The Multiplier Model

Similar documents
The Government and Fiscal Policy

ECO403 Macroeconomics Solved Online Quiz For Midterm Exam Preparation Spring 2013

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand P R I N C I P L E S O F. N. Gregory Mankiw. Introduction

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Learning Objectives. 1. Describe how the government budget surplus is related to national income.

Fiscal policy. Macroeconomics 5th lecture

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions

The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

Lesson 12 The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

ECO102. Macroeconomics Lecture 5

Principles of Macroeconomics Fall Answer Key - Problem Set 1

Econ 102 Exam 2 Name ID Section Number

Chapter 22. Adding Government and Trade to the Simple Macro Model. In this chapter you will learn to. Introducing Government. Government Purchases

SOLUTION ECO 202Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #1 LAST NAME FIRST NAME STUDENT NUMBER. University of Toronto June 18, 2002 INSTRUCTIONS:

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY LECTURE 3: AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND EQUILIBRIUM INCOME

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

Topic 1: National Accounting, Keynesian Income-Expenditure Model and Fiscal Policy

Lesson 8: Aggregate demand; consumption, investment, public expenditure and taxation.

Part IV: The Keynesian Revolution:

I. The Money Market. A. Money Demand (M d ) Handout 9

Econ 302 Fall Don t forget to download a copy of the Homework Cover Sheet. Mark the location where you handed in your work.

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 1 Solutions Spring 2003

Business Cycles II: Theories

Econ 98- Chiu Spring 2005 Final Exam Review: Macroeconomics

Chapter 10 Aggregate Demand I

Midsummer Examinations 2011

ECON2010 test 2 study guide

Midterm #2, version A, given Spring 2002 Note question #50 is from Chapter 11, which students are not responsible for on Exam 2 - Summer 02.

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH FISCAL POLICY.

Introduction. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame. Sims (ND) Introduction Fall / 26

EXPENDITURE APPROACH: The expenditures on all final goods and services made by all sectors of the economy are added to calculate GDP. Expenditures are

Keynesian Theory (IS-LM Model): how GDP and interest rates are determined in Short Run with Sticky Prices.

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Spring 03

Pre-Test Chapter 9 ed17

Econ 98- Chiu Spring Midterm 2 Review: Macroeconomics

q Multiple choice - Improving your knowledge of the key concepts

Principle of Macroeconomics, Summer B Practice Exam

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output. The Core of Macroeconomic Theory. Aggregate Output and Aggregate Income (Y)

The Multiplier Effect

Short run Output and Expenditure

The Aggregate Expenditures Model. A continuing look at Macroeconomics

The text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under the CC BY-NC-SA without attribution as requested by the works original creator or licensee

Principles of Macroeconomics December 17th, 2005 name: Final Exam (100 points)

Chapter 25 Fiscal Policy Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Foreign Trade and the Exchange Rate

Economics 302 Intermediate Macroeconomic

This is Appendix B: Extensions of the Aggregate Expenditures Model, appendix 2 from the book Economics Principles (index.html) (v. 2.0).

2. THE KEYNESIAN THEORY OF DETERMINATION OF NATIONAL INCOME

ECO 2013: Macroeconomics Valencia Community College

ECON 1102: MACROECONOMICS 1 Chapter 1: Measuring Macroeconomic Performance, Output and Prices

This is IS-LM, chapter 21 from the book Finance, Banking, and Money (index.html) (v. 1.1).

Notes for Econ FALL 2010 Midterm 1 Exam

Homework Assignment #6. Due Tuesday, 11/28/06. Multiple Choice Questions:

AQA Economics A-level

MACROECONOMICS. Aggregate Demand I: Building the IS-LM Model. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

Lecture 8: The Aggregate Expenditures Model Reference - Chapter 7

McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Macroeconomics Mankiw 6th Edition

Macroeconomic Analysis Econ 6022 Level I

Principles of Macroeconomics December 15th, 2005 name: Final Exam (100 points)

Economics 1012 A : Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Second Midterm Examination October 19, 2007

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

Objectives AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Chapter 47: HL extension the Keynesian multiplier (2.3)

The influence of Monetary And Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

Taking an Economic Pulse: Measuring National Output

ECO403 - Macroeconomics Faqs For Midterm Exam Preparation Spring 2013

CIE Economics AS-level

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics. Chapter 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

EC and MIDTERM EXAM I. March 26, 2015

Macroeconomics - Licence 1 Economie Gestion

9. ISLM model. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations CHAPTER 9. slide 0

macro macroeconomics Aggregate Demand I N. Gregory Mankiw CHAPTER TEN PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich fifth edition

Chapter 11 Aggregate Demand I: Building the IS -LM Model

An Introduction to Basic Macroeconomic Markets

Exam 3 ECON Thurs. Nov. 14, :30 a.m. Form A

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

The Expenditure-Output

AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT. Chapter 20

This is IS-LM, chapter 21 from the book Finance, Banking, and Money (index.html) (v. 2.0).

Chapter 3: National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes. CHAPTER 3 National Income. slide 0

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Practice Test 1: Multiple Choice

Macroeconomics Sixth Edition

ECON 120 -ESSENTIALS OF ECONOMICS

In understanding the behavior of aggregate demand we must take a close look at its individual components: Figure 1, Aggregate Demand

What is Macroeconomics?

Definition 58 POTENTIAL GDP is the economy s long run growth trend for real GDP.

AP Macroeconomics - Mega Macro Review Sheet Answers

Name: Days/Times Class Meets: Today s Date:

9/10/2017. National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes (in the long-run) Introduction. The Neoclassical model

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Openness in goods and financial markets II. Balance of payments. Uncovered interest rate parity. Goods market equilibrium in the open economy.

Transcription:

The Multiplier Model Allin Cottrell March 3, 208 Introduction The basic idea behind the multiplier model is that up to the limit set by full employment or potential GDP the actual level of employment and output depends on the state of aggregate demand ( AD). A shortfall in aggregate demand will push an economy into recession; an increase in AD can pull the economy back up to potential. The multiplier represents the ratio of the overall increment of real GDP to the increment of some independent expenditure variable, for example investment (where the increment can be positive or negative, i.e. a decrement). Where the multiplier is greater than one, the extra change in aggregate expenditure is accounted for by an induced change in consumption. In all cases, the possibility of a positive multiplier effect rests on the assumption that there are unused resources that is, the economy is operating short of full employment. If the economy is already at full employment, any increase in one category of real expenditure must be offset by a reduction in some other category or categories of real expenditure, or in other words the multiplier is necessarily zero. Notation: the symbols used in the following discussion are defined thus: Y AD C I G T X Z aggregate income or output aggregate demand aggregate consumption aggregate investment government purchases net tax revenue total exports total imports All of the above are assumed to be measured in real terms. Planned and actual investment Before proceeding we need to clarify something about investment spending, I. Total investment includes as one component inventory investment, that is, the change in the stocks of goods waiting to be sold (or raw materials waiting to be processed) from one period to the next. One special feature of inventory investment is that it may sometimes be negative (meaning that stocks of unsold goods are falling). Another special feature is that it may be unplanned or unintended. For example, consumer spending falls unexpectedly and firms find that they have amassed a greater quantity of unsold goods, when they had no intention of doing so. We ll use this language: actual investment includes any unintended change in inventories, while planned investment excludes such changes. We ll use the special symbol I p for planned investment. Independent here means, not in any direct way a function of aggregate income.

2 The simplest case We start with the simplest case, where we ignore (or set to zero) both the government sector and international trade. That leaves private-sector consumption and investment as the only categories of real expenditure, and we can write aggregate demand as AD = C + I p () where I p represents planned or intended investment (excluding unintended changes in inventory). The consumption function is C = a + by 0 < b < (2) and the short-run macroeconomic equilibrium condition is AD = Y (3) That is, firms in the aggregate are producing what there s a demand for, neither more nor less. If we substitute (2) into () and use (3) we obtain which can be solved for Y as Y = a + by + I p Y = b (a + I p) (4) the reduced form of our simplest model. (I will give a step-by-step solution for the most complex case, in section 4 below. Presumably if you can follow that, you can fill in the steps for yourself in the simpler cases.) This model incorporates a multiplier of /( b). Numerical example: if the marginal propensity to consume, b, is 0.9 then the multiplier is 0.9 = 0. = 0 and any change in investment will be multiplied tenfold in its effect on equilibrium GDP (within the full-employment limit as mentioned in section ). 3 Introducing the government We now introduce a government which carries out real expenditure G and collects real net tax revenue T. (Net tax revenue is tax revenue minus transfers such as social security and welfare payments; these transfers do not count as part of G since they are not payment for currently produced goods or services.) We will represent net tax revenue as T = ty 0 < t < (5) This says that the government collects as tax some fraction t of the GDP. Government expenditure must be added into aggregate demand, so we replace () with AD = C + I p + G (6) In addition, we must re-think the consumption function. With taxation in the picture, presumably consumption depends on post-tax or disposable income, Y T. So we replace (2) with C = a + b(y T) = a + b(y ty) = a + b( t)y (7) 2

Using equation (7) in (6), we get and setting AD = Y gives So and solving for Y gives AD = a + b( t)y + I p + G Y = a + b( t)y + I p + G [ b( t)]y = a + I p + G Y = which is the reduced form of our second model. b( t) (a + I p + G) (8) Numerical example: If b = 0.9 and t = 0.3 (a uniform 30 percent rate of income tax), we get b( t) = 0.9( 0.3) = 0.9(0.7) = 0.63 = 0.37 2.703 With the same marginal propensity to consume as in the earlier example, the positive tax rate produces a substantial reduction in the size of the multiplier effect. If fluctuations in investment are a significant source of instability in the GDP (as seems to be the case), the smaller multiplier is desirable. The overall fluctuations in GDP will be less than they would be if the tax rate were zero. The tax rate, t, is a government policy variable, and it will influence the equilibrium GDP via its influence on the size of the multiplier. For instance, a cut in t will increase the size of the multiplier, and will therefore raise equilibrium GDP so long as I p and G remain unchanged (and so long as we re not already at full employment). 4 Foreign trade Our last multiplier model brings back the other important factor initially banished from discussion for the sake of simplicity, namely foreign trade. The full, final form of the aggregate demand equation is AD = C + I p + G + (X Z) (9) where X denotes exports and Z denotes imports, so (X Z) is net exports. The rationale for this is that foreigners purchases of our exports constitute an additional source of demand for our goods, while the import component of consumption and investment must be subtracted if we re trying to measure expenditure on domestically produced goods and services. How should we treat X and Z in the context of our macro model, given that we re trying to strike a balance between simplicity and realism? We ll take exports to be an independent variable, on the grounds that they depend primarily on the level of demand in other countries. Imports, on the other hand, depend in an important way on the level of income and expenditure in the home economy: if we re spending more overall, we re likely to be spending more on imports too. The simplest way to capture this is to make imports proportional to GDP: Using (0) in (9) we get Z = zy 0 < z < (0) AD = C + I p + G + X zy () From this point we proceed as before. First set the right-hand side of () equal to Y, as per equation (3). Y = C + I p + G + X zy 3

Then, using the consumption equation (7), we get Y = a + b( t)y + I p + G + X zy Y b( t)y + zy = a + I p + G + X [ b( t) + z] Y = a + I p + G + X So, finally, the reduced form is Y = b( t) + z (a + I p + G + X) (2) Numerical example: With b = 0.9 and t = 0.3, as in the previous example, now let z = 0.4. That is, suppose 4 percent of expenditure goes on imports. In that case the multiplier is b( t) + z = 0.9(.3) + 0.4 =.4 0.63 = 0.5.96 which is a roughly realistic value for the US economy. This multiplier is smaller again than the one after we first introduced the positive tax rate. Well, actually, the global multiplier is not any smaller, but from any one country s point of view the multiplier effect is reduced, in the sense that part of it leaks abroad, stimulating production in other countries (by augmenting their exports, which are our imports). 5 Some implications The multiplier model, particularly in its most developed form, offers many insights into the working of the macroeconomy, some of them at variance with opinions frequently expressed by financial journalists and politicians (who should know better!). Here is a sampling. Note that you should not think of the following as independent points to memorize : they follow directly from a correct understanding of the models set out above (plus a little general knowledge). The government budget balance, G T, depends not only on fiscal policy (that is, the setting of government spending, G, and the tax rate, t) but also on the level of income. Other things equal, a rise in GDP will, by raising net tax revenue (T = ty), reduce the budget deficit or augment the budget surplus, while a fall in GDP will reduce the budget surplus or augment the budget deficit. If an increase in the budget deficit is brought on by recession, and the government reacts by cutting government spending or raising taxation (in an effort to eliminate the deficit), the effect will be a worsening of the recession. This sort of policy worsened and prolonged the Great Depression of the 930s, and there is a danger that it will do so again today. The level of net exports depends jointly on (a) the level of exports, X, (b) the propensity to import, z, and the level of home-country GDP. Given X and z, a rise in GDP will reduce net exports by raising Z = zy, hence worsening the trade balance (moving it towards deficit). A fall in GDP will improve the trade balance (raise net exports, by reducing imports). Therefore the trade balance should not be taken as a straightforward indicator of the health of an economy. An impressive trade surplus may be the result of a depressed home economy. A stronger currency (rise in value of the domestic currency in relation to other countries currencies) will tend to restrict exports (by making them more expensive in foreign currencies) and promote imports (by making them cheaper in the domestic currency). But a fall in X will tend to depress GDP, while a rise in z will reduce the value of the multiplier, again depressing GDP. Therefore, although people often talk as if a strong currency were always a desirable sign of economic health, there is such a thing as a too strong currency. 4

Individual countries can boost their GDPs by carrying out policies that promote exports and restrict the propensity to import (e.g. tariffs, import quotas, export subsidies). But the sum of net exports at the world level has to be zero (think about it). So one country s gain in this game is another s loss. If a government wants to stimulate home-country GDP, because it currently falls short of the full-employment level, they are better off increasing their own spending, or cutting taxes, or trying to find ways to boost private-sector investment spending (e.g. lower interest rates, assuming that interest rates have not already bottomed out). 5