounded risks Start with, as before, i.i.d. extremely heavy-tailed X i with Lévy distributions with α = 1/2 or any stable distribution with α < 1 (recall that diversification fails for X i s) Define A-truncated versions of Z i s: Y i (A) = X i I ( X i A) Y i (A) = X i if X i A Y i (A) = 0 if X i > A Z w = n i=1 w ix i : return on portfolio of unbounded risks X 1,..., X n Y w (A) = n i=1 w iy i (A): return on portfolio of bounded risks Y 1 (A),..., Y n (A) Risk holder problem: min P ( n i=1 w iy i (A) > z ) (Bounded) (disaster probability)

(Non-)diversification for bounded risks n 2 and disaster level z > 0 sufficiently large threshold A = A(n, z) (depends on n, z): Return on portfolio with equal weights w = (1/n, 1/n,..., 1/n) (fully diversified portfolio) Y w (A) = n i=1 1 n Y i(a) : more risky than of only one risk Y 1 (A) Comparisons of probabilities of disaster: P ( n i=1 1 n Y i(a) > z ) }{{} Disaster probability for diversified portfolio > P ( Y 1 (A) > z ) }{{}... for undiversified portfolio

(Non-)diversification for bounded risks Simple limiting argument We know diversification fails for X i : P ( n i=1 1 n X i > z ) }{{} Disaster probability for diversified portfolio Y i (A) = X i I ( X i A): truncations of X i s Y i (A) d X i as A > P ( X 1 > z ) }{{}... for undiversified portfolio Starting with some threshold A, the inequalities will hold for bounded Y i (A) P ( n i=1 1 n Y i(a) > z ) }{{} Disaster probability for diversified portfolio > P ( Y 1 (A) > z ) }{{}... for undiversified portfolio

Summary so far: Diversification for heavy-tailed and bounded distributions "Value" of a portfolio A. Light-tailed i.i.d. Zi with α>1. Example: Traditional situation with normal Zi D. Bounded Zi C. Specific boundary case: i.i.d. Cauchy Z i with α=1 B.Extremely heavy-tailed i.i.d. Z i with α<1. Example: Levy distribution with α=1/2 1 10 70 100 Number of risks in portfolio, n Figure: N = 10 risks/insurer; M = 7 insurers D: Individual/non-diversification corners vs insurer and reinsurer equilibrium

Implications for markets for catastrophic risks Equilibria in re-insurance markets for catastrophe risks (Ibragimov, Jaffee and Walden, 2009, RFS) A diversification equilibrium with full risk pooling for normally distributed (light-tailed) risks No risk pooling & no insurance or reinsurance activity (market collapse) for extremely heavy-tailed cat risks Intermediate cases (heavy tails): both Diversification equilibria, in which insurers offer catastrophe coverage and reinsure their risks Non-diversification equilibria with no insurance or re-insurance A coordination problem must be solved to shift from the bad to the good equilibrium Government regulations or well functioning capital markets

1st example: full risk pooling with normally distributed risks 1 s=4 s=5 0.9 s=3 s=2 0.8 0.7 s=1 0.6 U(z j,s ) 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 j Assume: Results: 1 s M (= 5) insurers If M 1 insurers are pooling, N (= 20) risks/insurer so will Mth 1 j Ns total risks i.i.d. normal X i If no insurers pool, CARA utility, Unlimited liability each still has N risks z j,s = ( j i=1 X i) /s

2nd example: Bernoulli-Lévy distribution with limited liability 1 0.5 s=5 Expected utility, U(z j,s ) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 s=2 s=3 s=4 2.5 s=1 3 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Number of risks, j Assume: Limited liability: maximum loss (k = 80) M = 5 insurers N (= 20) max risks/insurer u(x) = (x + k) 3/4 z j,s = ( j i=1 X i) /s Results: If insurers can coordinate, they can reach MN = 100 reinsurance equilibrium But if not, each insurer reverts to the N = 0 corner

Results for markets for catastrophic risks Absence of non-diversification traps: 1st example assumptions (light tails, normal) no non-diversification trap Mean-variance model no non-diversification trap 2nd moment finite, no limited liability no genuine non-diversification traps Existence of non-diversification traps: 2nd example assumptions genuine diversification trap Genuine non-diversification traps can occur only with fat tails (infinite 2nd moments) and limited liability

Implications for markets for catastrophic risks Catastrophic risks have many features favorable to the provision of insurance Generally independent over risk types and geography Few issues of asymmetric information at the risk level So a complete failure of these markets is puzzling We have shown that market failures (non-diversification traps) may arise when risks are fat-tailed and there is limited liability Diversification may not be beneficial for the single insurer, although a full reinsurance equilibrium may exist. Government programs (or diversified equity owners) may allow the system to reach the full diversification outcome

Dependence matters: Extreme examples MinimizeVaR q (w 1 X 1 + w 2 X 2 ) s.t. w 1, w 2 0, w 1 + w 2 = 1 Independence: Optimal portfolio: ( w 1, w 2 ) = ( 1 2, 1 2 ) (diversified) if α > 1 (not extremely heavy-tailed, finite means) ( w 1, w 2 ) = (1, 0) (not diversified, one risk) if α < 1 (extremely heavy-tailed, infinite means)

Dependence matters: Extreme examples Extreme positive dependence: X 1 = X 2 (a.s.) comonotonic risks VaR q (w 1 X 1 + w 2 X 2 ) = VaR q (X 1 ) w Diversification: no effect at all (similar to Cauchy) regardless of heavy-tailedness Extreme negative dependence X 1 = X 2 (a.s.) countermonotonic risks VaR q (w 1 X 1 + w 2 X 2 ) = (w 1 w 2 )VaR q (X 1 ) Optimal portfolio: ( w 1, w 2 ) = (1, 0) (not diversified, one risk) regardless of heavy-tailedness Optimal portfolio choice: affected by both dependence & properties of marginals

Copulas and dependence Main idea: separate effects of dependence from effects of marginals What matters more in portfolio choice: heavy-tailedness & skewness or (positive or negative) dependence? Copulas: functions that join together marginal cdf s to form multidimensional cdf

Copulas and dependence Sklar s theorem Risks X, Y : Joint cdf H XY (x, y) = P(X x, Y y): affected by dependence and by marginal cdf s F X (x) = P(X x) and G Y (x) = P(Y y) C XY (u, v) : copula of X, Y : H XY (x, y) = C XY }{{} dependence ( ) FX (x), G Y (y) }{{} marginals Similar definition: arbitrary number of risks X 1,..., X n F X, G Y : properties of marginals: heavy-tailedness, skewness, moments, range C XY : captures all dependence between risks X and Y

Copulas: Main properties Advantages: Exists for any risks (correlation: finiteness of second moments) Characterizes all dependence properties Flexibility in dependence modeling Asymmetric dependence: Crashes vs. booms Positive vs. negative dependence Independence: Nested as a particular case: Product copula, particular values of parameter(s) Extreme dependence: X = Y or X = Y extreme copulas; dependence in C XY varies in between

Conclusion Fundamental problems in economics, finance & risk management: Properties of marginal distributions Dependence Portfolio choice in value at risk theory: Key factors: Index of heavy-tailedness α, index of α symmetric distributions under dependence α > 1 : diversification typically preferable α < 1 : diversification typically fails Length of distribution support and number of risks available Diversification: Suboptimal if support large compared to number of risks

Conclusion Implications for re-insurance markets for catastrophe risks A diversification equilibrium with full risk pooling for normally distributed (light-tailed) risks No risk pooling & no insurance or reinsurance activity (market collapse) for extremely heavy-tailed cat risks Intermediate cases (heavy tails): both Diversification equilibria, in which insurers offer catastrophe coverage and reinsure their risks Non-diversification equilibria with no insurance or re-insurance A coordination problem must be solved to shift from the bad to the good equilibrium Government regulations or well functioning capital markets

Conclusion Copulas: convenient tool to account for both effects and to separate one from the other Separation of marginal effects from dependence: Key to Reduction of problems under dependence to independent case Sharp bounds on value at risk for financial portfolios & contingent claim (option) prices Estimation of co-movements in financial & insurance markets