Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Similar documents
Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

EU BUDGET AND NATIONAL BUDGETS

EMPLOYMENT RATE IN EU-COUNTRIES 2000 Employed/Working age population (15-64 years)

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components

EUROPA - Press Releases - Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax...of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15 64 years)

International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships

DG TAXUD. STAT/11/100 1 July 2011

EU-28 RECOVERED PAPER STATISTICS. Mr. Giampiero MAGNAGHI On behalf of EuRIC

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15-64 years)

DETERMINANT FACTORS OF FDI IN DEVELOPED AND DEVELOPING COUNTRIES IN THE E.U.

Live Long and Prosper? Demographic Change and Europe s Pensions Crisis. Dr. Jochen Pimpertz Brussels, 10 November 2015

PUBLIC PROCUREMENT INDICATORS 2011, Brussels, 5 December 2012

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

THE IMPACT OF THE PUBLIC DEBT STRUCTURE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER COUNTRIES ON THE POSSIBILITY OF DEBT OVERHANG

Macroeconomic scenarios for skill demand and supply projections, including dealing with the recession

Fiscal rules in Lithuania

STAT/12/ October Household saving rate fell in the euro area and remained stable in the EU27. Household saving rate (seasonally adjusted)

Technical report on macroeconomic Member State results of the EUCO policy scenarios

Balanced-budget rules and aggregate instability: the role of capital utilization

January 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.2 bn euro 14.0 bn euro deficit for EU25

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

The Economics of Public Health Care Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

3 Labour Costs. Cost of Employing Labour Across Advanced EU Economies (EU15) Indicator 3.1a

Lowest implicit tax rates on labour in Malta, on consumption in Spain and on capital in Lithuania

Updates and revisions of national SUTs for the November 2013 release of the WIOD

May 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.9 bn euro 3.8 bn euro deficit for EU27

The gains from variety in the European Union

First estimate for 2011 Euro area external trade deficit 7.7 bn euro bn euro deficit for EU27

June 2014 Euro area international trade in goods surplus 16.8 bn 2.9 bn surplus for EU28

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

June 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 14.9 bn euro 0.4 bn euro surplus for EU27

August 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.6 bn euro 12.6 bn euro deficit for EU27

March 2005 Euro-zone external trade surplus 4.2 bn euro 6.5 bn euro deficit for EU25

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro 2st quarter 2016

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro 3 rd quarter 2017

CFA Institute Member Poll: Euro zone Stability Bonds

August 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.6 bn euro 14.2 bn euro deficit for EU25

3 Labour Costs. Cost of Employing Labour Across Advanced EU Economies (EU15) Indicator 3.1a

The Swedish approach to capital requirements in CRD IV

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Turkish Economic Review Volume 3 March 2016 Issue 1

EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts March 2011 Update of the November 2009 release

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

Lithuania: in a wind of change. Robertas Dargis President of the Lithuanian Confederation of Industrialists

11 th Economic Trends Survey of the Impact of Economic Downturn

Courthouse News Service

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro 4 th quarter 2018 (p)

January 2014 Euro area international trade in goods surplus 0.9 bn euro 13.0 bn euro deficit for EU28

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Economics and Finance 6 ( 2013 )

Taxation trends in the European Union Further increase in VAT rates in 2012 Corporate and top personal income tax rates inch up after long decline

European Advertising Business Climate Index Q4 2016/Q #AdIndex2017

Reporting practices for domestic and total debt securities

CANADA EUROPEAN UNION

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS

October 2010 Euro area unemployment rate at 10.1% EU27 at 9.6%

World Economic Outlook Central Europe and Baltic Countries

Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax ratio at 39.8% of GDP in 2007 Steady decline in top personal and corporate income tax rates since 2000

Statistics Brief. Investment in Inland Transport Infrastructure at Record Low. Infrastructure Investment. July

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND SITUATION ON THE LABOUR MARKET IN EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER COUNTRIES

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT IN THE MEMBER STATES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

Electricity & Gas Prices in Ireland. Annex Business Electricity Prices per kwh 2 nd Semester (July December) 2016

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

A BRIEF OVERVIEW OF THE ACTIVITY EFFICIENCY OF THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ROMANIA WITHIN A EUROPEAN CONTEXT

Measuring financial protection: an approach for the WHO European Region

FCCC/SBI/2010/10/Add.1

May 2009 Euro area external trade surplus 1.9 bn euro 6.8 bn euro deficit for EU27

Consumer credit market in Europe 2013 overview

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro for period 1 st quarter rd quarter 2016

Council conclusions on "First Annual Report to the European Council on EU Development Aid Targets"

Heraklis Polemarchakis The Debt of Nations

Consumer Credit. Introduction. June, the 6th (2013)

Financial wealth of private households worldwide

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018

August 2008 Euro area external trade deficit 9.3 bn euro 27.2 bn euro deficit for EU27

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017

1 Chapter 1: Economic growth

Spain France. England Netherlands. Wales Ukraine. Republic of Ireland Czech Republic. Romania Albania. Serbia Israel. FYR Macedonia Latvia

How to complete a payment application form (NI)

2017 Figures summary 1

Online Insurance Europe: BEST PRACTICES & TRENDS

January 2010 Euro area unemployment rate at 9.9% EU27 at 9.5%

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

EN RLMM 2018 Monday 10 & Tuesday 11 September Exeter, UK

Borderline cases for salary, social contribution and tax

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

January 2009 Euro area external trade deficit 10.5 bn euro 26.3 bn euro deficit for EU27

Transcription:

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series A Note on Oil Dependence and Economic Instability Luís Aguiar-Conraria and Yi Wen Working Paper 2006-060B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-060.pdf November 2006 Revised September 2007 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Research Division P.O. Box 442 St. Louis, MO 6366 The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors.

A Note on Oil Dependence and Economic Instability Luís Aguiar-Conraria NIPE, Economic Policies Research Unit Universidade do Minho aguiarconraria@gmail.com Yi Wen Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis yi.wen@stls.frb.org July 30, 2007 Abstract We show that dependence on foreign energy can increase economic instability by raising the likelihood of equilibrium indeterminacy, hence making uctuations driven by selfful lling expectations easier to occur. This is demonstrated in a standard neoclassical growth model. Calibration exercises, based on the estimated share of imported energy in production for several countries, show that the degree of reliance on foreign energy for many countries can easily make an otherwise determinate and stable economy indeterminate and unstable. Keywords: Indeterminacy, Energy Imports, Externality, Returns to Scale, Sunspots, Self-Ful lling Expectations. JEL Classi cation: E3, E20, E30. This is a substantially shortened version of our working paper, "Oil Dependence and Economic Instability" (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 2006). We thank Karl Shell, Nicholas Kiefer, and an anonymous referee for comments. The usual disclaimer applies. Correspondence: Yi Wen, Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 6366-0442, USA. Email: yi.wen@stls.frb.org

Introduction Sharp increases in the prices of oil have triggered two signi cant world-wide recessions since World War II: one in 974-75 and another in 979-8. The underling reason is that many industrial economies depend heavily on imported energy in production, making them vulnerable to changes in the prices of oil in the world market. Although it is well known that increases in the prices of foreign energy can act like adverse productivity shocks to domestic economy, many economists also argue energy price shocks by themselves are not su cient for causing a massive recession as large as we experienced in the 970s and the early 980s. For example, Bernanke et al. (997), Barsky and Killian (200) and Leduc and Sill (2004) argue that monetary policies signi cantly aggravated the negative impact of oil shocks; and Hamilton (2003) argues that a sharp decrease of aggregate demand due to pessimistic expectations of the future at the time of oil shocks exacerbated the negative impact of higher energy prices. This paper claims that reliance on foreign energy has another potentially important e ect on economic activity it destabilizes the economy by increasing its likelihood of indeterminacy, hence making the economy more susceptible to uctuations driven by self-ful lling expectations. Economic data show that energy imports account for a signi cant fraction of total costs in domestic production for industrial countries. For example, Table shows that the cost shares of imported energy can be as high as 6% of a country s GDP. We argue that cost share of foreign energy as high as indicated in Table can easily make an otherwise stable economy susceptible to sunspots-derive uctuations. The framework we adopt to make our point is Aguiar-Conraria and Wen (2007), which introduced oil into an indeterminate RBC model similar to Benhabib and Farmer (994) and Wen (998). In that paper, we showed that the large negative impact of oil price shocks on GDP and investment in the 970s can be better understood by a multiplier-accelerator mechanism based on indeterminacy. However, we did not formally and systematically investigate the relationship between the magnitude of foreign energy shares in GDP and the conditions of indeterminacy. In this note we formally prove that the dependence of production on imported energy (such as oil and natural gas) can make indeterminacy easier to arise. For example, the required returns to scale for indeterminacy in the model of Wen (998) can be reduced by 50% when the share of imported energy reaches 5% of GDP. Based on realistic and conservative estimates of the aggregate returns to scale, a cost share even as low as 5% of GDP can subject an otherwise stable economy to sunspots-driven uctuations. The data for all EU-25 countries are taken from Eurostat (2006). The energy share for the EU-5 countries is easy to estimate based on the database. But to estimate the energy share of the remaining 0 countries: Czech Republic, Estónia, Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, Hungary, Malta, Poland, Slovenia, and Slovakia, we assume the unit import cost of oil or oil equivalent is the same as for the other EU-5 countries. The gure for Ukraine is from Davis et al. (2005). For the United States, we use data from the Energy Information Administration. Finally, information for South Korea was found in Rabobank (2006). All data refers to the year of 2004, except for South Korea, which refers to 2005. 2

Table. Cost Share of Imported Energy in GDP 2 The Model Lithuania 6:0% Luxembourg 3:6% Ukraine 5:7% Austria 3:4% Slovakia 2:% Portugal 3:5% Latvia 8:3% Greece 3:2% Belgium 7:7% Finland 2:9% South Korea 7:6% Sweden 2:8% Netherlands 5:8% Spain 2:8% Estonia 5:5% Germany 2:4% Hungary 5:4% France 2:3% Czech Republic 5:2% Italy 2:0% Malta 4:9% United States :8% Cyprus 4:5% Ireland :8% Slovenia 4:0% United Kingdom :4% Poland 3:9% Denmark :3% A representative agent chooses a trajectory for consumption (c), hours (n), capacity utilization (u), energy demand (e), and capital accumulation ( k) _ to solve max Z 0 exp( h i t) log(c t ) n + t =( + ) dt () subject to _k = k + y(uk; n; e) c pe; (2) where p denotes international energy price, which is exogenous to the economy. The agent pays the amount pe in terms of output to foreigners to receive energy imports. Note that trade is balanced in every period since the cost of energy imports is fully paid for with exports of output. Hence, national income is given by y pe, which equals domestic consumption and capital investment ( k _ + k). The production technology is given by y(uk; n; e) = (uk) k n n e e ; (3) where k + n + e = and is a measure of production externalities and is de ned as a function of average aggregate output which individual rms take as parametric: = [(uk) k n n (e) e ] ; 0: (4) 3

The rate of capital depreciation, ; is time varying and is endogenously determined in the model by the relationship = u ; (5) which states that capital depreciates faster if used more intensively. We require > ; which imposes a convex cost structure on capital utilization. To see the e ects of foreign energy on the economy, we can substitute out and the optimal demand for e in the production function to obtain the following reduced-form production function in equilibrium, y = A (uk) (+) k (+)e n (+)n (+)e ; (6) (+)e where A = e (+)e p is a Solow residual, which is inversely related to the energy price. 2 In this reduced-form production function, the e ective returns to scale are measured by ( + ) k ( + ) e + ( + ) n ( + ) e ; (7) which increases with e under the constraint ( k + n + e ) =, provided that > 0. Hence, the reliance on imported energy ampli es the true returns to scale when there are externalities. The following proposition shows formally that indeterminacy is easier to arise when e increases. Proposition The necessary and su cient conditions for indeterminacy are given by n ( n ) > > [( + )( e) n ] ( + ) k : (8) n + ( + )( k + e ) Proof. See the Appendix. It is clear from condition (8) that an increase in e ; either holding n constant or holding ( e + n ) constant, will decrease the term on the right-hand side, making indeterminacy easier to arise. Note that for realistic parameter values the inequality on the left-hand side does not bind. Calibration. We calibrate the model s structural parameters following Aguiar-Conraria and Wen (2007). Namely, we correspond one unit of time to a quarter, we set the inverse labor supply elasticity = 0 (Hansen s indivisible labor), the rate of time preference = 0:0 (analogous to the discount factor of 0:99 in a discrete-time model), = :4 (implying a steadystate rate of = 0:025; see the Appendix), and the labor elasticity of output n = 0:7. Given these parameter values, the following table shows the relationship between the share of foreign energy in GDP and the threshold value of the production externality ( ) for inducing indeterminacy. 2 This negative relationship substantiates the claim that oil price shocks act like adverse productivity shocks. 4

Table 2. The E ect of Factor Shares on Indeterminacy Energy Imports Required Reduction Share ( o ) Externality of 0.00 0.094 0 0.04 0.083 4% 0.08 0.067 28% 0.2 0.054 42% 0.6 0.042 56% We observe in Table 2 that as the share of foreign factor in domestic production increases, the threshold value of the production externality for inducing indeterminacy ( ) decreases signi cantly. For example, when we increase the share parameter of imported energy e from zero percent to 8 percent, the reduction in the externality is 28%. And if we increase the share parameter to 6 percent, then the reduction in the externality is 56%. 3 If we compare the values of Table with Table 2, we see that the required returns to scale for indeterminacy may vary between :04 and :0 in the presence of foreign energy imports. These values imply that many industrial countries are in the dangerous zone of indeterminacy. For example, Laitner and Stolyarov (2004) found the estimated returns to scale around :09 : for the U.S. economy. Inklaar (2006) found the estimated returns to scale around :6 for Germany and :2 for France. Hansen and Knowles (998) found the average estimated returns to scale around :05 for high income OECD countries (including Australia, Belgium, Canada, Finland, France, West Germany, Japan, Norway, Sweden, the United Kingdom and the United States). Miyagawa et al. (2006) found estimated returns to scale in Japan about :075, and Kwack and Sun (2005) found it to be around : for South Korea. With these numbers in mind, it is clear that dependence on imported energy can signi cantly increase a country s risk of indeterminacy, thereby making the country more susceptible to sunspots-driven uctuations. 3 Conclusion The impact of oil price shocks on economic uctuations have been widely recognized. But the relationship between economic stability and the reliance on foreign energy has not been fully investigated in the literature. This paper shows that dependence of domestic production on imported energy, such as oil or natural gas, can signi cantly increase the economy s instability in the presence of externalities or increasing returns to scale, because it reduces the required 3 Table 2 is computed under the assumption that the foreign imported factor is mainly a substitute for capital, hence when e increases, n remains constant but k decreases such that k + e remains constant (assuming constant returns to scale at the rm level). If we assume imported energy is mainly a substitute for labor instead (i.e., n + e is xed), then a larger e has the same qualitative consequences, although less dramatic. 5

degree of returns to scale for indeterminacy. As a result, the economy is more susceptible to endogenous uctuations driven by self-ful lling expectations. Appendix Let exp( t) be the Lagrangian multiplier for the household s budget constraint, the rst order conditions with respect to fc; n; e; u; kg are given respectively by = c ; n y = n y p = e e ; u y k = k u ; and _ = k y k + u + : To simplify analysis, we utilize the reducedform production function (which is obtained by substituting out the optimal demand for energy and the capacity utilization rate in the production function in equilibrium), n ; y = ~ Ak k (+)( ) (+)( +e) k n n(+) (+)( k +e) ; (9) where ~ A ( k ) (+) k (+)e (+)( k +e) e (+)( +e) k p : The rst order conditions and the budget constraint can be simpli ed to the following _c system of equations, c = k y k ; k _ = k + n y c; and c = y n ; where n + output is given by (9). In the steady state, we have y k = k ; c y = k + n ; c k = (( ) k + n) ( ) k ; and n = n + ( ) k + n. From the budget constraint and the Euler equation for consumption one can derive the steady state depreciation rate = ; which implies = + : Linearizing the economy around its steady state, the dynamics of the model can be represented by a system of two linear di erential equations: _c _k! = M c k! ; (0) where 2 M = 4 n(+) n ( n+ e(+))(+) n (+) n(+) n ( n+ e(+))(+) n (+) (( ) k + n) (+)(+) k ( ) ( n+ e(+))(+) n (+) + k (+)(+) k ( k ( )+ n) (( n+ e(+))(+) n (+)) ( ) 3 5 : The model exhibits local indeterminacy if and only if the eigenvalues of M are both negative. This is true if and only if the determinant of M is positive and the trace of M is negative. The determinant and trace of M are give, respectively, by det (M) = n ( + ) n k + k + (n+e(+))(+) n (+) (+)(+) k ( + ) ( e ( + ) n ) ; where = ( k( Tr (M) = )+ n)(+)(+) ( ) (+)( n (+)( k ( )+ n)) (( n+ e(+))(+) n (+))( k (+)) ; 2 (( n+ e(+))(+) n (+)) > 0: 6

The condition det (M) > 0 implies ( e k ) > > (( + )( e) n ) ( + ) k : () e + k n + ( + )( k + e ) Note that the numerator of Tr(M) trace is always negative, so the trace will be negative when the denominator is positive, which is equivalent to the condition > (( + )( e) n ) ( + ) k ; (2) n + ( + )( k + e ) which is the same as the right-hand side of condition (). References [] Aguiar-Conraria, L. and Y. Wen, 2007, Understanding the large negative impact of oil shocks, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39(4), 925-44. [2] Aguiar-Conraria, L. and Y. Wen, 2006, Oil Dependence and Economic Instability, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 2006-060A. [3] Barsky, R. B. and L. Kilian, 200, Do we really know that oil caused the great stag ation? A monetary alternative, in Ben S. Bernanke and Kenneth S. Rogo, eds., Macroeconomics Annual, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press for NBER, 37-83. [4] Benhabib, J. and R. Farmer, 994, Indeterminacy and increasing returns, Journal of Economic Theory 63, 9-4. [5] Bernanke, B.S., M. Gertler and M. Watson, 997, Systematic monetary policy and the e ects of oil price shocks, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,, 9-42. [6] Davis, M., R. Piontkivsky, O. Pindyuk and D. Ostojic, 2005, Ukraine: The Impact of Higher Natural Gas and Oil Prices, World Bank. [7] Eurostat, 2006, Energy Yearly Statistics 2004, Eurostat Publications. [8] Hamilton, J., 2003, What is an oil shock?, Journal of Econometrics, 3, 363-398. [9] Hansen, P. and S. Knowles, 998, Human capital and returns to scale, Journal of Economic Studies, 25, 8-23. [0] Inklaar, R., 2006, Cyclical Productivity in Europe and the United States, Evaluating the Evidence on Returns to Scale and Input Utilization, CEPR Discussion Paper no. 550. [] Kwack, S., L. Sun, 2005, Economies of scale, technological progress, and the sources of economic growth: case of Korea, 969 2000, Journal of Policy Modeling, 27, 265-283. 7

[2] Laitner, J. and D. Stolyarov, 2004, Aggregate returns to scale and embodied technical change: Theory and measurement using stock market data, Journal of Monetary Economics, 5, 9 234. [3] Leduc, S. and K. Sill, 2004, A Quantitative Analysis of Oil-Price Shocks, Systematic Monetary Policy, and Economic Downturns, Journal of Monetary Economics, 5. 78-808. [4] Miyagawa, T., Y. Sakuragawa and M. Takizawa, 2006, Productivity and Business Cycles in Japan: Evidence from Japanese Industry Data, Japanese Economic Review, 57, 6-86. [5] Rabobank, 2006, Country Report South Korea, Country Risk Research. [6] Wen, Y., 998, Capacity utilization under increasing returns to scale, Journal of Economic Theory, 8, 7-36. 8