So who is right? Income is not the problem

Similar documents
Level 2 l Upper intermediate

Family and Work. 1. Labor force participation of married women

Basic Income? Basically unaffordable, say most Canadians

Manage Your Life Insurance Policy

Time for a. New Deal. for Young People. Broadbent Institute poll highlights millennials precarious future and boomers worries.

More & More Americans Having to Work Past Age 70

Retirement NOW REPORT. Life s brighter under the sun

Retirement planning YOUR GUIDE

The consequences for communities of rising unemployment David Blanchflower

MOVING THE NEEDLE ON EMPLOYEE FINANCIAL WELLNESS

What really matters to women investors

The Future of Retirement:

Almost everyone is familiar with the

Issues linked to Settlement and population. The UK s ageing population; a contemporary geographical issue

Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends

Begin before the end

Heather Boushey, Senior Economist, Center for American Progress Action Fund. March 3, 2009

Young People and Money Report

Retirement Check-In survey

The Minimum Wage Ain t What It Used to Be

The 2008 Statistics on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION

Testimony before the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission. Heather Boushey, Senior Economist, Center for American Progress Action Fund

TRUE FACTS AND FALSE PERCEPTIONS ABOUT FEDERAL DEFICITS" Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Springfield, Missouri December 6, 1988

Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends

Full file at

Financial Guidebook for Women

Transcript of podcast with Alexander Pitt: A Dream Deferred: Inequality Across Generations In Europe

Singapore The Future of Retirement Report Generations and journeys

Download the full paper»

Jeremy Siegel on Dow 15,000 By Robert Huebscher December 18, 2012

HEALTHCARE S COMING ECONOMIC CRISIS IS HEALTHCARE TOO BIG TO FAIL? OR IS FAILURE EXACTLY WHAT WE NEED? Sam Glick

The gig economy. Achieving financial wellness with confidence.

Too old to hire, too young to retire.

Investing in Children

INTRODUCTION 1 1. RETIREMENT IN FRANCE 2 2. THE CHANGING NATURE OF RETIREMENT 2 3. THE STATE OF RETIREMENT READINESS 6

THIRD EDITION. ECONOMICS and. MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman Robin Wells. Chapter 18. The Economics of the Welfare State

Public Sector Statistics

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

STRUCTURAL REFORM REFORMING THE PENSION SYSTEM IN KOREA. Table 1: Speed of Aging in Selected OECD Countries. by Randall S. Jones

Challenges on Dutch and Finnish roads towards extending citizens working life: The current debates.

A Guide to Planning a Financially Secure Retirement

INTRODUCTION AEGON GERMANY REPRESENTATIVE 1 1. RETIREMENT IN GERMANY 2 2. THE CHANGING NATURE OF RETIREMENT 2 3. THE STATE OF RETIREMENT READINESS 6

How Well GDP Measures the Well-Being of Society

Statistical information can empower the jury in a wrongful termination case

U.S. Memo. Date: August 21, 2018 To: Express Employment Professionals From: The Harris Poll Subject: 2018 Survey of Blue Collar Americans

The Impact of Inflation

T. Rowe Price 2015 FAMILY FINANCIAL TRADE-OFFS SURVEY

The Allianz American Legacies Pulse Survey

Aging Population Poses Global Challenges Health Care, Other Rising Costs to Strain Budgets in U.S. and Abroad

Francis Cairncross: Professor Friedman, in recent years, we have seen an acceleration in inflation all over the world. What has caused that?

DISRUPTIVE DEMOGRAPHICS IN SUPPLY CHAIN MANAGEMENT

The View from. Chicago: 1,000 residents share their perspectives on life in Chicagoland, the local economy and personal finances.

Precarious to prosperous: Tackling income volatility in Canada. Bharat Masrani Group President and Chief Executive Officer, TD Bank Group

Article from. The Actuary. August/September 2015 Volume 12 Issue 4

ec nfip Economists for Inclusive Prosperity

The labour force participation of older men in Canada

Statement of Justin Wolfers

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

Yes, You Can Rai e Financially Aware Kids

The FAMILY Act. Recipes for Rational Government from the Independent Women s Forum. By Carrie Lukas, Managing Director, Independent Women s Forum

Appropriate monetary policy and the strong economy Before the Committee on Banking and Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives July 23, 1997

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

Issues For Couples. Preparing for your retirement: Workbook Four

Comprehensive Paid Family and Medical Leave for Today s Families and Workplaces

Independent Consultant Survey overall results including data cuts by geography, age and gender. December 2018

Glenn Stevens: The resources boom

MONITORING JOBS AND INFLATION*

The Impact of Globalisation on Systems of Social Security

Planning for your retirement. Generating an income in retirement

Conference summaries. Finnish Centre for Pensions, 19 May Susan Kuivalainen, Kati Kuitto, Kathrin Komp, Tuukka Niemi, Tuomo Honkanen

INTRODUCTION 1 1. RETIREMENT IN GERMANY 2 2. THE CHANGING NATURE OF RETIREMENT 2 3. THE STATE OF RETIREMENT READINESS 6

Attitudes towards New Zealand s financial markets. Investor confidence research May 2018

Issues 2012 THE UNEMPLOYMENT CRISIS FOR YOUNGER WORKERS. No. 14 May 2012

Buying Term Life Insurance in Your 30s

Scottrade Financial Behavior Study. Scottrade Financial Behavior Study 1

Introduction 1 Key Findings 1 The Survey Retirement landscape 2

Check against delivery

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011.

UBS Investor Watch. U.S. insights on investor sentiment / 1Q Who s the boss? Business ownership: Who s in, who s out and who s holding back

The Impact of Inflation

Lower savings rates now may have long-term implications for mothers, who are also less engaged in calculating and planning for their retirement.

Generations Apart. Allianz Life Insurance Company of North America Allianz Life Insurance Company of New York

The potential $2 trillion prize from longer working lives

Betterment s 2018 Report: GIG ECONOMY AND THE FUTURE OF RETIREMENT

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. Public University of Navarre Pamplona, Spain May 21 st 2018 J. E. Stiglitz

Using a Credit Card. Name Date

TODAY S RETIREMENT CRISIS Only 1 in 10 Americans Currently Saving Enough

A small business guide to. Income replacement for business owners

Patterns of Unemployment

Economic Theories & Debt Driven Realities

MYTHS. The Truth about Poverty in Abbotsford

Set Yourself Up for Retirement Success

Your Guide to Life Insurance for Families

Canada Report. The Future of Retirement Healthy new beginnings

EAGLE COUNTY COMMISSIONERS PUBLIC OPINION SURVEY. May 16-19, 2016

17 th Annual Transamerica Retirement Survey Influences of Gender on Retirement Readiness

YOUR FINANCIAL FUTURE

Lesson 12 - Fiscal Policy: A Two-Act Play

Chapter 4 Read this chapter together with unit four in the study guide. Consumer Choice

Lawn Mowing, Burglar Alarms, Whales, Drugs and Old Raincoats: GDP and Economic Well-Being

Transcription:

AI, Income, Employment, and Meaning Betsey Stevenson* * Betsey Stevenson is an Associate Professor of Economics and Public Policy, Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI; a visiting Associate Professor of Economics, University of Sydney, Sydney, Australia; a Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts; Research Affiliate, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London, United Kingdom, and a Research Fellow, CESifo, Munich, Germany. E mail address is betseys@umich.edu). The evolution of artificial intelligence evokes strong emotions in people. Some imagine a dystopia in which people are replaced by machines. Machines will develop the content we read, the entertainment we enjoy. Artificial intelligence will pick our friends and our politicians, and ultimately take away any sense of human agency. And worst of all, those machines will deprive us of work. Human beings will lose meaning and income and perhaps ultimately be driven to extinction. At the other end of the spectrum are those that envision the potential for utopia. With machines doing all the work, people will have plenty of income, yet very little unpleasant work to do. Instead, people will spend their days enjoying art and music. They will pursue their passions unburdened by the need to provide for their basic wants. They will feed their intellectual curiosity and fulfil the human demand for personal interactions. In short, people will be able to enjoy their lives with the freedom from time and money constraints, that artificial intelligence provides. So who is right? Income is not the problem Economists think that we know the answer, at least part of it. Most economists believe that automation promises a future of higher income that stems from the higher productivity that artificial intelligence will provide. In September 2017, the Chicago Booth IGM Forum's Economic Experts Panel asked 41 economists from top universities in the United States whether they strongly agreed, agreed, were uncertain, disagreed, or strongly disagreed with the following statement: Rising use of robots and artificial intelligence in advanced countries is likely to create benefits large enough that they could be used to compensate those workers who are substantially negatively affected for their lost wages. 1 The answer was clear, no one disagreed with that statement. A few economists ten percent were uncertain, and the modal answer was agree, rather than strongly agree. Yet, it s clear that economists believe that artificial intelligence represents an opportunity for substantial economic gains. Indeed, productivity gains have been at the heart of improvements in living standards from the beginning of time. And so, it is difficult to imagine a world in which 1 IGM Economic Experts Panel, 2017. http://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/robots and artificial intelligence 2 (accessed 12.15.17).

productivity gains do not generate benefits sufficiently large that we could compensate the losers. Therefore, the relevant question is whether we would compensate the losers. Here economists are more skeptical. Economics tells us that there will be income gains, but our social and political structure help determine how they will be distributed. Who Gets the Gains from Automation? Much of the skepticism about being able to successfully redistribute income comes from a lack of trust that the political process will successfully manage redistribution in a world in which income is primarily generated by capital. The history of the last several decades has certainly not been encouraging on that front. The share of income held by the top 1% of the population has risen to nearly 20 percent, from around 10 percent in 1980, while the share going to the bottom 50 percent of the population has fallen to 12 percent from 20 percent in 1980. 2 Currently we are failing to redistribute the gains from technological advances and so the concerns that distribution will be a challenge are supported by our recent past. What will we do with ourselves? Yet, the concern runs deeper than wondering whether as a society we could manage to redistribute income. Most economists are concerned about how we will allocate jobs and underneath that concern lies a belief that work matters independent of the earnings that are generated by the work. Essentially, many people are skeptical that people could successfully find engaging and emotionally rewarding ways to spend their time, if they were not working. One of the IGM Forum panelists, Robert Hall, expressed his concern most concretely Those not in the labor force are unhappy and inclined to opiods. So economists are fearful about what will happen if people lose employment opportunities, yet economic history provides economists with optimism that employment will adapt. Which is why so many economists wonder what, if anything, will be different about artificial intelligence compared to the industrial revolution or other important periods of rapid technological change. Economists intuition around the impact of technological change on employment comes from considering how employment has adapted following previous periods of technological change. Here, once again, economists have a united view: Technological change has not historically reduced employment. This view of economists is seen in a February 2014 question posed to the Chicago Booth IGM Forum's Economic Experts Panel. Forty four economists from top universities in the United States were asked whether they strongly agreed, agreed, were uncertain, disagreed, or strongly disagreed with the following statement: 2 World Wealth and Income database http://wid.world/country/usa/

Advancing automation has not historically reduced employment in the United States. 3 Economists are roughly united in agreeing with this statement, with only 4 percent disagreeing and 8 percent uncertain. 4 Yet, when the IGM Economic Experts Panel were asked in September 2017 whether they strongly agreed, agreed, were uncertain, disagreed, or strongly disagreed with the following statement: Holding labor market institutions and job training fixed, rising use of robots and artificial intelligence is likely to increase substantially the number of workers in advanced countries who are unemployed for long periods. 1 This is where economics lends a less clear answer and economists are divided on this question: 44 percent agree, 26 percent disagree, and 31 percent are uncertain. Is this a contradiction or a different view about artificial intelligence compared to other technologies? I don t think it is either. Instead, I believe these answers reflect the difference in what happens in the long run versus the short run. In the long run technological change leads to prosperity and new jobs arise as we adjust to our new wealth, develop new skills, and come up with new ways to use human skills. In the short run however there is often a disruption. The long run One of the confusions around what will happen to employment and unemployment stems from not separating short run vs. long run effects. When most of us think about artificial intelligence and increased automation, we are trying to think about what the long run future holds, and our intuition comes from considering how growth has changed how people live across generations. It's not how it's changed our lives over the last five years, but instead contrasting how we live our lives and if you are reading this it involves large periods of intellectual contemplation with how our own family members ten generations back spent their lives. In the 1800s, the vast majority of Americans worked in agriculture and very few of them spent their time thinking about ideas. Today, 2 percent of Americans are directly employed in agriculture. There are more people employed in the public school system than in agriculture. In sum, few of us are in the jobs or careers that our great great great great grandparents were in and many of us work in jobs today that didn t exist a single generation ago. One of the IGM panelists, Nancy Stokey, made it clear she was thinking about the long run: If this had been true over the last two centuries, almost no one would be working anymore. When you take a really long run view, it has to be true that automation has not reduced employment, at least not at as rapid a pace as the automation has itself occurred. In fact, many 3 IGM Economic Experts Panel, 2014. <http://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/robots> (accessed 12.15.17). 4 88 percent is adjusted for respondents confidence in their answer. Among all respondents, 76 percent agreed and 9 percent had no opinion.

economists regard it as a puzzle that paid work has been remarkably stable even as nations have become increasingly prosperous and its citizens might have been expected to use more of their higher income to choose to consume more leisure. In the long run employment and hours worked has declined Yet, despite our intuition, employment has tended to decline with technological progress. The difference between our beliefs about how technological progress has impacted employment and what has actually happened reflect two things. The first is that hours worked and employment has not declined by as much as one might have predicted. The second is that economists tend to think about employment in a model in which people who want to work can find jobs. Hours of work have declined in most countries with productivity growth. Figure 1 shows average annual hours worked in a handful of developed countries since 1970. Annual hours worked declined fairly steadily in France, Germany, and Japan. The United States and the United Kingdom had smaller declines. Yet in each country, the annual hours worked fell. To think more broadly about employment, childhood employment has been almost eliminated in developed countries. And employment of young adults, those ages 15 to 25 have declined as young people focus on investing in further human capital. On the other end of the lifecycle, life expectancy has increased, while retirement ages have fallen in most developed countries. Figure 1: Average Annual Hours Worked Source: OECD (2017), "Hours Worked: Average annual hours actually worked", OECD Employment and Labour Market Statistics (database). https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?datasetcode=anhrs (Accessed September 13, 2017)

Work has declined in terms of the number and share of our life in terms of hours and days that we're going to spend working. The decline in work has occurred through the interaction of economic growth with government policies. For example, extended retirement has been facilitated by government pension and retirement programs. The dramatic reduction in child labor was facilitated by child labor laws. The demand for these programs and regulations is itself facilitated by the higher income that productivity growth creates. Decreases in employment because of childhood education and retirement are thought to be improvements in living standards and not something we need or want to fix. However, they do require income redistribution. Older generations must support children, either through families or government redistribution (such as child tax credits, child allowances, child healthcare subsidies, etc). Yet, most people agree that this is an improvement few are trying to get kids back into the workforce to financially support themselves. Something similar is true at the other end of the lifecycle. While the elderly can save for retirement, redistribution allows those who are retired to share in continued economic growth. Short run disruption The real uncertainty with artificial intelligence is what will the disruption be like and how will we manage people through it. Most economists think there will be people who are hurt through decreased demand for their skills. There might be longer spells of unemployment and a larger need for worker retraining. There might be jobs that workers don't want, or aren't qualified to do. While we can prepare a new generation for a world in which robots do many of the jobs, preparing a generation midway through their life is harder. People are resistant to starting over, they mourn what they ve lost, and they resent a definition of progress that leaves them diminished in status and income. The loss of income should be easier to solve than the loss of status. So how important is work and what do we know about it? Is work about the income that it generates or about the meaning and order it gives to our days? Much of the debate about the potential impact of automation on employment is really a debate about how we ll spend our time. So it is useful to separate out the question of what will we do with our time if the robots take our jobs, from the question of whether we can find a stable and fair distribution of income in such a scenario. And it s useful to realize that the answers in the long run may be very different to what happens in the short run. Yet, how we handle the short run will ultimately influence our long run outcomes. There is work outside of employment Work is a broader concept than paid labor. Paid labor is the result of a trade off between leisure, home produced goods and market produced goods. This matters from a measurement perspective because the 1970s was a period of very rapid substitution, with non market produced goods being substituted by market produced goods. Women stopped making clothes, and making pies from scratch, and cakes from scratch, and started going to work, and buying

clothes, and buying pies, and buying cake mixes. Technological change occurred in a way that crowded out homemade goods and crowded in women's labor force participation. 5 Should we think about this as increasing or decreasing work? One thing is clear, work shifted from outside our typical measurement scope to inside it. For example, I suspect that there are fewer childcare workers today than 40 years ago if you count every stay at home mom with children as a childcare worker. Yet, time use surveys reveal that the decline in hours worked is smaller than measured hours of employment suggest, at least since the 1970s. If we look at time use surveys, dads are working more hours, even though they're working less in the labor force. 6 Once we account for hours spent on childcare and housework, men work more hours than they did in the 1960s. Why consider childcare and housework hours? If we want to think about really measuring what happens to work we need a more holistic sense of what work is. Particularly if the question is whether we can find meaningful ways to spend our time outside of paid work. Artificial intelligence won t replace the need for human connection, both in our personal lives and professionally. A robot may be able to care for an elderly bed bound person, but it s unlikely to produce the joy and satisfaction of connecting with a human being. Will there be more paid jobs caring for one another? Undoubtedly. But will our higher incomes also allow us to choose to work less in order to provide more uncompensated care for our friends and family? I hope so. Productivity growth ultimately gives us better lives and more options In the end, there's really two separate questions: there's an employment question, in which the fundamental question is can we find fulfilling ways to spend our time if robots take our jobs? And there s an income question, can we find a stable and fair distribution of income? The answer to both will depend on not just how technology changes but how our institutions change in reaction to technological change. Do we embrace technology and increase funding for education, worker training, the arts, community service? Or do we allow inequality to continue to grow unchecked, pitting workers against those investing in robots? The challenge for society is to ensure that we solve both problems. That we help shape a society in which people can find fulfilling ways to spend their time. And to solve that problem we must also solve the separate problem of finding a stable and fair distribution of income. 5 Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2007). Marriage and Divorce: Changes and Their Driving Forces. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27 52. 6 Council of Economic Advisors, 2014, Eleven facts about American families and work. https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/sites/default/files/docs/eleven_facts_about_family_and_work_final.pdf