Economy at Risk: The Growing U.S. Trade Deficit

Similar documents
China s Currency: A Summary of the Economic Issues

Chapter 19 (8) International Monetary Systems: An Historical Overview

China s macroeconomic imbalances: causes and consequences. John Knight and Wang Wei

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress

Answers to Questions: Chapter 7

Data Brief. Dangerous Trends: The Growth of Debt in the U.S. Economy

3/9/2010. Topics PP542. Macroeconomic Goals (cont.) Macroeconomic Goals. Gold Standard. Macroeconomic Goals (cont.) International Monetary History

Chapter 19 International Monetary Systems: An Historical Overview

Chapter 2. International Flow of Funds. Lecture Outline. Balance of Payments Current Account Capital and Financial Accounts

Chapter 18. The International Financial System Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market

Econ 340. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102

Why I Worry About the Trade Deficit

The Case for Chinese Capital Controls. Global Economics Monthly February 2016

I don't understand the argument that even though inflation is not accelerating, the world nevertheless suffers from "global excess liquidity":

Understanding the New Zealand exchange rate

Economics of Money, Banking, and Fin. Markets, 10e (Mishkin) Chapter 18 The International Financial System

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Trade Deficits; Currency Manipulation

Figure 0.1 US current account balance as percent of GDP,

Chapter 24 CRISES IN EMERGING MARKETS

Chapter 2. International Flow of Funds. Lecture Outline. Balance of Payments Current Account Capital and Financial Accounts

Economic Interaction

1 of 24. Modern Macroeconomics: From the Short Run to the Long Run. 2 of 24. They could not have differed more sharply on economic theory and policy.

Time for a New Global Currency?

Ian J Macfarlane: Payment imbalances

The Balance of Payments. Balance of Payments. Balance of Payments Accounts. Balance of Payments Accounts. They are composed of the following:

The Future of the International Monetary System

Preface to Global imbalances. Is the world economy really at risk?, by Anton Brender and Florence Pisani

AP Gov Chapter 17 Outline

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 6

The fiscal adjustment after the crisis in Argentina

Economic Growth After the Crisis. Dani Rodrik April 20, 2009

Chapter 6. Government Influence on Exchange Rates. Lecture Outline

AQA Economics A-level

Goals of Topic 8. NX back!! What is the link between the exchange rate and net exports? How do different policies affect the trade deficit?

Monetary Policy Statement: March 2010

How Is Global Trade Financed? (EA)

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Definitions. Class 3

Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation

Outlook for the Chilean Economy

Practical Problems with Discretionary Fiscal Policy

Chapter 21 The International Monetary System: Past, Present, and Future

Economic Theories & Debt Driven Realities

ECONOMICS U$A 21 ST CENTURY EDITION PROGRAM #25 MONETARY POLICY Annenberg Foundation & Educational Film Center

The Impact of the Global Crisis on China and its Reaction (ARI)

BOP Problems and Marshall Lerner condition and J-curve

Should China Revalue? Domingo Cavallo and Joaquín Cottani

This is Policy Effects with Floating Exchange Rates, chapter 10 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

SHORT-TERM ACHIEVEMENTS AND LONG-TERM PROBLEMS. by Man 9{. MeCtzer

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

The global context and its implications for Latin America. Dani Rodrik May 17, 2010

CIE Economics AS-level

May 9, Dear Member of Congress:

Slides for International Finance Macroeconomic Policy (KOM Chapter 19)

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

Chapter Eleven. The International Monetary System

The Role of Asian Currencies in the International Monetary System

Mr Thiessen converses on the conduct of monetary policy in Canada under a floating exchange rate system

Sigma Alpha Capital Inc. Market Overview (as of January 31, 2013)

Gauging Current Conditions:

Chapter 2 Foreign Exchange Parity Relations

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 15 International Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics in an Open Economy

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 4

FOREWORD THE JAPANESE CAPITAL MARKETS

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

JAPAN s CURRENT FINANCIAL & ECONOMIC CRISIS. AContrarianView?

file:///c:/users/moha/desktop/mac8e/new folder (13)/CourseComp...

Ms Hessius comments on the inflation target and the state of the economy in Sweden

THE JAPANESE ECONOMY AND THE AFTERMATH OF ITS UNUSUAL RECESSION SHIJURO OGATA. Occasional Paper No. 19

Normalizing Monetary Policy

9 Right Prices for Interest and Exchange Rates

Global Imbalances and Current Account Imbalances

The massive deficit in the U.S. trade and current accounts is one of the most

Fiscal Policy. Fiscal Policy

SIEPR policy brief. Why Exchange Rate Changes Will Not Correct Global Trade Imbalances. About The Author. By Ronald I. McKinnon

China s Currency: A Summary of the Economic Issues

Period 3 MBA Program January February MACROECONOMICS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Core Course. Professor Ilian Mihov

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

Other similar crisis: Euro, Emerging Markets

10 Chapter Outline What is Keynesianism?

University of Toronto December 3, 2010 ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2 L0101 L0301 L0401 M 2-4 W 2-4 R 2-4

12 ECB GLOBAL IMBALANCES: RECENT DEVELOPMENTS AND POLICY REQUIREMENTS

Glenn Stevens: Capital flows and monetary policy

Consumption expenditure The five most important variables that determine the level of consumption are:

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 1

Global Imbalances and the U.S. Current Account Deficit. Economics 826 January 2009

Chapter 18 (7) Fixed Exchange Rates and Foreign Exchange Intervention

Effects of CNY Revaluation on Mongolian Economy

The U.S. Current Account Balance and the Business Cycle

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

A Personal Perspective on the Dollar Christian E. Weller, Senior Economist, Center for American Progress February 5, 2004

Econ 340. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Outline: Exchange Rates

EconS 327 Test 2 Spring 2010

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Lessons VII and VIII: BoP Accounting Mechanisms and Models of Exchange Rate. Determination

The U.S. Trade Deficit: A Sign of Good Times. Testimony before The Trade Deficit Review Commission

Balance-Sheet Adjustments and the Global Economy

Transcription:

Economy at Risk: The Growing U.S. Trade Deficit Statement by Professor Robert A. Blecker Department of Economics American University Washington, DC 20016-8029 blecker@american.edu Presented at AFL-CIO/USBIC Conference Trade Summit 2006: Crisis and Opportunity Washington, DC July 12, 2006

I have a feeling that explaining to this audience why the U.S. trade deficit is a bad thing and needs to be reversed is like preaching to the choir. So I am just going to spend a few minutes reviewing the economic problems that are associated with the trade deficit, and then I want to move on to outline a framework for thinking about the causes of the trade deficit and the options for reducing it. I see two broad types of problems stemming from the trade deficit, which we might call the real and financial effects. The real problems include above all the loss of good-paying jobs in tradable goods industries, especially manufacturing, which has contributed to the rising inequality in American society. The real problems also include the gradual shrinkage of the U.S. industrial sector to the point where so much of our production has been outsourced that it would be difficult, in the short run, even to produce enough goods to replace many of our imports unless we rebuild our industrial capacity. According to my estimates, the rise in the value of the dollar since 1995 which is a major cause of the trade deficit has discouraged investment in U.S. manufacturing to such an extent that the capital stock of the manufacturing sector was 17% lower in 2004 and new investment in U.S. manufacturing was more than 60% lower in 2004 than they would have been if the dollar had not appreciated. Although the remaining manufacturing capacity is highly efficient, it accounts for a shrinking portion of U.S. employment. Thus, the trade deficit does not simply cause a temporary reduction in output, but also a permanent loss of manufacturing capacity that can have long-lasting negative effects on the country s future productive capabilities. On the financial side, the trade deficit is sustained by capital inflows essentially, borrowing from abroad currently to the tune of about $800 billion annually. In the short run this use of a national credit card gives American consumers 1

the appearance of a free lunch, but in the long run it creates a serious vulnerability to a financial meltdown whenever foreign lenders are no longer willing to buy up massive amounts of U.S. assets that are likely to fall in value when the dollar eventually declines further than it has already. Today, most economists are debating whether we will have a soft or hard landing when that day comes, but the necessity of an eventual and painful adjustment is becoming ever more clear. How did we reach this situation? In part there is a long-term deterioration in U.S. competitiveness, some of which is inevitable due to the catch-up of less developed countries and former Communist nations, but some of which is due to our own neglect of our industrial base. In part, the U.S. economy is effectively more open to imports than many of its trading partners, especially in Asia, in spite of trade agreements like the WTO that create the appearance of reciprocal market opening. In some cases, other countries have been more willing to use government influence to promote domestic industrial production, rather than to encourage their own companies to move offshore as our government has. In addition, there are very important short-term macroeconomic factors that have caused the trade deficit to balloon in recent years. These factors include the persistent overvaluation of the dollar (see Figure 1) and the especially continued manipulation of exchange rates by China and other East Asian countries, as well as the slow growth in Europe and Japan that have contributed to their surpluses with the more rapidly growing U.S. economy. One red herring that we have to dismiss is the infamous twin deficits argument, which blames the trade deficit on the federal budget deficit. It is true that these two deficits are linked by an accounting identity, which says that the current account balance (the broadest measure of our trade) must equal the sum of the government 2

budget surplus plus the difference between private saving and investment. But this is an accounting identity, not a causal relationship. It does not mean that reducing the budget deficit will automatically improve the trade balance, because private saving and investment can adjust in ways that offset the shift in the fiscal balance. This is exactly what happened in the late 1990s, when the budget deficit shrank and turned into a surplus, but the trade deficit continued to grow as consumer spending boomed and private saving lagged behind private investment. There are good reasons to reduce the federal budget deficit and restore fiscal sanity, but no one should think that this would be sufficient by itself to solve the trade imbalance. In fact, there is really no secret about how to solve global trade imbalances; it is not rocket science. Good old-fashioned macroeconomics teaches that there are two essential devices for reducing a trade deficit: (1) expenditure-switching policies and (2) expenditure-changing policies. Expenditure-switching policies, which induce consumers (both at home and abroad) to buy more U.S. goods and less foreign goods, include exchange rate adjustments, import tariffs, and more complicated schemes such as Warren Buffet s auction quota proposal which is designed to promote exports as well as to restrain imports. Expenditure-changing policies could include fiscal restraint and reduced consumer spending in the U.S., but these must be accompanied by more expansionary macro policies and increased consumer spending by our trading partners in order to prevent U.S. adjustment from sparking a global downturn. If there were enough political leadership in the United States and the other major countries, it would be easy to formulate a deal in which these sorts of policies that is, exchange rate realignment combined with offsetting expenditure changes could be implemented simultaneously in a joint effort to reduce the trade imbalances that 3

threaten global financial stability, while maintaining growth and prosperity throughout the world economy. In an even more ideal world, we would reconsider the ideas of John Maynard Keynes and others since him to create a new source of global liquidity in order to eliminate the usage of dollars as an international reserve currency, which tends to keep its value chronically above a level that is optimal for the U.S. domestic economy (as happened to the British pound in an earlier era). Unfortunately, such leadership is lacking both at home and abroad today. In the absence of concerted efforts to create a more stable global financial system, we are left to our own devices to try to pressure countries like China to stop manipulating their currencies, and we have to consider fall-back measures such as an across-the-board tariff or a system of import quotas allocated to exporters. These sorts of measures are not ideal; especially, an import tariff helps to reduce imports but does not stimulate exports. Nevertheless, the adoption of such fall-back measures may be necessary, and their threatened adoption could potentially prod reluctant nations to make the adjustments that they have so far resisted. My own view, which I expressed in a 1992 book with the Economic Policy Institute, is that tariffs should be limited to imports from those countries that intervene heavily to keep their currencies artificially undervalued, and should be lifted if those countries abandon their currency manipulation and let their exchange rates adjust to levels consistent with more balanced trade. I realize, however, that considerations such as GATT/WTO legality and other factors may weigh in favor of other alternatives, as I m sure will be discussed by the next panel. It is important to note that some adjustment is already going on in the global economy, although so far it has been too little and too partial. As the blue line in Figure 2 shows, the dollar has fallen 23% in real terms relative to the major, floating rate 4

currencies (euro, yen, pound, etc.) since its peak in February 2002, and this has begun to show fruits in terms of more rapid export growth in the past two years. This makes sense, because U.S. exports compete primarily with European and Japanese products in global markets. However, the decline in the dollar relative to the major currencies has not helped much on the import side, since most of our imports now come from other trading partners such as China and other developing and transition economies. As Figure 2 also shows (see the red line), the dollar has not declined over the past four years relative to the currencies of these other countries, most of which have pegged or managed exchange rates and some of them (led by China, though China is not alone) have been amassing huge reserves of dollar assets in an effort to keep their currencies artificially low and the dollar artificially high. As a result of the continued undervaluation of so many foreign currencies, imports continue to grow just about as fast as exports (see Figure 3), thus leaving us with a persistently worsening deficit since imports are now much larger than exports as a result of a decade of persistently faster growth. 1 It should also be noted that the Fed s interest rate increases in the past few years which have been greater than necessary for restraining any actual inflationary threat have helped to halt the dollar from adjusting further downward vis-à-vis the major floating rate currencies. Thus, Fed policy is currently operating the wrong direction for solving our trade problem. Meanwhile, the willingness of foreign central banks to hold large amounts of low-return U.S. official assets (such as T-bills) has helped to keep down borrowing costs for both the U.S. government and the ever-more 1 In 2005, export growth exceeded import growth for the first time in ten years (see Figure 3), but only by a slight margin. 5

indebted U.S. consumers, and this helps to explain why the Bush administration has not been too eager to pressure those central banks into stopping their exchange market intervention. This brings me to my final point, which is that we have to recognize the political obstacles that currently prevent us from adopting a more rational policy about the trade deficit. The current situation, however dysfunctional and risky, has created powerful vested interests in maintaining the status quo. Corporations that have succeeded by outsourcing, financial institutions that benefit from large capital flows, and foreign countries that depend on exports for promoting growth and employment all have a stake in perpetuating the present currency misalignments and trade imbalances. And again, the Bush administration benefits politically from the willingness of foreign central banks to finance the growing U.S. federal debt, which relieves upward pressures on U.S. interest rates and thereby prevents American households and corporations from feeling more of a pinch from the budget deficit. At present, this combination of economic and politically interests is blocking any concerted effort to address the trade deficit and its real and financial consequences. Accordingly, not only those who are adversely affected by the present circumstances, but all who are concerned about the country s economic future, must exert pressure on the U.S. government to abandon its ostrich-like stance and take the trade deficit problem seriously. Hopefully, our government in cooperation with the other major countries can adopt a sensible package of exchange rate and macroeconomic policies to help wean this country and the global economy as a whole away from their unsustainable co-dependency on trade imbalances before it collapses of its own weight. If a cooperative approach is not possible, then unilateral actions such as tariffs 6

or auction quotas could be necessary either to rectify the imbalances or to induce other countries to permit the necessary adjustments in their exchange rates. Finally, it is important to remember that either a lower dollar or other expenditure-switching policies, although necessary and unavoidable, will not be effective in the long run unless we also address the underlying sources of U.S. competitive decline and work to recreate a larger industrial base in the United States. Thank you. 7

Figure 1 Fed's Broad Index of the Real Value of the U.S. Dollar Monthly, January 1990 - July 2006 120 All currencies Index, March 1973 = 100 110 100 90 80 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Source: U.S. Federal Reserve Board of Governors, Statistical Release H.10, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/summary/.

130 Figure 2 Fed's Indexes of the Real Value of the U.S. Dollar, Major Currencies versus Other Trading Partners Monthly, January 1990 - July 2006 120 Index, March 1973 = 100 110 100 90 Other Trading Partners Major Currencies 80 70 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Source: U.S. Federal Reserve Board of Governors, Statistical Release H.10, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/summary/.

Figure 3 Growth Rates of Real U.S. Exports and Imports of Goods Annually, 1990-2005 Exports Imports 15 10 Percent 5 0-5 -10 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product (Gross Domestic Product) Accounts, Table 4.2.1, www.bea.gov.