Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control

Similar documents
für Mathematik in den Naturwissenschaften Leipzig

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

Control Improvement for Jump-Diffusion Processes with Applications to Finance

An Approximation for Credit Portfolio Losses

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Semi-Markov model for market microstructure and HFT

On worst-case investment with applications in finance and insurance mathematics

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Credit Risk using Time Changed Brownian Motions

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

High Frequency Trading in a Regime-switching Model. Yoontae Jeon

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

Hans-Fredo List Swiss Reinsurance Company Mythenquai 50/60, CH-8022 Zurich Telephone: Facsimile:

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

High-Frequency Trading in a Limit Order Book

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

Robust Portfolio Decisions for Financial Institutions

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

Optimal Switching Games for Emissions Trading

Liquidation of a Large Block of Stock

Optimal Order Placement

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Self-Exciting Corporate Defaults: Contagion or Frailty?

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery?

A Quadratic Gradient Equation for pricing Mortgage-Backed Securities

Forward Dynamic Utility

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Fourier Space Time-stepping Method for Option Pricing with Lévy Processes

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Part 3: Trust-region methods for unconstrained optimization. Nick Gould (RAL)

Optimal investments under dynamic performance critria. Lecture IV

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Optimal Execution: II. Trade Optimal Execution

Optimal Dividend Policy of A Large Insurance Company with Solvency Constraints. Zongxia Liang

Indifference fee rate 1

Contagion models with interacting default intensity processes

ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE

Mean-Quadratic Variation Portfolio Optimization: A desirable alternative to Time-consistent Mean-Variance Optimization?

Pricing early exercise contracts in incomplete markets

e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

Utility indifference valuation for non-smooth payoffs on a market with some non tradable assets

Economics 2010c: Lecture 4 Precautionary Savings and Liquidity Constraints

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets

American-style Puts under the JDCEV Model: A Correction

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling

Kim Weston (Carnegie Mellon University) Market Stability and Indifference Prices. 1st Eastern Conference on Mathematical Finance.

Saddlepoint Approximation Methods for Pricing. Financial Options on Discrete Realized Variance

Optimizing Portfolios

Large Deviations and Stochastic Volatility with Jumps: Asymptotic Implied Volatility for Affine Models

Anumericalalgorithm for general HJB equations : a jump-constrained BSDE approach

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Stat 260/CS Learning in Sequential Decision Problems. Peter Bartlett

Information Acquisition under Persuasive Precedent versus Binding Precedent (Preliminary and Incomplete)

Optimal Asset Allocation with Stochastic Interest Rates in Regime-switching Models

Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Dynamic pricing with diffusion models

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Part 2: Monopoly and Oligopoly Investment

X ln( +1 ) +1 [0 ] Γ( )

Real Options and Free-Boundary Problem: A Variational View

Discounted Optimal Stopping for Maxima of some Jump-Diffusion Processes

An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking

Bachelier Finance Society, Fifth World Congress London 19 July 2008

Mgr. Jakub Petrásek 1. May 4, 2009

Carnets d ordres pilotés par des processus de Hawkes

Optimum Thresholding for Semimartingales with Lévy Jumps under the mean-square error

Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Frictions

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Final exam solutions

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

NOTICE: This is the author s version of a work that was accepted for publication in Systems and Control Letters. Changes resulting from the

Risk minimizing strategies for tracking a stochastic target

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples

ESTIMATION OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS: MARKET VS. REPRESENTATIVE AGENT THEORY

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Lecture notes on risk management, public policy, and the financial system Credit risk models

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION

A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution.

Infinite Horizon Optimal Policy for an Inventory System with Two Types of Products sharing Common Hardware Platforms

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Online Appendix to Financing Asset Sales and Business Cycles

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Transcription:

Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Rüdiger Frey (joint work with Roland C. Seydel) Mathematisches Institut Universität Leipzig and MPI MIS Leipzig Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 (1) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 1

Overview Introduction 1 Introduction 2 Optimal Securitization Strategy The model Specific model inputs Solution of the Optimization Problem 3 Numerical Results (2) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 2

Introduction Securitization Consider a commercial bank lending to customers. In a securitization transaction the bank sells part of its loan portfolio to investors in a bond-like form, passing on part of the risk and return. Investor A Investor B Customer Bank CDO Investor C Potential benefits of securitization On the macro level: possibly mitigation of concentration risk and easier refinancing for banks On the micro level securitization can be an important risk management tool for commercial banks (reduction of leverage) Securitization is of course not problem-free but this is not our focus here. (3) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 3

Introduction Securitization ctd. It is not costless to securitize (sell) loans: An ABS transaction typically entails fixed costs: Rating agency fees, legal costs, time spent... The more you sell, the lower the price investors want to pay (liquidity and agency problems) Finding a good (optimal) securitization strategy is non-trivial... it is not optimal to sell all at once, but rather distributed over time;... it is not optimal to securitize all the time, but rather at discrete points in time. Conclusion. Determination of an optimal securitization strategy (for the bank) leads to a a dynamic optimization problem under fixed and variable transaction costs. apply impulse control methods. (4) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 4

Overview Optimal Securitization Strategy 1 Introduction 2 Optimal Securitization Strategy The model Specific model inputs Solution of the Optimization Problem 3 Numerical Results (5) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 5

The Agents Involved Optimal Securitization Strategy The model Bank s creditor Customers Bank ABS Investors Bank s shareholder (6) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 6

Optimal Securitization Strategy The model Modeling a commercial a bank ctd Consider a commercial bank solely engaged in lending business. Loan portfolio is homogeneous and loans to customers have maturity (perpetuities) with nominal 1. Starting point is the fundamental balance sheet equation assets = liabilities cash 1 cash> + loans = equity cash 1 cash< Refinancing through negative cash (short-term refinancing): Assume there are no liquidity problems! Loans Equity Cash > Loans Cash Cash < Cash Equity (7) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 7

Model dynamics Optimal Securitization Strategy The model State variables of the model: Nominal loan exposure L t =: X 1 t. Cash balance C t =: Xt 2 (positive or negative). Note that loan exposure leverage equals π t = equity = Lt L t+c t. Economic state variable M t =: Xt 3 that affects default rates Dynamics of L: dl t = dn t + β t dp t, where N t is a point process with state dependent intensity λ(m t )L t, representing the timing of defaults. (Bottom-up view: defaults are conditionally independent given F M with intensity λ(m t ).) The stochastic control β t {, 1} allows to increase the loan exposure at the advent of a potential customer. Advents of customers are modelled by jumps of the standard Poisson process P. (8) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 8

Optimal Securitization Strategy The model Model dynamics (2) Cash C. Cash position is affected by interest payed or earned on cash position given by r B C t dt (r B refinancing cost) interest r L L t dt earned on loan position recovery payments in case of default (1 δ)dn t (here LGD δ = 1). cash-reduction because of issuing of new loans β t dp t. Hence we have the following cash-dynamics dc t = (r B (X t )C t + r L L t ) dt + dn t β t dp t Economic state M. Markov switching process (continuous-time Markov chain) between two economic states, M t {, 1}. (9) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 9

Optimal Securitization Strategy The model The Securitization strategy (impulses) Each securitization of ζ i loans at a stopping time τ i has the following effects: 1 Reduce loan exposure: L τi = Ľτ i ζ i. 2 Increase cash by market value η( ) of the amount sold minus fixed costs c f > : C τi = Č τi + η( ˇM τi, ζ i ) c f In summary, bring the process X = (L, C, M) T from an old state x to the new state Γ(x, ζ) with Γ(x, ζ) = (x 1 ζ, x 2 + η(x 3, ζ) c f, x 3 ) T A sequence γ = (τ i, ζ i ) i 1 is called an impulse control strategy. (1) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 1

Optimal Securitization Strategy The model The optimization problem We consider the model on the state space S = {x R 3 : x 1 > 1, x 1 + x 2 > } (as long as the bank does not default and L t.) Fix horizon date T > t and some concave increasing utility function U. Let τ = τ S T. We assume that the shareholders want the bank to maximize the expected utility of its liquidation value at τ S, J (α) (t, x) = E (t,x) [U (max(η(m τ, L α τ ) + C α τ, ))] (1) by an choosing optimal stochastic and impulse control strategy α = (β, γ). Define the value function v(t, x) = sup{j (α) (t, x): α admissible}. (11) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 11

The players revisited Optimal Securitization Strategy Specific model inputs Bank s creditor Customers Bank ABS Investors Bank s shareholder (12) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 12

Optimal Securitization Strategy Specific model inputs Modeling market value of loans η( ) The loan portfolio of our bank consists of perpetuities (loans with maturity, i.e., the nominal is never paid back). The risk-neutral value of one such perpetual loan is [ τ ] pm := E e ρs r L ds + e ρτ (1 δ(m τ )) M = m, for τ the default time of the loan, and ρ risk-free interest rate. The vector p can be obtained by a simple inversion of the generator matrix of M. With constant default intensity λ: p = (r L + (1 δ)λ) / (ρ + λ). To account for risk aversion, one possible choice for the market value of ζ loans is: η(m, ζ) := ζ min (1, p m (1 δλ(m)) ) < ζp m (2) (13) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 13

Optimal Securitization Strategy Modeling refinancing cost r b ( ) Specific model inputs Basic rule of thumb: On average, the bank s creditors want to earn the risk-free interest ρ, so they will demand a refinancing rate r B according to 1 + ρ = (1 PD) (1 + r B ), (3) where PD = probability of default of the bank over one year. Equation (3) leads to r B := ρ + PD 1 PD. (4) Now, for a given loan amount l and cash position c we define ( L PD := P( L > l + c) = P > l + c ) l l model the distribution of the [, 1]-valued relative loss L/l. (5) (14) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 14

Optimal Securitization Strategy Specific model inputs Modeling refinancing cost r b ( ) ctd. Goal: Model distribution of relative loss L/l as seen by creditors Losses in our loan portfolio follow a Bernoulli mixture distribution (for fixed t) with path of M as common factor. Large portfolio approximation: typically a Bernoulli mixture distribution converges for granularity going to to a limiting distribution depending only on the common factor (see [McNeil et al., 25]) Choosing a probit-normal factor leads to the well-known continuous Vasicek loss distribution V p,ϱ, [ V p,ϱ (x) = N 1/ ϱ(n 1 (x) ] 1 ϱ N 1 (p)) (p (, 1) average default rate, ϱ (, 1) correlation) We take p λ(m t ); the parameter ρ can be used as additional risk-aversion parameter on behalf of creditors (15) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 15

Optimal Securitization Strategy Refinancing cost: examples Specific model inputs 3 25 Vasicek loss dist. for ms=., rel. VolaL=.16125, Uncertainty time T=1.5 Refin. cost r B for ms=., rel. VolaL=.16125, Uncertainty time T=1.5 1 1 No loan return, corr base =.2 With loan return, corr base =.4 With loan return, corr base =.2 2 1 density 15 r B 1 5 1 1.2.4.6.8.1.12.14.16.18.2 relative portfolio loss.5.1.15.2.25.3.35.4.45.5 inverse leverage Loss distribution V p,ρ (left) and refinancing rate r B (right) as function of the inverse leverage (l + c)/l. (16) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 16

Optimal Securitization Strategy Solution of the Optimization Problem Numerical considerations We want to find an optimal impulse control for the bank It seems impossible to find an analytical solution Usual approach: solve numerically the HJBQVI 1 (partial integro-differential equation) by iterated optimal stopping and thus obtain the value function v = sup α E[U(wealth)] From the value function, derive an (approximately) optimal strategy 1 Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman quasi-variational inequality (17) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 17

Optimal Securitization Strategy Value function v and HJBQVI Solution of the Optimization Problem Our aim is to find v as solution of the HJBQVI (here partial difference equation) min( sup β {,1} {u t + L β u}, u Mu) = in [, T ) S (6) for L β the infinitesimal generator of the state variable process X = (L, C, M) where x := (x 1, x 2 ) = (l, c): L β u(x) = ( u( x + ( 1 + ), x 3 ) u(x) ( u( x + ) λ(x 3 )x 1 ( ) ) β, x β 3 ) u(x) λ P + (u( x, 1 x 3 ) u(x)) λ x3,(1 x 3 ) + (r B (x)x 2 + r L x 1 )u x2 and M the intervention operator selecting the momentarily best impulse, Mu(t, x) = sup ζ {u(t, Γ(x, ζ))}. (18) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 18

Optimal Securitization Strategy HJBQVI: Existence and Uniqueness Solution of the Optimization Problem We can prove using results from [Seydel, 28]: Theorem (Parabolic viscosity solution) Assume that c r B (l, c, m) is continuous, and U continuous and bounded from below. Further assume that lim inf c l r B (l, c, ) > r L for l >, and η(, ζ) ζ. Then the value function v is the unique viscosity solution of (6), and it is continuous on [, T ] Z R {, 1} (i.e., continuous in time and in cash). Proof: See [Frey and Seydel, 29]. (19) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 19

Overview Numerical Results 1 Introduction 2 Optimal Securitization Strategy The model Specific model inputs Solution of the Optimization Problem 3 Numerical Results (2) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 2

Numerical Results Basic data Power law utility U(x) = x Symmetric Markov chain transition intensities of.3 for M Default intensities per loan: λ() = 2.6% in expansion and λ(1) = 4.7% in contraction, no loan default recovery (δ 1) Risk-free rate ρ =.4, loan interest rate r L =.8 Market value η: A form slightly more procyclical than (2) proportional transaction costs of % ( 6.5%) in expansion (contraction) Refinancing cost r B is based on Vasicek loss distribution with with p = 1.5λ, and correlation ϱ =.2 (.4) in expansion (contraction). Fixed transaction costs c f =.5 State equations: dl t = dn t dc t = (r B (X t )C t + r L L t ) dt Γ(t, x, ζ) = (x 1 ζ, x 2 + η(x 3, ζ) c f, x 3 ) T (21) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 21

y y Optimal impulses Numerical Results 4 impulses in time 7., ms=. 4 4 impulses in time 7., ms=1. 4 3 35 3 35 2 3 2 3 1 25 1 25 2 2 1 15 1 15 2 1 2 1 3 5 3 5 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x Figure: Impulses in expansion (left) and contraction (right) for T = 7. The light areas mark the impulse departure points (with the lightness indicating how far to the left the impulses goes, i.e., how many loans are sold), the cyan circles represent the corresponding impulse arrival points (22) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 22

Numerical Results Further results of numerical analysis Even with substantial transaction costs, securitization is a useful risk management tool for the bank: utility indifference argument shows that value of bank is increased substantially by the possibility of securitization Risk-dependent refinancing cost creates a major incentive to securitize Optimal securitization strategy is largely influenced by form of transaction cost - Low fixed cost c f more transactions - Strongly procyclical market value of loans (high transaction costs in contraction), only little securitization in contraction, but more loans are securitized in expansion Weakly procyclical market value High securitization activity in contraction Additional control of loan exposure (β) had only small effect (23) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 23

y y Numerical Results Cash value of securitization 4 Utility indifference iter3 iter1 (time 7.), ms=. 3.5 4 Utility indifference iter3 iter1 (time 7.), ms=1. 3.5 3 3 3 3 2 2 2.5 2.5 1 1 2 2 1 1.5 1 1.5 2 1 2 1 3.5 3.5 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x Figure: Cash value of securitization in expansion (M = ) and in contraction (right), for T = 7. For every x we display the cash amount a such that v 3 (x 1, x 2 a) = v 1 (x 1, x 2 ) (v 3 being the value function with impulses, v 1 without (24) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 24

y y y y Numerical Results Impulse and stochastic control 4 Utility indifference v fct MSSC= MS= (time 7.) 4 Utility indifference v fct MSSC=1 MS=1 (time 7.) x 1 3.4 3 3 12.35 2.3 2 1 1.25 1 8.2 6 1.15 1 4 2.1 2 3.5 3 2 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 control and impulses in time 7., ms=. 4 4 control and impulses in time 7., ms=1. 4 3 35 3 35 2 3 2 3 1 25 1 25 2 2 1 15 1 15 2 1 2 1 3 5 3 5 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x Figure: Impulse and stochastic control: Cash value of additional stochastic control (top row), and optimal strategy (bottom row) in expansion (left) and contraction (right), for T = 7. Business arrival intensity λ P = 2 (25) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 25

Literature Numerical Results Frey, R. and Seydel, R. C. (29). Optimal securitization of credit portfolios via impulse control. Working paper. McNeil, A. J., Frey, R., and Embrechts, P. (25). Quantitative risk management. Princeton Series in Finance. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Concepts, techniques and tools. Øksendal, B. and Sulem, A. (25). Applied stochastic control of jump diffusions. Universitext. Springer-Verlag, Berlin. Seydel, R. C. (28). General existence and uniqueness of viscosity solutions for impulse control of jump-diffusions. MPI MIS Preprint 37/28. (26) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 26

Viscosity solutions (1) Viscosity solutions Definition (Viscosity solution) A function u PB([, T ] R d ) is a (viscosity) subsolution of (6) if for all (t, x ) [, T ] R d and ϕ PB C 1,2 ([, T ) R d ) with ϕ(t, x ) = u (t, x ), ϕ u on [, T ) R d, min ( sup β B in (t, x ) S T, and { } ) ϕ t + Lβ ϕ + f β, u Mu min (u g, u Mu ) in (t, x ) + S T (the parabolic boundary). [...] (27) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 27

Viscosity solutions (2) Viscosity solutions Definition (Viscosity solution (cont d)) A function u PB([, T ] R d ) is a (viscosity) supersolution of (6) if for all (t, x ) [, T ] R d and ϕ PB C 1,2 ([, T ) R d ) with ϕ(t, x ) = u (t, x ), ϕ u on [, T ) R d, min ( sup β B in (t, x ) S T, and { } ) ϕ t + Lβ ϕ + f β, u Mu min (u g, u Mu ) in (t, x ) + S T. A function u is a viscosity solution if it is sub- and supersolution. (28) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 28

y y y y Impulses in time Further numerical results 4 impulses in time 1., ms=. 4 4 impulses in time 3., ms=. 4 3 35 3 35 2 3 2 3 1 25 1 25 2 2 1 15 1 15 2 1 2 1 3 5 3 5 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 impulses in time 5., ms=. 4 4 impulses in time 7., ms=. 4 3 35 3 35 2 3 2 3 1 25 1 25 2 2 1 15 1 15 2 1 2 1 3 5 3 5 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x Figure: Impulses in expansion for different T : top left T = 1, top right T = 3, bottom left T = 5 and bottom right T = 7 (29) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 29

y y Further numerical results Optimal impulses, no Markov-switching 4 impulses in time 7. 4 4 impulses in time 7. 4 3 35 3 35 2 3 2 3 1 25 1 25 2 2 1 15 1 15 2 1 2 1 3 5 3 5 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x 4 5 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 x Figure: Impulses without Markov switching, for only expansion (left) and only contraction (right) for T = 7. Market value according to procyclical form (a), corresponding to % (about 17%) proportional transaction costs in expansion (contraction). For the colour code, see the explanations in Figure 1. Otherwise, same data as in Figure?? (3) Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 3