Suggested Solutions to Homework #5 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Similar documents
Consumption and Asset Pricing

Slides III - Complete Markets

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Problem set Fall 2012.

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Cash-in-Advance Model

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Solutions for Homework #5

Lecture 5: to Consumption & Asset Choice

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

1 Dynamic programming

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Macroeconomics and finance

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

1 Mar Review. Consumer s problem is. V (z, K, a; G, q z ) = max. subject to. c+ X q z. w(z, K) = zf 2 (K, H(K)) (4) K 0 = G(z, K) (5)

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Real Business Cycles (Solution)

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

Feb. 20th, Recursive, Stochastic Growth Model

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

Assets with possibly negative dividends

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 7

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

A simple wealth model

Money in an RBC framework

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

ECON Micro Foundations

The Neoclassical Growth Model

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

One-Period Valuation Theory

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Value Function Iteration

An Entrepreneur s Problem Under Perfect Foresight

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

ECON 815. Uncertainty and Asset Prices

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

PhD Qualifier Examination

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II

Period State of the world: n/a A B n/a A B Endowment ( income, output ) Y 0 Y1 A Y1 B Y0 Y1 A Y1. p A 1+r. 1 0 p B.

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Growth model with Epstein-Zin preferences and stochastic volatility

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Transcription:

Suggested Solutions to Homework #5 Econ 5b (Part I), Spring 004. Consider the planning problem for a neoclassical growth model with logarithmic utility, full depreciation of the capital stock in one period, and aproductionfunctionoftheformy = zk α,wherez is a random shock to productivity. The shock z is observed before making the current-period savings decision. Assume that the capital stock can take on only two values: i.e., k is restricted to the set k, k ª. In addition, assume that z takes on values in the set {z, z } and that z follows a Markov chain with transition probabilities p ij = P z 0 = z j z = z i. (a) Let z =0.9, z =.,p =0.95,p =0.9. Find the invariant distribution associated with the Markov chain for z. Use the invariant distribution to compute the long-run (or unconditional) expected value of z. Given the transition matrix P = µ 0.95 0.05 0. 0.9 we can calculate the stationary distribution π according to the formula π 0 = π 0 ½ P π =0.95π +0.π π =0.05π +0.9π The solution to this equation is π =π Imposing the condition that π + π =, the solution is ½ π = 3 π = 3 Correspondingly, the long run expected value is E π z = π 0 z = 3 0.9+ 3. =9 30 (b) Let β= 0.9, α= 0.36, k =0.95k ss, and k =.05k ss,wherek ss is the steadystate capital stock in a version of this model without shocks and with no restrictions on capital (i.e., k ss =(αβ) α. Using Matlab (if you need to), find the optimal decision rule for capital, i.e., a function mapping pairs of the form (k, z) into the optimal choice for capital. Form the dynamic programming problem as v (k i,z i )= max ln ³z 0 ³ i k αi k + β p i v ³k 0,z + p i v ³k 0,z k 0 {k,k }

Since (k i,z i ) can take on only four values, we can solve for value function v (k i,z i ) and policy function g (k i,z i ) as 4 vectors. For example, we can solve that using value function iteration on the computer. Using Matlab, we can get the policy function as g(k,z ) = k g(k,z ) = k g(k,z ) = k g(k,z ) = k This is our policy function. (c) The decision rule from part (b) and the law of motion for z jointly determine an invariant distribution over (k, z)-pairs. Find this distribution. Use your answer to compute the long-run (or unconditional) expected values of the capital stock and of output. Based on policy function g (k i,z i ) and transition matrix of z, the pair (k, z) follows a Markov process with the transition matrix (z,k ) (z,k ) (z,k ) (z,k ) (z,k ) 0.95 0 0.05 0 (z,k ) 0.95 0 0.05 0 (z,k ) 0 0. 0 0.9 (z,k ) 0 0. 0 0.9 Now we can calculate the stationary distribution either on the computer or by hand. The result is p(k,z ) = 9 30 =0.63333 p(k,z ) = 30 =0.033333 p(k,z ) = 30 =0.033333 p(k,z ) = 3 0 =0.3 Using the stationary distribution, the long-run (or unconditional) expected values of the capital stock and of output are Ek = 3 k + 3 k =0.747 Ey = 3 kα + 3 kα =0.549 (d) In Matlab, use the optimal decision rule, the law of motion for z, anda random number generator to create a simulated time series {k t,y t } T t=0, givenaninitialcondition(k 0,z 0 ). Compute T P T t= k t and T P T t= y t for a suitably large value of T and confirm that these sample means

are close to the corresponding population means that you computed in part (c). Depending on the realization of each simulation, the result will differ a little bit. For example, one possible result based on T = 0000 is T T TX k t = 0.747 t= TX y t = 0.4687 t=. Consider a two-period exchange economy with two (types of) consumers labelled A and B. The two types of consumers have identical preferences given by u (c 0 )+βeu(c ), where u is strictly increasing and strictly concave. Each consumer is endowed with one consumption good in period 0. In period, each type A consumer is endowed with θy consumption goods and each type B consumer is endowed with ( θ) y consumption goods. The random variable θ can be interpreted as the consumer s share of the aggregate endowment y. Let θ equal / + z with probability p and equal / z with probability p, where0 < z < /. The aggregate endowment y is also random: it equals +x with probability one-half and equals x with probability one-half. The random variables y and θ are statistically independent. (a) Assume that markets are complete: in period 0, consumers can trade a full set of Arrow securities. Express the competitive equilibrium allocations and prices in terms of primitivesasexplicitlyasyoucan. You might want to start with the case where p = / (so that the consumers are identical in all respects) and then consider the more general case p 6= /. First, let s define states in this economy. From the specification of the problem, there are four states indexed by the pair (θ, y). The probability of each state is π = prob µθ = + z,y =+x = p π = prob µθ = + z,y = x = p π 3 = prob µθ = z,y =+x = ( p) π 4 = prob µθ = z,y = x = ( p) Now we begin by defining a competitive equilibrium. A competitive equilibrium with n complete markets o is a pair of consumption, asset holdings, and asset price 4 {c i 0,c i s,a i s} i=a,b,q s such that 3

(a) Consumers solve the problem max u c i {c i s} 4 0 + β u c i s s=0 s.t c i 0 + q s a i s = c i s = a i s + ω i s where ω A s = θ s y s and ω B s =( θ s ) y s. (b)productmarketclearing:c A 0 + c B 0 =, c A s + c B s = y s for s =,...4. (c) Asset market clearing: a A s + a B s =0for s =,..., 4. We know that the consumer s choice is determined by F.O.C. and budget constraint, i.e. βu 0 (c i q s = π s) s u 0 (c i 0) c i 0 + q s a i s = c i s = a i s + ω i s Now we start to find the system of equations for equilibrium. Because of Walras s law, we have five redundant equations: we take consumer B s five BC out of our system of equations. Therefore, the necessary and sufficient conditions for the equilibrium are βu 0 (c i q s = π s) s u 0 (c i 0) c A 0 + q s a A s = c A s = a A s + ω A s c A 0 + c B 0 = c A s + c B s = y s a A s + a B s =0 n o 4 which is a system of equations and unknowns {c i 0,c i s,a i s} i=a,b,q s The. existence of solution is guaranteed by the standard existence result for Walrasian equilibrium. This system implicitly defines our equilibrium. For the case p =, we can solve for the equilibrium explicitly. Due to the 4

symmetry when p =, we can guess the solution as c A 0 = c B 0 c A = c A 3 = c B = c B 3 c A = c A 4 = c B = c B 4 q = q 3 q = q 4 Plug into equilibrium equations, we have and c A 0 = c B 0 = c A = c A 3 = c B = c B 3 = ( + x) c A = c A 4 = c B = c B 4 = ( x) βu 0 (c i q = q 3 = π ) u 0 (c i 0) = βu 0 ( + x) 4 u 0 () βu 0 (c i q = q 4 = π ) u 0 (c i 0) = βu 0 ( x) 4 u 0 () a A = c A ω A = ( + x) µ + z ( + x) = z ( + x) a A = c A ω A = ( x) µ + z ( x) = z ( x) a A 3 = c A 3 ω A 3 = ( + x) µ z ( + x) =z ( + x) a A 4 = c A 4 ω A 4 = ( x) µ z ( x) =z ( x) a B = a A = z ( + x) a B = a A = z ( x) a B 3 = a A 3 = z ( + x) a B 4 = a A 4 = z ( x) For the case p 6=,wecannotfind explicit analytical solution. But we can reduce theequationalittlebit. Theintuitiontellsusthatcompletemarketcaninsure against idiosyncratic risk. Therefore, we conjecture the following fact: c A = c A 3,c A = c A 4 c B = c B 3,c B = c B 4 5

Plug this into equilibrium equation and substitute out q 3,q 4 and a i s, it becomes βu 0 (c i q = π ) u 0 (c i 0) βu 0 (c i q = π ) u 0 (c i 0) µ c A 0 + q + π µ 3 q c A + q + π 4 q c A =+ q s ω A s π π c A 0 + c B 0 = c A + c B =+x c A + c B = x The reduced system contains 8 equations and 8 unknowns n{c i0,c i,c i} o i=a,b,q,q. This system implicitly defines our equilibrium. We cannot go further beyond that. A little digression (only for nerds!!! Don t spend time on that if you cannot understand it.). The argument above only goes very loosely. To be rigorous, we have not verified our guess yet. In the above system of 8 equations and 8 unknowns, we have not proved that there is no contradiction for our guess, i.e. we have not shown the existence of solution for that 8-equation system. Now I give a rough sketch of the existence proof about c i = c i 3,c i = c i 4. From First Welfare Theorem complete market equilibrium is Pareto optimal. Therefore, it maximizes a social welfare function by the concavity of utility function and Kuhn-Tucker Theorem. In addition, the price q s is Lagrangian multiplier associated with the resource constraint. From envelope theorem, q s is indeed the marginal utility of representative agent evaluated at aggregate endowment. Therefore, we know that q s = f(w s ) for s =0,,.., 4 (hereweusetheassumptionof additive separable utility). From the F.O.C. of individuals q s u 0 (c i 0)=π s βu 0 (c i s), we know that c i s = g i (ω s ) (here g depends on i because the marginal utility of i or u 0 (c i 0) depends on i, indeed it is the inverse of the weight we give to social welfare function), which finishes the proof. (b) Use the prices of the Arrow securities from part (a) to find the equilibrium period-0 price of a risk-free bond (i.e., an asset that pays one unit of the consumption in all states of the world in period ). If you are unable to solve for the Arrow prices explicitly, then show how you would use these prices to compute the price of a risk-free bond. Due to non-arbitrage property, the price of risk-free asset must be q rf = q s For the case p =,wehave q rf = q s = β u 0 ( + x) + u 0 ( x) u 0 () 6

(c) Now suppose that markets are incomplete: in period 0, the only asset that consumers are allowed to trade is a risk-free bond. The net supply of bonds is zero (since the economy is closed). Find the competitive equilibrium allocations and the equilibrium price of the bond as explicitly as you can. Compare your answers to those in parts (a) and (b). Show that eliminating complete markets makes consumers worse off. Does eliminating complete markets increase or decrease the risk-free rate of return (i.e., the inverse of the bond price)? Why? (Again, you might want to start with the case p= / before considering the case p 6= /.) Now we begin by defining a competitive equilibrium with a risk-free asset. A competitive equilibrium with n incomplete markets o is a pair of consumption, asset 4 holdings, and asset price {c i 0,c i s,a i } i=a,b,q rf such that (a) Consumers solve the problem max u c i {c i s} 4 0 + β π s u c i s s=0 s.t c i 0 + q rf a i = c i s = a i + ω i s where ω A s = θ s y s and ω B s =( θ s ) y s. (b)productmarketclearing:c A 0 + c B 0 =, c A s + c B s = y s for s =,...4. (c) Asset market clearing: a A + a B =0. We know that the consumer s choice is determined by F.O.C. and budget constraint, i.e. q rf = βu 0 (c i π s) s u 0 (c i 0) c i 0 + q rf a i = c i s = a i + ω i s Now we start to find the system of equations for equilibrium. Because of Walras law, we have fiveredundantequations: wetakeconsumerb sbcoutofour system of equations. Therefore, the necessary and sufficient conditions for the 7

equilibrium are q rf = βu 0 (c i π s) s u 0 (c i 0) c A 0 + q rf a A = c A s = a A + ω A s c A 0 + c B 0 = c A s + c B s = y s a A + a B =0 which is a system of 3 equations with 3 unknowns n {c i 0,c i s,a i } i=a,b,q rf o 4. This system implicitly defines our equilibrium. Now we start to discuss the difference of allocation from complete market case. The first fact is that with only one risk-free asset, consumers cannot insure again the idiosyncratic risk. This can been seen from the third line of our equilibrium system. From c A s = a A + ω A s, if there is a change in ω A s across the state (which is thecasehere),wemusthavec A 6= c A 6= c A 3 6= c A 4. To say more about this issue, we start from the simple case with p =. If p =,duetothesymmetryoftheconsumersweconjecturethesolutionas c A = c B 3 c A = c B 4 c A 3 = c B c A 4 = c B Combinethisfactwithc A s = a A +ω A s and a A = a B,wehavethefurtherconjecture a A = a B =0 c i s = ω i s Plug this into equilibrium conditions, it satisfies every equation, which verifies our conjecture. (You may wonder why this conjecture cannot hold for p 6=.The reason is that the same conjecture holds for every equation except the first two equations in the equilibrium system: with p 6=,thefirst two equations (F.O.C. for A and B) contradict each other.) We can analyze the equilibrium utility and asset price as follows. Since u () + β π s u ω i s < u() + β µ µ (π + π 3 )u ( + x) +(π + π 4 )u ( x) due to the concavity of utility function, we know that both consumers become worse off under incomplete markets. As for the price for risk-free asset of incomplete market q rf incomplete = 8 π s βu 0 (ω i s) u 0 ()

compared to the case of complete market q rf complete = β µ µ (π u 0 + π 3 )u 0 () ( + x) +(π + π 4 )u 0 ( x) We can not determine relative magnitude unless we are willing to make an assumption about marginal utility. If u 000 > 0, q rf incomplete >qrf complete < 0, we ;ifu000 have q rf incomplete <qrf complete. The economic explanation is that if u000 > 0, thereis precautionary saving motive in incomplete market, which leads to higher demand for saving and hence higher asset price. For the case of p 6=, without specification of utility function, it is too complex to give a definite answer. Now I only give a verbal explanation. For the welfare, the general result is that the transition from incomplete market to complete market could be Pareto-improving or Non-Pareto improving. We can speak two facts. First, there is possibility that it is Non-Pareto improving. Theintuitionisthatthechangefromincompletemarkettocompletemarketwill have a general equilibrium effect: the change in the price of existing assets. The change in asset price will bring wealth redistribution between debtors and creditors. Therefore, there is a tradeoff between two effects: the effects of insurance from complete markets and the redistribution effects from the asset price change. If the change in the price of existing asset is dramatic, the redistribution effect will dominate the insurance effect, in this case the transition from incomplete market to complete market won t be pareto-improving. Second, the transition from incomplete market to complete market won t make everybody worseoff, aslongasthereisonlyonegood. Thelogicgoesasfollows. The insurance effect increase utility, while the sign of redistribution effects must be opposite. Therefore, in the world of our problem at least one agent will become better off from completing the market. For the effect on interest rate, it is uncertain. This effect can be seen even in the case of p =. It depends on the sum of marginal rate of substitution between future and date-0. Therefore, the change in p may change the result. We cannot say more about this. (d) Introduce a second asset into the economy you studied in part (c). Specifically, in addition to the endowments described above (which can be viewed as labor income ), let each consumer be endowed with one Lucas tree in period 0. Each tree yields a dividend of d consumptiongoodsinperiod,whered equals d H if y equals +x and equals d L <d H if y equals x. Trees, as well as risk-free bonds, can be boughtandsoldincompetitivemarketsinperiod0. Withoutdoing any explicit calculations, show how you would go about solving for the equilibriumpricesofthetwoassetsinthiseconomy. We begin by defining a competitive equilibrium with two assets. A incomplete market competitive equilibrium with risk-free n asset and Lucas tree is a pair of c i consumption, asset holdings, and asset price 0,c i s,a i rf,ai ªi=A,B, ª o q rf 4,q such that 9

(a) Consumers solve the problem max u c i {c i s} 4 0 + β π s u c i s s=0 s.t c i 0 + q rf a i rf + q a i = c i s = a i + ω i s + d s a i where ω A s = θ s y s, ω B s =( θ s ) y s,d = d 3 = d H, d = d 4 = d L. (b)productmarketclearing:c A 0 + c B 0 =, c A s + c B s = y s +d s for s =,...4. (c) Asset market clearing: a A rf + ab rf =0, aa + a B =. It is easy to see that the equilibrium is determined in the same way as in part (c). The necessary and sufficient conditions for the equilibrium are q rf = q = βu 0 (c i π s) s u 0 (c i 0) βu 0 (c i π s) s u 0 (c i 0) d s c A 0 + q rf a A rf + q a A = c A s = a A + ω A s + d s a A c A 0 + c B 0 = c A s + c B s = y s +d s a A rf + a B rf =0 a A + a B = n c i which is a system of 6 equations with 6 unknowns 0,c i s,a i rf,ai ªi=A,B, ª o q rf 4,q This system implicitly defines our equilibrium. (e) Determine (as completely as you can) the prices of a risk-free bond and of a Lucas tree under the assumption that consumers can trade a full set of Arrow securities in the economy that you studied in part (d). Compare (if possible) these prices to the corresponding prices in part (d). If we can trade a full set of Arrow security, again we go back to the complete market economy in part (a). The only difference is that the product market clearing condition in period changes to the equation c A s + c B s = y s +d s. Since with complete Arrow security, the risk-free asset and Lucas tree become redundant, we can start by finding equilibrium in an economy with only Arrow securities. Then we can price those two assets with Arrow security. Follow the same steps as in part (a) and use the same notation, we get the system. 0

of equilibrium equations as βu 0 (c i q s = π s) s u 0 (c i 0) c A 0 + q s a A s = c A s = a A s + ω A s c A 0 + c B 0 = c A s + c B s = y s +d s a A s + a B s =0 n o 4 which is a system of equations and unknowns {c i 0,c i s,a i s} i=a,b,q s. This system implicitly defines our equilibrium. Using the price of Arrow security, we can find the price of risk-free bond and Lucas tree as q rf = q tree = q s q s d s 3. Consider a complete-markets exchange economy populated by identical consumers whose preferences exhibit habit persistence : X E 0 β t (c t λc t ) σ, σ t=0 where σ>0,β (0, ), and λ is positive and bounded. Each consumer has thesameendowmentω t in period t. Assume, for simplicity, that ω t grows deterministically according to: ω t+ = gω t,withg>. (a) Formulate the consumer s consumption-savings problem as a dynamic programming problem: there is one asset, a one-period riskless bond whose price is q. To simplify notation, we conjecture that in equilibrium the bond price is constant across time (we will check this conjecture later). Now the recursive formulation of the consumer s problem is v (a t,c t,ω t ) = max {c t,a t+ } s.t. (c t λc t ) σ σ c t + qa t+ = a t + ω t + βv (a t+,c t,ω t+ )

or equivalently, v (a t,c t,ω t ) = (a t + ω t qa t+ λc t ) σ max {a t+ } σ +βv (a t+,a t + ω t qa t+,ω t+ ) Note the choice of aggregate state variable here. In principle we should include the triple aggregate state (A, ω t, ω t ) into our state variable. But here we know that A =0, since it is a representative agent economy. And as long as we know about onevalueinthepair(ω t, ω t ), we can deduce the other from the constant growth rate g. Therefore, we need only one aggregate endowment (either ω t or ω t )asour aggregate state variable. For example, we could choose ω t and the bond price would be q t = q(ω t ). To save notation further, we can even write q t = q(ω t ), since this is a representative agent exchange economy (ω t = ω t ) and we cannot change (either individual or aggregate) endowment anyway. Furthermore, due to the special utility funciton here, we can conjecture that the bond price is constant across time and check it later. So after a long chain of reasoning, we choose q t = q and only include the individual triple state (a t,c t,ω t ) into our recursive formulation. (b) Derive the Euler equation for the consumer s problem. F.O.C. for this problem is a t+ :(u (c t,c t )+βv (t +))q = βv (t +) where v (t +)and v (t +)are partial derivatives of v (a t+,c t,ω t+ ). Theenvelopeconditionis Solve for this, we get a t : v (t) =u (c t,c t )+βv (t +) c t : v (t) =u (c t,c t ) v (t) = u (c t,c t )+βu (c t+,c t ) v (t) = u (c t,c t ) Iterate forward for one period and plug into F.O.C., we get the Euler Equation (u (c t,c t )+βu (c t+,c t )) q t+ = β (u (c t+,c t )+βu (c t+,c t+ )) q = β (u (c t+,c t )+βu (c t+,c t+ )) u (c t,c t )+βu (c t+,c t ) q = β (c t+ λc t ) σ βλ(c t+ λc t+ ) σ (c t λc t ) σ βλ(c t+ λc t ) σ Notice the similarity with normal Euler equation: it is the marginal rate of substitution between consumption c t+ and c t. The difference is the involvement of two period felicity function, which is due to the "habit persistence".

(c) Find the equilibrium bond price in this model as a function of the structural parameters. In equilibrium, we must have c t = ω t. Plug into the Euler Equation, we get the equilibrium bond price as q = β (u (ω t+,ω t )+βu (ω t+,ω t+ )) u (ω t,ω t )+βu (ω t+,ω t ) = β (ω t+ λω t ) σ βλ(ω t+ λω t+ ) σ (ω t λω t ) σ βλ(ω t+ λω t ) σ ³(gω σ t λω t ) σ βλ(g ω t λgω t ) = β = βg σ ³ σ ω t λω g t βλ(gωt λω t ) σ This verifies our conjecture that q t = q. The result is quite intuitive: (a) the more patient (β ) the individuals are, the higher the demand for savings, and the higher the asset price will be; (b) the higher of the growth rate of endowment (g ), the less need for saving, the lower the asset price. We need to be careful about the result. The independence of q on λ only because of this special utility function. From the derivation, we can see that with other functional form, λ may have a direct effect on q. (d) Suppose now that the endowment grows stochastically: ω t+ = g t+ ω t, where the growth rate g t+ is independent across time and takes on the two values λ > and λ < with equal probability. Find the prices of the Arrow securities and use them to compute the (long-run) average rate of return on a riskless bond in this model. If you cannot find explicit solutions for the prices of the Arrow securities, then show what conditions they must satisfy (i.e., find a set of equations that determine these prices) and explain how you would use them to compute the average rate of return on a riskless bond in this model. Define the price and holdings of Arrow security at time t as {q t,q t } and {a,t+,a,t+ }, respectively. Now the recursive formulation of the consumer s decision problem becomes (c i,t λc t ) σ v (a i,t,c t,ω i,t,λ i,t ) = max + {c t,a,t+,a,t+ } σ βev (a j,t+,c i,t,ω j,t+,λ j,t+ ) s.t. c i,t + q (ω it,λ i,t )a,t+ + q (ω it,λ i,t )a,t+ = a i,t + ω i,t where a i,t means the asset holdings in state i. Again notice the choice of state variables here. Different from the deterministic case, here we need to include both (ω t, ω t ) in our aggregate state variable. (or equivalently, here we use the pair (ω i,t,λ i,t ) as our aggregate state variable). Refer to the comments given in part (a) for the chain of logic. 3

Plug BC into objective function, we have v (a i,t,c t,ω i,t,λ i,t ) = (a i,t + ω it q a,t+ q a,t+ λc t ) σ max {a,t+,a,t+ } σ +βev (a j,t+,a i,t + ω it q a,t+ q a,t+,ω j,t+,λ j,t+ ) Now we follow the same steps as in part (b) to derive the Euler equation. F.O.C. for this problem is a,t+ : (u (c t,c t )+βev (t +))q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= βv (,t+) a,t+ : (u (c t,c t )+βev (t +))q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= βv (,t+) where v (i, t +)and v (i, t +)are partial derivatives of v (a i,t+,c it,ω i,t+,λ i,t+ ). Theenvelopeconditionis Solve for this, we get a i,t : v (i, t) =u (c i,t,c t )+βev (t +) c t : v (i, t) =u (c i,t,c t ) v (i, t) = u (c i,t,c t )+βeu (c j,t+,c i,t ) v (i, t) = u (c i,t,c t ) Iterate forward for one period and plug into F.O.C., we get the Stochastic Euler Equation (u (c i,t,c t )+βe (u (c j,t+,c i,t ))) q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= µ β u (c,t+,c i,t ) +βeu (c j,t+,c,t+ ) and q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= β (u (c,t+,c i,t )+βeu (c j,t+,c,t+ )) u (c i,t,c t )+βe (u (c j,t+,c i,t )) β (c,t+ λc i,t ) σ λβe (c j,t+ λc,t+ ) σ (c i,t λc t ) σ λβe (c j,t+ λc i,t ) σ (u (c i,t,c t )+βe (u (c j,t+,c i,t ))) q (ω t,λ i,t )= β µ q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= β (u (c,t+,c i,t )+βeu (c j,t+,c,t+ )) u (c i,t,c t )+βe (u (c j,t+,c i,t )) β (c,t+ λc i,t ) σ λβe (c j,t+ λc,t+ ) σ (c i,t λc t ) σ λβe (c j,t+ λc i,t ) σ u (c,t+,c i,t ) +βeu (c j,t+,c,t+ ) 4

Plug equilibrium condition c i,t = ω i,t into S.E.E., we have q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= β (ω,t+ λω i,t ) σ λβe (ω j,t+ λω,t+ ) σ (ω i,t λω t ) σ λβe (ω j,t+ λω i,t ) σ q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= β (λ ω i,t λω i,t ) σ λβe (λ j λ ω i,t λλ ω i,t ) σ ³ω i,t λλi ω i,t σ λβe (λj ω i,t λω i,t ) σ and q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= β (λ λ) σ λβλ σ E (λ j λ) σ (λ i λ) σ λ σ i λβe (λ j λ) σ β (ω,t+ λω i,t ) σ λβe (ω j,t+ λω,t+ ) σ (ω i,t λω t ) σ λβe (ω j,t+ λω i,t ) σ β (λ ω i,t λω i,t ) σ λβe (λ j λ ω i,t λλ ω i,t ) σ ³ω i,t λλi ω i,t σ λβe (λj ω i,t λω i,t ) σ q (ω i,t,λ i,t )= β (λ λ) σ λβλ σ E (λ j λ) σ (λ i λ) σ λ σ i λβe (λ j λ) σ where E (λ j λ) σ = (λ λ) σ + (λ λ) σ. NoticethatthepriceofArrow securities does not depend on the state variable ω i,t, which is due to the assumptions on the preference and endowment process. Now we can calculate the price of risk-free bond as q rf (ω i,t,λ i,t ) = q (ω i,t,,λ i,t )+q (ω i,t,,λ i,t ) = β (λ λ) σ λβλ σ E (λ j λ) σ (λ i λ) σ λ σ i λβe (λ j λ) σ + β (λ λ) σ λβλ σ E (λ j λ) σ (λ i λ) σ λ σ i λβe (λ j λ) σ = β (λ λ) σ +(λ λ) σ λβ λ σ + λ σ E (λj λ) σ (λ i λ) σ λ σ i λβe (λ j λ) σ = β (λ λ) σ +(λ λ) σ λβ λ σ + λ σ (λ i λ) σ λ σ i λβe (λ j λ) σ and the long-run average return as q rf = q rf (ω i,t,,λ )+q rf (ω i,t,,λ ) Here we can do a little more exercise to check the relationship with deterministic case and the case without "habit formation". First, let λ = λ = g. Thenweget q rf (ω i,t,λ i,t )=βg σ and q rf = βg σ, which is the same as in the deterministic case. Second, let λ =0,weget q rf (ω i,t,λ i,t )= β λ σ + λ σ which is the same as the case of without "habit formation". 5