Option Pricing Models for European Options

Similar documents
1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

MA4257: Financial Mathematics II. Min Dai Dept of Math, National University of Singapore, Singapore

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

American options and early exercise

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

The Black-Scholes Model

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

The Black-Scholes Model

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Monte Carlo Simulations

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Risk Neutral Pricing Black-Scholes Formula Lecture 19. Dr. Vasily Strela (Morgan Stanley and MIT)

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

The Black-Scholes Model

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Financial Risk Management

Computational Finance

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Outline One-step model Risk-neutral valuation Two-step model Delta u&d Girsanov s Theorem. Binomial Trees. Haipeng Xing

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Black-Scholes model: Derivation and solution

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

1 Geometric Brownian motion

Extensions to the Black Scholes Model

Merton s Jump Diffusion Model

Copyright Emanuel Derman 2008

The Multistep Binomial Model

SOA Exam MFE Solutions: May 2007

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

The Black-Scholes Equation

Risk Neutral Measures

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Financial Derivatives Section 5

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

In chapter 5, we approximated the Black-Scholes model

Pricing Financial Derivatives Using Stochastic Calculus. A Thesis Presented to The Honors Tutorial College, Ohio University

Non-semimartingales in finance

Risk Neutral Valuation

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Lévy models in finance

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Path Dependent British Options

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

1 Parameterization of Binomial Models and Derivation of the Black-Scholes PDE.

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

Short-time-to-expiry expansion for a digital European put option under the CEV model. November 1, 2017

Degree project. Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model

Models of Option Pricing: The Black-Scholes, Binomial and Monte Carlo Methods

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Advanced Numerical Methods

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

1 Interest Based Instruments

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Transcription:

Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying asset price follows a geometric Brownian motion ds t S t = µdt + σdw t where µ and σ are the expected return rate and volatility of the underlying asset, W t is the Brownian motion. 2. There are no arbitrage opportunities. The absence of arbitrage opportunities means that all risk-free portfolios must earn the same return. 3. The underlying asset pay no dividends during the life of the option. 4. The risk-free interest rate r and the asset volatility σ are known constants over the life of the option. 5. Trading is done continuously. Short selling is permitted and the assets are divisible. 6. There are no transaction costs associated with hedging a position. Also no taxes. 2.1.2 Derivation of the Black-Scholes Model Let V = V (S, t) be the value of an European option. To derive the model, we construct a portfolio of one long option position and a short position in 9

10CHAPTER 2. OPTION PRICING MODELS FOR EUROPEAN OPTIONS some quantity, of the underlying. Π=V S. The increment of the value of the portfolio in one time-step is dπ = dv ds t = ( t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V )dt + S2 S ds t ds t. To eliminate the risk, we take = S and then dπ =( t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V S 2 )dt. Since there is no random term, the portfolio is riskless. By the no-arbitrage principle, a riskless portfolio must earn a risk free return (i.e. 1.5). So, we have dπ =rπdt = r(v S S )dt. From the above two equalities, we obtain an equation t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V + rs rv =0. (2.1) S2 S This is the well-known Black-Scholes equation. The solution domain is D = {(S, t) :S>0, t [0,T)}. At expiry, we have { (S X) V (S, T )= +, for call option, (X S) + (2.2), for put option. There is a unique solution to the model (2.1-2.2): { SN(d1 ) Xe V (S, t) = r(t t) N (d 2 ) for call option Xe r(t t) N( d 2 ) SN( d 1 ) for put option where N(x) = 1 2π x e y2 2 dy, d1 = log S σ2 X +(r + 2 )(T t) σ, d 2 = d 1 σ T t T t Remark 2 The Black-Scholes equation is valid for any derivative that provides a payoff depending only on the underlying asset price at one particular time (European style). Exercise: Use the Black-Scholes equation to price a long forward contract, and digital options (binary options).

2.1. CONTINUOUS-TIME MODEL: BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL 11 2.1.3 Risk-Neutral Pricing and Theoretical Basis of Monte- Carlo Simulation The expected return rate µ of the underlying asset, clearly depending on risk preference, does not appear in the equation. All of the variables appearing in the Black-Scholes equation are independent of risk preference. So, risk references do not affect the solution to the Black-Scholes equation. This means that any set of risk preferences can be used when evaluating options (or any other derivatives). In particular, we may carry out the evaluation in a risk-neutral world. In a risk-neutral world, all investors are risk-neutral, namely, the expected return on all securities is the risk-free rate of interest r. Thus, the present value of any cash flow in the world can be obtained by discounting its expected value at the risk-free rate. Then the price of an option (a European call, for example) can be represented by [ ] V (S, t) =Ê e r(t t) (S T X) + S t = S. (2.3) Here Ê denotes the expected value in a risk-neutral world under which the underlying asset price S t follows ds t S t = rdt + σdw t. (2.4) Note that in this situation the expected return rate of the underlying is riskless rate of interest r (suppose the underlying pays no income). Mathematically, we can provide a rigorous proof for the equivalence of (2.1-2.2) and (2.3). In fact, this is just a corollary of Feynman-Kac formula. We refer interested readers to Oksendal (2003). Eq (2.3) is the theoretical basis of Monte-Carlo simulation for derivative pricing. The simulation can be carried out by the following procedure: (1) Simulate the price movement of the underlying asset in a risk-neutral world according to (2.4) (see the discrete scheme (1.8)); (2) Calculate the expected terminal payoff of the derivative. (3) Discount the expected payoff at the risk-free interest rate. Remark 3 It is important to emphasize that risk-neutral valuation (or the assumption that all investors are risk-neutral) is merely an artifical device for obtaining solutions to the Black-Scholes equation. The solutions that are obtained are valid in all worlds, not just those where investors are risk neutral.

12CHAPTER 2. OPTION PRICING MODELS FOR EUROPEAN OPTIONS 2.2 Discrete-time Model: Cox-Ross-Rubinstein Binomial Model 2.2.1 Single-Period Model Consider an option whose value, denoted by V 0 at current time t = 0, depends on the underlying asset price S 0. Let the expiration date of the option be T. Assume that during the life of the option the underlying asset price S 0 can either move up to S 0 u with probability p, or down to S 0 d with probability 1 p (u>1 >d,0 <p < 1). Correspondingly, the payoff from the option will become either V u (for up-movement in the underlying asset price) or V d (for down-movement). The following argument is similar to that of continuous time case. We construct a portfolio that consists of a long position in the option and a short position in shares. At time t =0, the portfolio has the value V S 0 If there is an up movement in the underlying asset price, the value of the portfolio at t = T is V u S 0 u. If there is a down movement in the underlying asset price, the value becomes V d S 0 d. To make the portfolio riskfree, we let the two be equal, that is, V u S 0 u = V d S 0 d or = V u V d S 0 (u d). (2.5) Again, by the no-arbitrage principle, a risk-free portfolio must earn the riskfree interest rate. As a result V u S 0 u = e rt (V S). Substituting (2.5) into the above formula, we get V = e rt [pv u +(1 p)v d ], where p = ert d u d.

2.2. DISCRETE-TIME MODEL: COX-ROSS-RUBINSTEIN BINOMIAL MODEL13 This is the single-period binomial model. Here p is called the risk-neutral probability. Note that the objective probability p does not appear in the binomial model, which is consistent with the risk-neutral pricing principle of the continuous time model. 2.2.2 Multi-Period Model Let T be expiration date, [0,T] be the lifetime of the option. If N is the number of discrete time points, we have time points n t, n =0, 1,..., N, with t = T N. At time t =0, the underlying asset price is known, denoted by S 0. At time t, there are two possible underlying asset prices, S 0 u and S 0 d. Without loss of generality, we assume ud =1. At time 2 t, there are three possible underlying asset prices, S 0 u 2,S 0, and S 0 d 2 = S 0 u 2 ; and so on. In general, at time n t, n + 1 underlying asset prices are considered. These are S 0 u n,s 0 u n+2,..., S 0 u n. A complete tree is then constructed. Let Vj n be the option price at time point n t with underlying asset price S j = S 0 u j. Note that S j will jump either up to S j+1 or down to S j 1 at time (n + 1) t, and the value of the option at (n + 1) t will become either Vj+1 or Vj 1. Since the length of time period is t, the discounting factor is e r t. Then, similar to the arguments in the singleperiod case, we have [ ] Vj n = e r t pvj+1 +(1 p)v j 1, j = n, n+2,..., n, n =0, 1,..., N 1 where At expiry, p = er t d u d. V N j = { (S0 u j K ) + for call, (K S 0 u j ) + for put, j = N, N +2,..., N. This is the multi-period binomial model. To make the binomial process of the underlying asset price match the geometric Brownian motion, we need to choose u, d such that p u +(1 p )d = e µ t (2.6) p u 2 +(1 p )d 2 e 2µ t = σ 2 t. (2.7)

14CHAPTER 2. OPTION PRICING MODELS FOR EUROPEAN OPTIONS There are three unknowns u, d and p. Without loss of generality, we add one condition ud =1. (2.8) By neglecting the high order of t, we can solve the system of equations (2.6-2.8) to get u = e σ t, d = e σ t. 2.3 Consistency of Binomial Model and Continuous- Time Model. 2.3.1 Consistency The binomial tree method can be rewritten as V (S, t t) =e r t [pv (Su,t)+(1 p)v (Sd,t)]. Here, for the convenience of presentation, we take the current time to be t t. Assuming sufficient smoothness of the V (S, t), we perform the Taylor series expansion of the binomial scheme at (S, t) as follows 0 = V (S, t t)+e r t [pv (Su,t)+(1 p)v(sd,t)] = V (S, t)+ t t + O( t2 ) +e r t V (S, t)+ S Se r t [p(u 1) + (1 p)(d 1)] + 1 2 V 2 S 2 S2 e r t [p(u 1) 2 +(1 p)(d 1) 2 ] + 1 3 V 6 S 3 S3 e r t [p(u 1) 3 +(1 p)(d 1) 3 ]+O( t 2 ) Observe that e r t [p(u 1) + (1 p)(d 1)] = r t + O( t 2 ). e r t [p(u 1) 2 +(1 p)(d 1) 2 ]=σ 2 t + O( t 2 ) e r t [p(u 1) 3 +(1 p)(d 1) 3 ]=O( t 2 ). We then get 0 = V (S, t t)+e r t [pv (Su,t)+(1 p)v (Sd,t)] = [ rv (S, t)+ t + rs S + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V S 2 ] t + O( t2 )

2.3. CONSISTENCY OF BINOMIAL MODEL AND CONTINUOUS-TIME MODEL.15 or rv (S, t)+ + rs t S + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V S 2 = O( t). This implies the consistency of two models. 2.3.2 *Equivalence of BTM and an explicit difference scheme We claim the BTM is equivalent to an explicit difference scheme for the continuous-time model. Using the transformations u(x, t) =V (S, t), S = e x, (2.1-2.2) become the following constant-coefficient PDE problem u t + σ2 2 u 2 +(r σ2 x 2 2 ) u x ru =0 x (, ), t [0,T) u(t,x)=ϕ(x) + in (, ), (2.9) where ϕ (x) =e x X (call option) or ϕ (x) =X e x (put option). We now present the explicit difference scheme for (2.9). Given mesh size x, t >0, N t = T, let Q = {(j x, n t) :0 n N, j Z} stand for the lattice. Uj n represents the value of numerical approximation at (j x, n t) andϕ j = ϕ (j x). Taking the explicit difference for time and the conventional difference discretization for space, we have U j or U n j t U n j = + σ2 2 U j+1 2Uj + Uj 1 x 2 +(r σ2 ( 1 (1 σ2 t )U 1+r t x2 j + σ2 t x 2 (1 2 + σ2 t x 2 (1 σ2 (r 2 2 ) x 2σ )U 2 j 1 ) 2 )U, j+1 U j 1 2 x σ2 +(r 2 ) x 2σ ru n j =0 )U 2 j+1 which is denoted by Uj n = 1 [ ] (1 α)uj + α(auj+1 +(1 a)uj 1 1+r t ), (2.10) where α = σ 2 t x 2,a= 1 σ2 +(r 2 2 ) x 2σ 2. By putting α = 1 in (2.10), namely σ 2 t/ x 2 =1, we get U n j = 1 [ auj+1 1+r t ] +(1 a)uj 1. (2.11)

16CHAPTER 2. OPTION PRICING MODELS FOR EUROPEAN OPTIONS The final values are given as follows: Uj N = ϕ + j,j Z. Recall the binomial tree method can be described as follows by adopting the same lattice: Vj n = 1 [ ] pvj+1 +(1 p)vj 1, j = n, n 2,, n, (2.12) ρ Vj N = ϕ + j,j= N,N 2,, N (2.13) In view of ρ =1+r t + O ( t 2) and p = 1 t 2 (1 + σ2 (r σ 2 )) + O( t3/2 ), Recall the binomial tree method can be described as follows by adopting the same lattice: Vj n = 1 [ ] pvj+1 +(1 p)vj 1, j = n, n 2,, n, (2.14) ρ Vj N = ϕ + j,j= N,N 2,, N (2.15) In view of ρ =1+r t + O ( t 2) and p = 1 t 2 (1 + σ2 (r σ 2 )) + O( t3/2 ), we deduce that the binomial tree method is equivalent to explicit difference scheme (2.11) in the sense of neglecting a higher order of t. 2.4 Continuous-dividend and Discrete-dividend Payments 2.4.1 Continuous-dividend Payment Let q be the continuous dividend yield. This means that in a time period dt, the underlying asset pays a dividend qs t dt. Following a similar argument as in the case no dividend payment, it is not hard to derive the pricing equation. t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V +(r q)s rv =0. S2 S

2.4. CONTINUOUS-DIVIDEND AND DISCRETE-DIVIDEND PAYMENTS17 For the binomial model, the risk neutral probability is adjusted as p = e(r q) t d. u d We leave the details to readers. 2.4.2 Discrete-dividend Payment Without loss of generality, suppose that the asset pays dividend just once during the lifetime of the option, at time t d (0,T), with the known dividend yield d y. Thus, at time t d, the holder of the asset receives a payment d y S(t d ), where S(t d ) is the asset price just before the dividend is paid. To preclude arbitrage opportunities, the asset price must fall by exactly the amount of the dividend payment, S(t + d )=S(t d ) d ys(t d )=S(t d )(1 d y). This means that a discrete dividend payment leads to a jump in the value of the underlying asset across the dividend date. One important observation for option pricing model is that the value of the option must be continuous as a function of time across the dividend date because the holder of the option does not receive the dividend. So, the value of the option is the same immediately before the dividend date as it is immediately after the date, that is, V (S(t d ),t d ) = V (S(t+ d ),t+ d ) = V (S(t d )(1 d y),t + d ). Let S replace S(t d ). We then have the so-called jump condition: V (S, t d )=V (S(1 d y),t + d ). For t t d, there is no dividend payment and thus V (S, t) still satisfies the equations without dividend payments. Therefore, we have for European options, t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V + rs S2 S rv = 0,S>0, t (0,t d), t (t d,t) V (S, t d ) = V (S(1 d y),t + d ) V (S, T ) = ϕ +.

18CHAPTER 2. OPTION PRICING MODELS FOR EUROPEAN OPTIONS 2.5 Option Pricing: from a point of view of option replication 2.5.1 Self-financing process Consider a market where only two basic assets are traded. One is a bond, whose price process is dp = rpdt. The other asset is a stock whose price process is governed by the geometric Brownian motion: ds t = µs t dt + σs t dw t. Let us consider a self-financing process Z t which means that there is no withdrawal of infusion of funds during the investment period. We denote Y by Y t the amount invested in the stock (i.e., t S t number of shares). The remaining amount Z t Y t is invested in the bond. The wealth process Z t is described by 2.5.2 Option replication dz t = r (Z t Y t ) dt + dy t = r (Z t Y t ) dt + µy t dt + σy t dw t = [rz t +(µ r) Y t ] dt + σy t dw. (2.16) Consider a European call option whose payoff is (S T K) +. The price of the option at t = T is the amount that the holder of the option would obtain as well as the amount that the writer would lose at that time. Now, suppose this option has a price z at t =0. The writer has to invest this amount of money in some way (called replication) in the market (where there are only bond and the underlying stock) so that at time t = T,his total wealth, denoted by Z T, resulting for the investment of z, should at least compensate his potential loss (S T K) +, namely Z T (S T K) +. (2.17) It is clear that for the same investment strategy, the larger the initial endowment z, the larger the final wealth Z T. Hence the writer of the option would like to set z large enough so that (2.17) can be guaranteed. On the other

2.5. OPTION PRICING: FROM A POINT OF VIEW OF OPTION REPLICATION19 hand, if it happens that for some z the resulting final wealth Z T is strictly larger than the loss (S T K) +, then the price z of this option at t =0is considered to be too high. In this case, the buyer of the option, instead of buying the option, would make his own investment to get the desired payoff (S T K) +. As a result, the fair price for the option at time t =0shouldbe such a z that the corresponding (self-financing) investment would result in a wealth process Z T satisfying Z T =(S T K) +. Let Z t be the self-financing process satisfying (2.16) with Z 0 being the fair value of the opiton. Denote Z t = V (t, S t ). Applying Ito lemma, ( dv = t + 1 2 σ2 St 2 2 ) V S 2 + µs t dt + σs t dw (t). (2.18) S S Comparing (2.18) with (2.16), we get { Y t = S t S t + 1 2 σ2 St 2 2 V + µs S 2 t S = rv +(µ r) Y t. In the end, we get t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V + rs rv =0. S2 S This is the Black-Scholes equation. It is worthwhile noting Y t = S t S (S t,t) = t. This means that the strategy for replication is holding shares of stock. Consequently, dz t =[rz t +(µ r) t S t ] dt + σ t S t dw. That is t t Z t = Z 0 + [rz τ +(µ r) τ S τ ] dτ + σ τ S τ dw τ. 0 0 Using the idea of replication, we can derive the binomial model as well.