y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

Similar documents
David Romer, Advanced Macroeconomics (McGraw-Hill, New York, 1996) (hereafter AM).

ECONOMICS. of Macroeconomic. Paper 4: Basic Macroeconomics Module 1: Introduction: Issues studied in Macroeconomics, Schools of Macroeconomic

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

2. Barro, Robert and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. Economic Growth, second edition, MIT Press, (Required text).

Dynamic Macroeconomics

On the Determination of Interest Rates in General and Partial Equilibrium Analysis

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Monetary Economics Semester 2, 2003

INDIAN HILL EXEMPTED VILLAGE SCHOOL DISTRICT Social Studies Curriculum - May 2009 AP Economics

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

Monetary Business Cycles. Introduction: The New Keynesian Model in the context of Macro Theory

Models of the Neoclassical synthesis

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

Macro theory: Quick review

It is a great delight to be here at this conference. I am very familiar with the

History of modern macroeconomics

Lecture 4: 16/07/2012

Macroeconomic Theory IV: New Keynesian Economics

PROBLEM SET 6 New Keynesian Economics

Nº 4 On the Long-Run Inflation-Unemployment Trade-Off Francisco L. Lopes

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

EUROPEAN MACROECONOMICS

Macroeconomic Modeling: From Keynes and the Classics to DSGE. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2018 Last updated: August 16, 2018

Exam #2 Review Questions (Answers) ECNS 303 October 31, 2011

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

Macro theory: A quick review

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Winter 2009 Solutions to Problem Set 2.

Lecture Notes in Macroeconomics. Christian Groth

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Macroeconomics I International Group Course

Economics 325 (Section 020*) Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2009

macro macroeconomics Aggregate Demand I N. Gregory Mankiw CHAPTER TEN PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich fifth edition

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

INTERMEDIATE ECONOMIC THEORY: MACRO ECON Fall 2008

PART XII: SHORT-RUN ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY. Chapter 33

Introduction The Story of Macroeconomics. September 2011

Monetary Theory and Policy. Fourth Edition. Carl E. Walsh. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

Part I (45 points; Mark your answers in a SCANTRON)

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background

Macroeconomics. Based on the textbook by Karlin and Soskice: Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial System

Lecture 1. Macroeconomic Modeling: From Keynes and the Classics to DSGE. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: March 12, 2017

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Economics 2202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2014

Inflation Targeting and Output Stabilization in Australia

ECOM 001 Macroeconomics A

Macroeconomic Modeling: From Keynes and the Classics to DSGE

ECON : Topics in Monetary Economics

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

Matthew 0. Shapiro. Working Paper No. 2146

The Real Business Cycle Model

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE College of Management and Economics University of Guelph. ECON*6490 Money and Banking Fall 2012

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2018

TEACHING STICKY PRICES TO UNDERGRADUATES

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

CHAPTER 1 Introduction

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy

Economic Importance of Keynesian and Neoclassical Economic Theories to Development

Macroeconomics, Cdn. 4e (Williamson) Chapter 1 Introduction

AP Macroeconomics Trent Thornton Voice mail:

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Economics II/Intermediate Macroeconomics (No. 5025) Prof. Dr. Gerhard Schwödiauer/ Prof. Dr. Joachim Weimann. Semester: Summer Semester 2003

The Phillips curve menu

Macroeconomics. The Short-Run Trade-off Between Inflation and Unemployment. Introduction. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Economics 2202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2015

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

The Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

Trade and Development

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH INTRODUCING ECONOMIC CONCEPTS.

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

Macroeconomics II. Lecture 07: AS, Inflation, and Unemployment. IES FSS (Summer 2017/2018)

Macroeconomics Finals

Monetary Economics July 2014

Economics II/Intermediate Macroeconomics (No. 5025) Prof. Dr. Gerhard Schwödiauer/ Prof. Dr. Joachim Weimann. Semester: Winter Semester 2002/03

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

Objectives THE BUSINESS CYCLE CHAPTER

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

B r i e f T a b l e o f C o n t e n t s

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

No 02. Chapter 1. Chapter Outline. What Macroeconomics Is About. Introduction to Macroeconomics

Week 5. Remainder of chapter 9: the complete real model Chapter 10: money Copyright 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

2.2 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

Working Paper No. 241

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Expectations Theory and the Economy CHAPTER

Disputes In Macroeconomics

The Monetary Transmission Mechanism

Chapter 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations

Macroeconomic Analysis Econ 6022

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Transcription:

The Neutrality of Money. The term neutrality of money has had numerous meanings over the years. Patinkin (1987) traces the entire history of its use. Currently, the term is used to in two specific ways. Thefirst refers to the division of a static economic model into a real part, in which the quantity of output is determined, and a nominal part, in which nominal prices and wages are determined given the real quantities from the first part. In the second instance, the neutrality of money has come to mean that all anticipated monetary and fiscal policy all aggregate demand policy has no effect on output and employment in either the short or the long-run. The remainder of this essay will present a discussion of the theoretical and empirical issues surrounding these two meanings. Monetary neutrality in a static macroeconomic model is synonymous with the term classical dichotomy. Standard models, such as Sargent (1986, Chapter 1) exhibit this property in which changes in the quantity of money generate proportional changes in all nominal variables in the economy, leaving real quantities unchanged. In other words, the model is homogeneous of degree zero in all nominal prices, nominal wages, and nominal money. The following is a very simple version of such a model: y = f(n) Production function (1) n d = f 0 1 ( W P ) Labor Demand (2) n s = g( W P ) Labor Supply (3) M d P M s P y = c + i + ḡ National Income Accounting Identity (4) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7) = M P Money supply function, (8) where y is real output, n is the level of employment, W and P are nominal wages and prices, c and i are real consumption and investment, g is government expenditure on goods and services, r is the real interest rate, and M is the nominal money stock. The superscripts 1

d and s refer to demand and supply, the overbar signifies that a variable is determined exogenously, and f 0 1 is the inverse of the first derivative of the production function. If we assume that the labor market clears, and so n s = n d, equations (1), (2) and (3) determine the level of employment, output, and the real wage, without reference to either the level of government expenditure or the stock of nominal money. The real and nominal parts of this system are separate. Furthermore, changes in money have no impact on any real variables. Nominal prices and nominal wages will move so that the real wage and the level of real money balances are left unchanged. Thus far, the discussion has been carried on in terms of a timeless, static model of the macroeconomy. It is now useful to introduce time, and distinguish between short-run and long-run neutrality. Let us think of the short run as several years and the long run as a limiting concept. Until recently, there was consensus that money was neutral in the longrun. That is to say the impact of all monetary changes on output died out, and so changes in the quantity of money result solely in changes in prices. Current developments in growth theory, primarily Romer s (1986) endogenous growth model, imply that short-run output declines, i.e. recessions, may cause decreases in (human) capital accumulation, which has permanent consequences. I should also note that there is little consensus on the issue of whether money is superneutrality. The term superneutrality refers to the case in which real quantities are unaffected by changes in the growth rate of money. There are clearly reasons to believe that changes in money growth rates can have real effects, as they create inflation, which is a tax on real balances, and they force agents to use more resource in changing their prices. The remainder of this article is devoted to the theoretical and empirical case for and against short-run neutrality. The work of Lucas (1973), Barro (1978) and new other new classical macroeconomists has extended the concept of the neutrality of money to mean that no anticipated changes in money, or any other aggregate-demand policy variable, does not change the level of real output in the short-run. Their argument combines market clearing with rational expectations to yield the result that it is solely unanticipated policy, such as unexpected monetary shocks, that can affect output. Furthermore, by assuming that the markets for goods and labor are competitive, and clear each period, these researchers 2

conclude that these shocks should be short lived. It is useful to phrase the issue in the language of macroeconomics textbooks. proposition that money is neutral in the long-run is the statement that shifts in aggregate demand do not effect the location of the long-run aggregate supply curve. The Put another way, current changes in the quantity of money leave the natural rate of unemployment unaffected. Thus, the statement that money is neutral in the short run means that, following a disturbance, the short-run aggregate supply curve shifts quickly to its long-run position. The empirical evidence for short-run neutrality is extremely weak. Cecchetti (1986) derives a test under very general conditions that requires only that the econometrician specify the length of the maximum lag with which unanticipated money should influence output. The finding that money growth lagged is correlated with output movements contradicts the new-classical proposition that aggregate-demand policy is neutral in the short run. It is worth noting that the evidence of long-horizon effects of money on output is prima facie evidence in favor of the long-run nonneutralities emphasized in endogenous growth theory. The new Keynesian economics, surveyed in Ball, Mankiw, and Romer (1989), provides the main alternative to the new classical proposition of short-run neutrality. While continuing to maintain the assumption that expectations are rational, new Keynesians examine the implications of a monopolisitically competitive structure in which changing prices is costly, and prices change at different times. Nominal rigidities are important for two reasons. First, the fact that changing prices is costly creates an aggregate-demand externality ; and second, the assumption of staggered price setting yields a mechanism for monetary shocks to be propagated over time. The remainder of this essay discusses each of these nonneutralities. To understand the source of the aggregate-demand externality, assume that each firm s demand depends on its relative price and the level of aggregate real balances, which is a measure of aggregate demand. This can be written as y D i = µ ² µ Pi M P P, (9) where P i is the firm s price level, P is the aggregate price level, M is the stock of nominal money. Now consider an experiment in which M drops, and ² is the relative price elasticity 3

of demand. If the firm spriceissetattheprofit maximizing level prior to the monetary contraction, then, as pointed out by Akerlof and Yellen (1985), according to the envelope theorem, the loss from not adjusting P i is second order. This non-adjustment at the firm level implies rigidity of the aggregate price level, and generates a first-order fall in real balances, reducing the aggregate demand for goods. While this externality generates firstorder output fluctuations, Ball and Romer (1990) show that the welfare loss is also secondorder. The aggregate demand externality clearly implies monetary nonneutrality, but it may not be important. The second source of nonneutrality in new Keynesian models emphasizes the temporal propagation of monetary shocks. The issue here is to understand how a purely nominal disturbance could have long-lived real effects that resemble business cycle fluctuations. How is it that following a monetary contraction a recession can last for several years? Even if prices are changed frequently, asynchronous timing will cause shocks to affect output for a long time. To understand how this works, begin by assuming the opposite. Assume that firms pricing decisions are perfectly synchronized. As is discussed in Ball and Cecchetti (1988) this is the only possibility under perfect competition, and so the results are analogous to those of the new classical macroeconomics. If all firms change prices on the first day of every month, then adjustment to any monetary shock will take at most one month. While the shock can change real balances during the month, every firm will adjust at the beginning of the next month, knowing that all other firms are doing the same. This price adjustment would eliminate the real balance effect of the shock. Lags for data collection in the real world may cause a one-month delay in this process. Nevertheless, the economy jumps quickly back to the optimal level and money is neutral in the short-run. Now consider the alternative in which firms adjust every month, but half change prices on the first of the month, while the other half change on the fifteenth. The reasons for this could be that firms receive idiosyncratic shocks at different times, as suggested by Ball and Romer (1989), or that firms stagger decisions in order to collect information, as described in Ball and Cecchetti (1988). Now consider a monetary shock that comes on the 10th of the month. Clearly this shock was unanticipated by the group that adjusted on the first of the 4

month, and so their prices will differ from those they would have set had they known the shock was coming. By contrast, the group adjusting on the fifteenth has the opportunity to take the shock into account. The assumption of imperfect competition implies that there is some substitutability between the products of the firms adjusting prices at different times, which is why the relative price appears in the demand function (9). That firms care about relative prices means that the firms adjusting on the fifteenth do not want their prices to move too far from the prices of the firms that adjust on the first. Thus, the expectation error built into the first group s prices finds its way into the second group s prices as well. Similarly, when the first group s turn to change prices again arrives on the first of the next month following the shock, they will take into account the prices of the firms that last set their prices, which now include the expectation errors of their original price set before to the shock. In this way the impact of the shock dies out only asymptotically, with the effect peaking after all firms have adjusted prices once. The result is that nominal shocks have only short-run real effects. Stephen G. Cecchetti 5

Bibliography Akerlof, George A. and Janet L. Yellen, Can Small Deviations from Rationality Make Significant Differences in Economic Equilibria? American Economic Review 75 (September 1985) pg. 708 720. Ball, Laurence and Stephen G. Cecchetti, Imperfect Information and Staggered Price Setting, American Economic Review 78 (December 1988) pg. 999 1018. and David Romer, The Equilibrium and Optimal Timing of Price Changes, Review of Economic Studies 56 (April 1989) p. 179 198. and, Real Rigidities and the Non-Neutrality of Money, Review of Economic Studies 57 (April 1990) pg. 183 203., N. Gregory Mankiw and David Romer, The New Keynesian Economics and the Output-Inflation Trade-off, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1988:1) pg. 1 82. Barro, Robert J., Unanticipated Money, Output and the Price Level, Journal of Political Economy 86 (August 1978) pg. 549 580. Cecchetti, Stephen G., Testing Short-Run Neutrality, Journal of Monetary Economics 17 (May 1986) 409 423. Lucas, Robert E. Jr., Some International Evidence on the Output-Inflation Tradeoff, American Economic Review 63 (June 1973) pg. 326 334. Patinkin, Don, Neutrality of Money, in John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman, editors, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Macmillan Press, Ltd., 1987, volume 3, pg. 639 645. Romer, Paul M., Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth, Journal of Political Economy 94 (October 1986) pg. 1002 1037. Sargent, Thomas J. Macroeconomic Theory, Second Edition. New York: Academic Press, 1986. 6