Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Similar documents
TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Macro theory: A quick review

Economics 502. Nominal Rigidities. Geoffrey Dunbar. UBC, Fall November 22, 2012

The Real Business Cycle Model

1.3 Nominal rigidities

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Chapter 13 Short Run Aggregate Supply Curve

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Introduction The Story of Macroeconomics. September 2011

Mankiw Chapter 14 Aggregate Supply and the Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment CHAPTER 14

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

Macroeconomics II. Explaining AS - Sticky Wage Model, Lucas Model, Sticky Price Model, Phillips Curve

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Monetary Economics Final Exam

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

EC3115 Monetary Economics

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, November 2016 Quiz, Unit VI, Stabilization Policies

Exam #2 Review Questions (Answers) ECNS 303 October 31, 2011

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

Macroeconomics II. Lecture 07: AS, Inflation, and Unemployment. IES FSS (Summer 2017/2018)

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

EC 205 Macroeconomics I. Lecture 19

Homework 4 of ETP Economics

Part I (45 points; Mark your answers in a SCANTRON)

DEMAND FOR MONEY. Ch. 9 (Ch.19 in the text) ECON248: Money and Banking Ch.9 Dr. Mohammed Alwosabi

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

1 Figure 1 (A) shows what the IS LM model looks like for the case in which the Fed holds the

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

The science of monetary policy

Analysis of Business Cycles II : The Supply Side of the Economy

Aggregate Supply. Reading. On real wages, also see Basu and Taylor (1999), Journal of Economic. Mankiw, Macroeconomics: Chapters 9.4 and 13.1 and.

Inflation and Unemployment

Aggregate Supply. Dudley Cooke. Trinity College Dublin. Dudley Cooke (Trinity College Dublin) Aggregate Supply 1 / 38

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

6. Deficits and inflation: seignorage as a source of public sector revenue

ECONOMIC GROWTH 1. THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL

Macroeconomics. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Zoltán Bartha, PhD Associate Professor. Andrea S. Gubik, PhD Associate Professor

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory / Macroeconomic Analysis (ECON 3560/5040) Midterm Exam (Answers)

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Fall 2006 Solutions to Problem Set 4 (35 points)

Disputes Over Macro Theory and Policy

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 4 Crowder Fall 2016

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

Money in an RBC framework

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Test Review. Question 1. Answer 1. Question 2. Answer 2. Question 3. Econ 719 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7,9. Nominal GDP.

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Winter 2009 Solutions to Problem Set 2.

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

Aggregate demand. Short run aggregate demand (AD) function: Monetary rule followed by the government: Short run aggregate supply (AS) function:

The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment. Chapter 33

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

The New Keynesian Model

31E00700 Labor Economics: Lecture 3

A dynamic model with nominal rigidities.

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility

Lecture 22. Aggregate demand and aggregate supply

PROBLEM SET 6 New Keynesian Economics

Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem

Economics II/Intermediate Macroeconomics (No. 5025) Prof. Dr. Gerhard Schwödiauer/ Prof. Dr. Joachim Weimann. Semester: Summer Semester 2003

Real Business Cycle Model

Models of the Neoclassical synthesis

Chapter 12: Unemployment and Inflation

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Monetary Economics. Money in Utility. Seyed Ali Madanizadeh. February Sharif University of Technology

1 No capital mobility

AP Macroeconomics Formulas and Definitions: Key Formulas

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Spring 2016

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

ECON 3020: ACCELERATED MACROECONOMICS

On the new Keynesian model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

Inflation & Welfare 1

Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom? Martin Uribe and Vivian Yue (JIE, 2006)

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Transcription:

Chapter 6 Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment In Romer s IS/MP/IA model, we assume prices/inflation adjust imperfectly when output changes. Empirically, there is a negative relationship between unemployment and output in the short-run, according to an expectations-augmented Phillips Curve. Friedman (968) and Phelps (968). This implies a positive relationship between inflation and output. This chapter focuses on theories of why prices adjust imperfectly. Rather than simply assuming that wages/prices fail to adjust, these theories demonstrate why there is a positive relationship between prices and output in the short run, resulting from optimizing decisions by rational households and firms. These theories serve as the foundation of modern analysis of economic fluctuations. Without a positive relationship between inflation and output in the short run, there is no role for monetary policy to affect real economic variables. In the IS/MP/IA model, this would mean assuming π 0 Y. We can see from the model that a vertical IA curve implies that shifts in IS/MP have no effect on output. Also, we can see that changes in fiscal policy can affect the composition of output (through affecting the real interest rate), but cannot affect the level of output. This is consistent with the classical dichotomy: changes in nominal variables (money supply, nominal interest rates, inflation) do not affect real variables (output, unemployment, real interest rates). We can see this in the case studies below where the economy is initially at potential output, Y = Ȳ. Assume that prices/inflation adjust perfectly to deviations in output from potential output, so that the IA curve is vertical. Now, consider a situation where the Federal Reserve tries to expand output by lowering interest rates. We see from the diagram below that money has no effect on real economic variables (real interest rate and output return to their initial values). This is known as money neutrality. 56

57

Now, consider the same scenario, except that the government attempts to boost output through a tax cut. We see from the diagram that this has no effect on output, but it does lead to an increase in the real interest rate. The tax cut therefore leads to an increase in consumption (because disposable income has increased) and a decrease in investment. From the cases above, we can see that if there is some imperfection in price adjustment, there is a role for policy to affect real economic variables. Generally, if such a perfection does exist, then changes in aggregate demand affect output. The focus in this literature tends to be on monetary policy. There are several reasons for this. The most obvious one being that we know fiscal policy has 58

the ability to affect real economic variables through affecting the composition of output. Also, when we consider using policy in response to economic outcomes, monetary policy has the ability to respond quickly to economic conditions (relative to fiscal policy) because of institutional limitations (e.g., the federal budget process). Another reason why these theories of incomplete price adjustment are important relates to the timing between short run and long run. The time between short run (when output can deviate from potential) and long run (when prices adjust and the economy returns to potential output/natural rate of unemployment) depends on your assumptions about the nature of incomplete price adjustment. Part A The Lucas Imperfect-Information Model This model relaxes the assumption of perfect information in the classical model. Perfectly competitive firms observe the prices of their individual products, but they do not observe the economy-wide price level. Therefore, when the producer observes a change in the price of her product, she does not know if this is a reflection of increased demand for her individual good, or simply a general increase in the economy-wide price level (associated with changes in aggregate demand). She must forecast the expected economy-wide price level and determine whether or not to change her individual production levels when she observes a change in her individual price. The model presented in this chapter is based mainly on Lucas (972) and less so on Lucas (973, 976). 6. The Case of Perfect Information To understand how the Lucas model works, we will begin with developing a classical model with utility maximizing households who supply labor to profitmaximizing firms. All economic agents observe information perfectly, so that producers are able to distinguish between fluctuations in prices associated with individual demand versus aggregate demand. To simplify things, we focus on the behavior of a representative producer. 6.. Producer Behavior (and Household Behavior) A perfectly competitive firm producers output Q i using labor supplied by the household, L i : Q i = L i In the model, the "owner" of the firm is also the worker. That is, each household producers its own product by hiring itself. 59

The firm s profit maximization problem is: Π = P i Q i W i L i where P i is the price of the individual good produced by the aforementioned firm. and Q i = L i because of the linear production function: Π = P i L i W i L i The FOC for this problem is: Π =0:W i = P i L i Therefore, W i L i = P i Q i. That is, each household earns P i Q i in nominal wages. The worker receives real income equal to P iq i P. The aggregate price level is denoted P this represents the price of a market basket of goods produced in the economy. Therefore, we deflate the worker s wages by P to adjust for the purchasing power of wages earned. Utility depends positively on consumption and negatively on labor (e.g., positively on leisure). We assume the following utility function: U i = C i γ Lγ i where C i is (real) consumption purchased by the household. From this expression, we can see that as the household works more, she enjoys less leisure time, reducing her utility. The household maximizes utility subject to the budget constraint (note that Q i = L i from the production function above): subject to C i P il i P This problem can be set up as a Lagrangian: L = C i γ Lγ i + λ µ Pi L i P max C i γ Lγ i C i The first order conditions are: L C i = 0 : λ =0 L = 0 : L γ i + λ P i L i P Combining these conditions we have: L γ i = P i P L i = 60 µ Pi P γ

In log notation (with lower case letters indicating logs): log(l i ) = i = (γ ) (log(p i) log(p )) (γ ) (p i p) We can see from this expression that the supply of labor from the household is a positive function of the relative price of his/her product. If the firm/household sees the price of his/her individual product is higher than the economy-wide price level, then it should increase production. It does so by increasing labor hours. 6..2 Demand The demand for an individual good (in log form) q i is expressed as: q i = y + z i η (p i p) where y denotes the log of aggregate real income, z i is an idiosyncratic shock to the demand for good i, and η is the elasticity of demand for each good. 2 We can see from this expression that if the price of this good is relatively low, p i <p, then the demand for good i will exceed the average, q i >y. If all goods are identical, then we can express aggregate real income y and aggregate prices p as: Aggregate demand is specified as: y = q i p = p i y = m p where m denotes the log of money supply. However, it is easier to interpret this as any shock to aggregate demand. This expression is consistent with the quantity theory of money. 3 6..3 Equilibrium Note, the demand for good i is given above: q i = y + z i η (p i p) 2 We assume z i (0,σ 2 z ). 3 The quantity theory of money uses the equation of exchange MV = PY. In logs, this expression is m + v = p + y, or y = m p + v. Since the quantity theory of money assumes that velocity is constant, it is dropped from the expression (it will not be a source of variation in aggregate demand). 6

The quantity supplied is given by the production side of the economy. We know that q i = i from the production function: q i = i = (γ ) (p i p) The quantity of good i demanded must equal the quantity supplied: y + z i η (p i p) = (γ ) (p i p) Solving for p i : p i = γ +ηγ η (y + z i)+p We can use this expression to find q i for the individual producer. We can see that on the production side of the economy, it is the relative price of individual good i that matters for production. 6.2 New Classical Approach: The Case of Imperfect Information Now, we assume that the producers are unable to observe the expression above - they only see p i and are unable to distinguish between possible sources of a shock to their individual prices. 6.2. Producer Behavior Here, when the firm chooses how much to produce, she has to forecast the relative price of her product, conditional on the information she observes (which is the individual price of her product): q i = i = (γ ) E [(p i p) p i ] Lucas assumes that the household has rational expectations. This means that rather than basing her forecast of (p i p) on past values, she fully incorporates all available information (in this problem, this information is contained in p i ) into her forecast. To determine how much the firm will produce, we need to find E [(p i p) p i ]. This value depends on the underlying distributions of p and p i. The firm observes p i,e(p i p i )=p i : q i = (γ ) p i (γ ) E (p p i) To see the implications of this model for the economy, see the Lucas Imperfect Information model supplement. In the end, we arrive at the following production choice for the individual producer (in the notation used by Romer): q i = αβ(p i p) 62

where α = γ and β = σ2 z σ 2 p + σ 2 z The parameter β measures how much the producer responds to a change in her price. It is known as a signal-to-noise ratio. Notice that when the aggregate price level is unstable (σ 2 P is large), β is small. That is, the producers are less responsive to changes in their individual prices because of the noise created by unstable aggregate prices. When σ 2 zis large, β is large, so that most variation in the individual price is associated with idiosyncratic demand shocks. In aggregate, production is: y = αβ (p E(p)) where p = E(p) on average (e.g., in the long run), so that y =0in the long run. Notice, this can easily be modified to allow for some positive potential output, ȳ : y =ȳ + αβ (p E(p)) 6.2.2 Equilibrium Taking the expression for output and combining this with the aggregate demand equation: p = +αβ m + αβ +αβ E(p) y = αβ +αβ m αβ +αβ E(p) We can combine these expressions to show that E(p) =E(m). Substituting this into the expressions above: p = E(m)+ [m E(m)] +αβ y = αβ [m E(m)] +αβ From these expressions, we see the key implications from the model. Only unanticipated changes in money supply (or unanticipated shocks to AD in general), affect real output. Anticipated changes in money only affect the price level. 6.3 New Classical Approach: Implications and Limitations This section applies the model to the data to consider its implications for policy and potential limitations. 63

6.3. The Phillips Curve and the Lucas Critique In the Lucas model, shocks to aggregate demand affect real output only when these shocks are unanticipated. To understand the time series implications of the model, we need to assume a distribution for the money supply. Romer suggests assuming that money supply follows a random walk with a drift: m t = δ + m t + u t where u t iid (0,σ 2 u). Taking the expectations of this expression (at time t) allows us to find E(m) : E(m t ) = E [δ + m t + u t ] = E (δ)+e(m t )+E(u t ) = δ + m t so that m E(m) =u. Plugging this into the expressions for prices and output abovewehave: p t = δ + m t + y t = αβ +αβ u t +αβ [u t] This highlights the key implication pointed out above. Shocks to aggregate demand affect real output only when they are unexpected. Notice that inflation π t = p t p t (because the variables are defined in logs). Therefore, inflation is: π t = ½ ¾ δ + m t + +αβ [u t] δ + m t 2 + +αβ [u t ] π t = m t m t 2 + +αβ (u t u t ) π t = δ + +αβ (u t u t ) When there is a positive shock to m t, that is, u t > 0,y t and π t increase according to the expressions above. Therefore, there is a positive relationship between inflation and output in the short run. If there were an anticipated shock to money, then the price level would increase proportionately, leaving real output unaffected. In the context of the model, if the producers know that aggregate demand has increased, then they will not increase individual production. They won t be tricked into increasing production because they will know that the increase in their individual prices are a reflection of economy-wide inflation. 64

6.3.2 Stabilization Policy Another important implication from the Lucas imperfect information model is that systematic changes in policy will not affect output. If the Federal Reserve or federal government respond to recessions in the same way, households and producers learn from this, and adjust their inflation forecasts accordingly. For example, if the Federal Reserve announces that it wants to lower the inflation rate, if this is credible, then households and producers will lower their inflation expectations, allowing for a painless disinflation. However, if the Fed tries this repeatedly, then agents learn that the announcements are not credible, reducing the effectiveness of policy to reduce inflation. The general implication from the model is as follows: if the policy is a surprise, it is more likely to affect real economic variables. 6.3.3 International Evidence on Output-Inflation Tradeoffs Lucas (973) examines the relationship between the variance in prices and variance of output. Empirically, he identifies the effect of an aggregate demand shock on real output using a two step process. First, he estimates the relationship between real output, y t, and the change in the log of nominal output, x t (plus some control variables): y t = γ + δt + τ x t + ρy t He runs this time series regression for several countries. Then, taking the estimates τ i for each country, he runs the following cross section regression: τ i = α + βσ x,i where σ x,i is the standard deviation of the change in the log of nominal GDP for country i. According to the Lucas imperfect information model, β<0. This would mean that aggregate demand shocks have a relatively smaller effect on real output in countries where nominal GDP is less stable. The idea is that in these countries, the individual producers would be less responsive to changes in individual prices because of the noise created by unstable nominal variables. This is related to the discussion of stabilization policy above. The more policymakers attempt to stabilize real output, the more volatile are nominal variables, and the less effective their policies become. This has lead toward a general consensus, even among new Keynesians, that stabilization policy should NOT be used to fine tune a perceived recession. Stabilization policy should be used sparingly in response to large negative shocks to the economy. 6.3.4 Difficulties There are two major weaknesses in the model. This model is actually a precursor to the RBC model we ve already studied. The fluctuations in output come 65

entirely from changes in labor supply and production. Like the RBC model, in order to generate fluctuations in (the cyclical component of) output that are consistent with the data, we need to assume a high degree of labor supply elasticity. In order to generate large fluctuations in output, we need households to be very responsive to changes in wages. The second problem is that it is difficult to believe that business cycles can be attributed to imperfect information. Producers can learn of changes in aggregate prices relatively quickly and adjust their output accordingly. This appears to be at odds with the generate the large and persistent changes in output observed in the data. 66