Does Regional and Sectoral Aggregation Matter? Sensitivity Analysis in the Context of an EU-Korea FTA

Similar documents
A Graphical Exposition of the GTAP Model

Session 5 Evidence-based trade policy formulation: impact assessment of trade liberalization and FTA

Modelling Government Procurement in a General Equilibrium Framework

Preliminary draft, please do not quote

Appendix A Specification of the Global Recursive Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model

Global Value Chains and the Cost of Protection: Insights from the New OECD Trade Model

General Equilibrium Analysis Part II A Basic CGE Model for Lao PDR

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA

Chapter 3 What's New in GTAP 9?

Appendix C An Added Note to Chapter 4 on the Intercepts in the Pooled Estimates

The macroeconomic effects of reductions in the costs of facilitating payments. Philip D. Adams, Peter B. Dixon and Maureen T.

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Model (CGE)

Introducing Firm Heterogeneity Theory into CGEBox

TRADE DISTORTION INDEXES AND MULTI- REGIONAL AGE MODELS: THE CASE OF THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

The Irrelevance of Detail in a Computable General Equilibrium Model

The revival of regional trade arrangements: a GE evaluation of the impact on small countries

Chapter 3: Predicting the Effects of NAFTA: Now We Can Do It Better!

Comparing market access formulas for US and EU

Getting Started with CGE Modeling

Evidence Based Trade policy Making: Using statistical tools for policy making

CGE Simulation of the ASEAN Economic Community and RCEP under Long-term Productivity Scenarios 1

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Model (CGE)

Estimating Economic Impacts of the U.S.-South Korea Free Trade Agreement *

assessment? Maros Ivanic April 30, 2012 Abstract The major shift in global food and fuel prices in the past several years has left the world

Sub-national Differentiation and the Role of the Firm in Optimal International Pricing

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models.

Duty drawbacks, Competitiveness and Growth: The Case of China. Elena Ianchovichina Economic Policy Unit, PREM Network World Bank

Comparison of Welfare Gains in the Armington, Krugman and Melitz Models

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

A New Final Demand System for GTAP?

Chapter 5. Partial Equilibrium Analysis of Import Quota Liberalization: The Case of Textile Industry. ISHIDO Hikari. Introduction

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Evaluating the Doha Market Access Modalities

Intra and Extra-regional Effects of Plurilateral FTAs in Asia *

CHAPTER 6 CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS

Preliminary Assessment of the Economic Impacts of a Canada-Korea Free Trade Agreement

Sensitive Product Designation in the Doha Round: The Case of Rice

Dynamic Effects of the New Age Free Trade Agreement between Japan and Singapore

U. S. International Trade Commission Report to the GTAP Advisory Board. for

USO cost allocation rules and welfare

A Nested PE/GE Model for GTAP: Simulating the Disaggregated Impacts of. Tariff-Liberalization on Automotive Industry in India 1. Badri Narayanan G.

Trade model to assess Euro-Med agreements. An application to the fresh tomato market

The Impact of Free Trade Agreements in Asia

DRAFT. A microsimulation analysis of public and private policies aimed at increasing the age of retirement 1. April Jeff Carr and André Léonard

Market Access and the Reform of State Trading Enterprises

The Model: Tradables, Non-tradables, and Semi-tradables in Trade Models. Shantayanan Devarajan Jeffrey D. Lewis Jaime de Melo Sherman Robinson

Using the Logistic Functional Form for Modelling International

ARTNeT Capacity Building Workshop on Trade Research UN ESCAP WITS

Do price uncertainties affect the use of policy flexibilities? The selection of sensitive products in WTO agricultural negotiations

The 2008 Financial Crisis and the Lack of Retaliatory. Trade Intervention. Abstract

PRMTR - Trade Policy Simulation Course Maros Ivanic 5 May 2010

The Welfare Cost of Inflation. in the Presence of Inside Money

BIMSTEC Regional Integration: Prospects and Challenges 1

TRADE PARTNERSHIP WORLDWIDE, LLC

Linking Microsimulation and CGE models

Impacts of East Asian Integration on Vietnam: A CGE Analysis

Session Two: SPECIFICATION

Essential Policy Intelligence

Lecture #2. Government intervention in the market

A Baseline Scenario for the Dynamic GTAP Model

The regional CGEs of CAPRI RegCgeEU+ Model documentation including Graphical User Interface. Wolfgang Britz, University Bonn

The Relative Significance of EPAs in Asia-Pacific

General Equilibrium Mechanisms and the Real Exchange Rate in the GTAP Model* Third Draft of a Technical Document November, 2012

Vertical Linkages and the Collapse of Global Trade

Economic Integration in South East Asia and the Impact on the EU

Appendix A Methodology for Reciprocity Measure and GDP Gains

Global value chains, Commission trade policy priorities and data needs

Social Accounting Matrix and its Application. Kijong Kim Levy Economics Institute GEM-IWG summer workshop July

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

Improved market access for Russia or own liberalization as part of WTO accession: what will raise Russian income and reduce poverty more?

4. SOME KEYNESIAN ANALYSIS

ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF A POSSIBLE CANADA-U.S. CUSTOMS UNION: SIMULATION RESULTS FROM A DYNAMIC CGE MODEL 1. Madanmohan Ghosh Someshwar Rao

Long-Run Simulations with GTAP: Illustrative Results from APEC Trade Liberalisation

CHANGING THE TAXATION REGIME FOR INVESTORS IN THE HOUSING MARKET

A poverty module of the MIRAGE model of the world economy

Computational Analysis of APEC Trade Liberalization. Kozo Kiyota. Robert Stern

Chapter 6 SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS

Social Accounting Matrices for CGE

Chapter 4 THE SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX AND OTHER DATA SOURCES

More (or Less) on Necessarily Welfare-Enhancing Free Trade Areas

Evaluating the Effects of Free Trade Agreements in the Asia-Pacific Region under Alternative Sequencings *

Economic Impact of Canada s Participation in the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership

Sizing Strategies in Scarce Environments

Potential Effects of Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP) on the Philippine Economy*

THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF WESTERN HEMISPHERE ECONOMIC INTEGRATION: EMPHASIS ON FOOD AND AGRICULTURAL SECTORS

Impacts of the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans- Pacific Partnership on the New Zealand Economy

A Computable General Equilibrium Model of Energy Taxation

ABSTRACT Keywords: JEL codes:

AEA poster presentation. Contact: Karen Thierfelder

MANAGING TRADE POLICY REFORM AND THE REFORM OF

Regional unemployment and welfare effects of the EU transport policies:

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Chapter 5. The Standard Trade Model. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

Partnership for Economic Policy. Martín Cicowiez (CEDLAS-UNLP) Bernard Decaluwé (Université Laval) Mustapha Nabli

ADB Working Paper Series on Regional Economic Integration. Methods for Ex Ante Economic Evaluation of Free Trade Agreements

Whither the ASEAN Economic Community in ?

Partial Equilibrium Model: An Example. ARTNet Capacity Building Workshop for Trade Research Phnom Penh, Cambodia 2-6 June 2008

Assessing the Impact of China s WTO Accession on Foreign Ownership

Is MERCOSUR external agenda pro-poor? An assessment of the EU-MERCOSUR free trade agreement on Uruguayan poverty applying MIRAGE

- 1 - Abstract. Keywords: CGE modelling, European Enlargement, Common Agricultural Policy, hectare and animal premiums, GTAP.

Transcription:

Does Regional and Sectoral Aggregation Matter? Sensitivity Analysis in the Context of an EU-Korea FTA Jong-Hwan Ko 1 and Wolfgang Britz 2 1 Division of International and Area Studies, Pukyong National University, Korea jonghko@pknu.ac.kr 2 Institute for Food and Resource Economics, University of Bonn, Germany wolfgang.britz@ilr.uni-bonn.de Paper prepared for presentation at the 16 th Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis "New Challenges for Global Trade in a Rapidly Changing World" Shanghai, China, June 12-14, 2013

1. Introduction Computable general equilibrium (CGE) models and partial equilibrium (PE) models has been widely used in the context of trade policy analysis. In such studies, a decision on the aggregation level with regard to regions and sectors is needed. Quite often, that decision is made a priori before the model runs, and a systematic analysis of trade policy on its impact is not undertaken. There is ample evidence that sectoral aggregation matters in trade analysis. So far, however, limited evidence exists about how the regional aggregation level affects results in CGE and PE applications. We take an FTA between EU and South Korea as an example to analyze how the sectoral and regional aggregation level affects results. The EU-Korea FTA became effective in July 2011 and thus provides a real world example which is not only of academic interest. South Korea s agricultural markets, while showing with the exception of rice relatively low self-sufficiency levels, are generally protected by rather high tariffs. Therefore, we have an example in which some larger effects on domestic prices, consumption, production and trade patterns from an FTA are expected. In order to analyze the effects of the EU-Korea FTA, we use the GTAP model in combination with different configurations of the GTAP data base. All configurations can be assumed plausible a priori in the light of what matters in that type of analysis : who are the important trading partners? Which sectors are expected to be most affected? Specifically, in addition to different sectoral aggregation levels, we consider different aggregation levels (1) with regard to trading partners indirectly affected by the FTA to take a closer look at trade diversion effects and (2) with regard to the regional aggregation level of the EU (one block or individual countries). Additionally, we also compare our findings from the GTAP model with the results from a PE for agricultural and food products, namely the CAPRI model to shed light on questions of the effects of border protection instruments such as TRQs which are explicitly considered in the PE, in comparison to ad-valorem tariffs used in most of the standard GTAP applications. Thus, our analysis aims to show on the one hand to what extent regional and sectoral aggregation matters, while on the other lobbying for more systematic sensitivity analysis of regional and sectoral aggregation levels and cross-model comparisons. 2. Literature review: Aggregation 3. Sensitivity analysis with an Armington model In order to abstract from the given data constellation and parameterization in a specific policy experiment such as in our case study on an EU-South Korea FTA, we conduct sensitivity analysis with stochastically drawn data. Equally, in order to focus on the possible main reason why results differ depending on the regional aggregation level, we only analyze the effect in an Armington CES system, neglecting any trickle-down effects in the overall CGE. We use three equations representing the usual Armington equations in a trade models. The equation exhausts the demand budget armval for imports of a product by the total value of the imports (quantity tradeflows times import price impp):

armval tradeflows impp (1) r r r The second equation exhausts that value by the product of the Armginton aggregator ArmQuant and the related price armp: (2) armquant armp armval Finally, behavioral equations drive the trade flows as a function of relative prices armp (3) tradeflowsr rarmquant imppr As seen from above, we take the prices and budget for total imports as given. By shocking selected import prices, we simulate the impact of introducing a FTA. Specifically, we model three importers of which the first is assumed to be not part of the new FTA. The second and third importers belong to the same trade block say the EU. Set-up of experiments and main findings We assume in our experiments that the analyzed FTA will reduce import prices from the trade block by 20%. We draw 20 times from uniform [1,10000] to get starting values for the trade flows, assuming that all import prices in the calibration point are equal to unity. For each of these outer draws, we construct a benchmark by aggregating the trade flows for region 2 and 3 to a trade block and lower its import prices to 0.8. That would be equivalent of an analysis where we have only two exporters in our analysis: the trade block for which import tariffs are lowered and ROW with unchanged tariffs. Next, we perform 20 inner draws where we draw both import shares for the two regions of the block between [0,1] and new prices for these regions between [0.6,1.0]. The trade shares are scaled to unity such the sum of imports of the trade block does not change and the new prices scaled such that the average price at trade block level in the simulation would be again 0.8. Each draws thus represent a possible consistent break down of the trade block in terms of quantities and ad-valorem bi-lateral tariffs towards our importing region for which armval is given. For the example with the EU, bi-lateral tariffs of an importer say South Korea - for one product might differ between EU Member States as each Member State might have a specific composition of that product with respect to HS6 tariff lines. The model is then calibrated against the trade flows at prices before the shock (=1) by adjusting the share parameters. Afterwards, the price shock is introduced the resulting changes in trade flows and the Armington aggregator quantities and prices simulated and stored. The table below gives an idea how the experiments look like by reporting the first five draws for one out draw: d1 d2 d3 d4 d5 R1.TradeFlows, drawn 173 173 173 173 173 R1.TradeFlows, sim 1 0.948 0.909 0.466 0.795 R1.Price 1 1 1 1 1

R2.TradeFlows, drawn 1394 708 1293 514 1116 R2.Price 0.8 0.772 0.786 0.971 0.764 R3.TradeFlows, drawn 687 101 880 278 R3.TradeFlows, sim 633 16 2155 57 R3.Price 0.8 0.829 0.981 0.7 0.946 SubAgg.TradeFlows, drawn 1394 1394 1394 1394 1394 SubAgg.AvPrice 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 SubAgg.TradeFlows, sim 1927 1951 1960 2203 2012 Arm.Price, sim 1 0.994 0.99 0.919 0.975 Arm.Quant, sim 1 1.006 1.011 1.088 1.026 The first columns D1 report the benchmark case. Imports from regions 2 and 3 are aggregated such that the model does only comprise two regions; the aggregated results are reported as region 2. In subsequent draws (D2, D3 etc.), the sum of the imports from region 2 and 3 (subagg. Trade Flows, drawn) and the trade flows for ROW (R1) will not change in the new calibration point of the model. Equally, in each draw, the price shocks for regions 2 and 3 differ (R2.Price, R3.Price), but the average shock for the trade block at unchanged trade flows is always equal to 20% (subagg.avprice). Changes for the ROW imports are shown in relative terms (R1, TradeFlows, sim), the same holds for the Armington price and quantity. Our analysis finds firstly, which is reassuring, that if tariffs do not differ inside the trade block, i.e., between regions R2 and R3, the simulated trade generation effect on the block as a whole is independent on how large the exports share of block members are. That also means that trade diversion effects and aggregator prices and quantities are not affected. But if, as it will be usually the case, tariffs inside the block differ, simulation results will depend on the chosen regional dis-aggregation. In the unlike case of an Armington elasticity below unity, tariff differences between exporters inside a trade block will lead to lower trade effects. In the usual case of Armginton elasticities above unity (see table below), these tariffs differences will increase the simulated trade generation and diversion effects compared to an aggregated analysis, while lowering the Armington aggregate prices and thus increasing the Armington aggregate quantity. The later can be interpreted as a welfare gain, such that also overall simulated welfare effects for the importer are larger. The differences between aggregated and dis-aggregated analysis increase with the size of the substitution elasticities. The table below reports the findings for different substitution elasticities. Substitution elasticity 2 5 10 Min simulated 0.960 0.632 0.141 trade diversion effect Mean simulated 0.994 0.935 0.766 trade diversion effect Min simulated Armington price 0.960 0.892 0.805

Mean simulated Armginton price Max simulated Armington quantity Mean simulation Armington quantity Note: Benchmark, i.e. aggregated analysis = 1 0.994 0.983 0.965 1.042 1.121 1.243 1.006 1.018 1.038 Discussion We find these results disturbing. Obviously, it is possible to increase trade and welfare effects in an analysis with Armington based models by increasing the dis-aggregation. The effects found with the very same version of GTAP from a policy experiment will therefore depend on the regional aggregation chosen. Similar findings can probably be generated by changing the product disaggregation. The results above show sizeable average effects at reasonable Armington elasticities in the range reported for GTAP (see Hertel et al. 2008, Table 14.2, Sourcing of Imports), the minimum and maximum values reported hint at the possible range of errors which depend on the specific data constellation. The results can be seen in the context of the discussion around a consistent aggregation of tariffs (cf.). Obviously, simply adding regional data on imports flows in cif and fob values and deriving the ad-valorem tariff is an aggregation rule which does not match an Armington system at unchanged substitution elasticities. 4. Comparison of simulation results of an EU-Korea FTA using GTAP model and CAPRI model 5. Concluding remarks References Britz, W. and Witzke, P. (2012) (eds.), CAPRI model documentation version 2012, University of Bonn, Germany (http://www.capri-model.org/docs/capri_documentation.pdf) EU (2012), Korea, website of the European Commission (http://ec.europa.eu/trade/creatingopportunities/bilateral-relations/countries/ korea/) visited on 11 January 2013 Arndt, C. and T.W. Hertel (1997), Revisiting The Fallacy of Free Trade, Review of International Economics, 5(2), 221-229. Grant, J.H., Hertel, T.W. and Rutherford, T.F. (2006), Extending General Equilibrium to the Tariff Line: U.S. Dairy in the Doha Development Agenda, Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Long Beach, CA, July 23-26, 2006

Hertel, Thomas, Robert McDougall, Badri Narayanan, and Angel H. Aguiar (2008), GTAP 7 data base documentation - Chapter 14: Behavioral parameters. Technical Report. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University Lenzen, M. (2011), Aggregation versus Disaggregation in Input-Output Analysis of the Environment, Economic Systems Research 23(1), 73-89. Miller, R. E. and Shao, G. (1990), "Spatial and sectoral aggregation in the commodity - industry multiregional input - output model", Environment and Planning A 22(12),1637 1656. Pelikan J. and Brockmeier M. (2008), Methods to Aggregate Import Tariffs and their Impacts on Modeling Results, (https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/download/3461.pdf) Yvan Decreux, Y., Chris, M. and Péridy, N (2010), The Economic Impact of the Free Trade Agreement (FTA) between the European Union and Korea, Report for the European Commission (http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/may/tradoc_146174.pdf)