TIME PASSING AND THE MEASUREMENT OF DEPLETION

Similar documents
The Revised SEEA Draft, Chapter 5 Asset accounts Discussion Note. Ole Gravgård Statistics Denmark

Asset Account for Mineral and Energy Resources: Monetary Terms. Regional Training Workshop on the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

The revised SEEA and the environmental consequences of disposal of fixed capital

Monetary Valuation of UK Continental Shelf Oil & Gas Reserves

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

Economic and Social Council

INTRODUCING CAPITAL SERVICES INTO THE PRODUCTION ACCOUNT

Treatment of emission permits in the SEEA

Outcome Paper for Global Consultation. Issue #12: Valuation of Assets: A case study on the valuation of fish stocks 1

Twelfth Meeting of the IMF Committee on Balance of Payments Statistics Santiago, Chile, October 27-29, 1999

Accounting for Natural Capital in Mining MFP: Comparing User Costs for Non-Renewable Resources. Khanh V. Hoang

TREATMENT OF INTEREST ON INDEX-LINKED DEBT INSTRUMENTS 1

ACCRUAL RECORDING OF INTEREST REVISITED: WHY THE SNA MUST BE REVISED. A comment on the IMF Paper on Interest Accrual. Peter Hill

The User Cost of Non-renewable Resources and Green Accounting. W. Erwin Diewert University of British Columbia and UNSW Australia

Measuring subsoil natural resources in Australia. Presented by: Paul Roberts

Holding Gains and Interest Accrual

Asset Valuation and The Post-Tax Rate of Return Approach to Regulatory Pricing Models. Kevin Davis Colonial Professor of Finance

Information Paper. Financial Capital Maintenance and Price Smoothing

ACCOUNTING FOR DEPLETION OF NATURAL ASSETS IN THE 1993 SNA

Valuing the UK Continental Shelf s Oil and Gas Reserves

The internal rate of return (IRR) is a venerable technique for evaluating deterministic cash flow streams.

Imputation of property income in the case of liabilities between the sponsor and the pension fund

Expenses Impairment - Production 7 - (6,386) Exploration and evaluation expenditure 9 (1,509) (8,369) Administration expenses 8 (2,361) (5,128)

SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX (SAM) AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MACROECONOMIC PLANNING

UPDATE OF QUARTERLY NATIONAL ACCOUNTS MANUAL: CONCEPTS, DATA SOURCES AND COMPILATION 1 CHAPTER 4. SOURCES FOR OTHER COMPONENTS OF THE SNA 2

Mineral and Energy Resources

Australian National Accounts

QUEENSLAND COMPETITION AUTHORITY

JOINT OECD/ESCAP MEETING ON NATIONAL ACCOUNTS

Revised proposal for revenue from contracts with customers. Applying IFRS in Mining & Metals. Implications for the mining & metals sector March 2012

Report ISBN: (PDF)

Revised proposal for revenue from contracts with customers

MODULE 1: The role and importance of financial reporting Part A: The role and importance of financial reporting

Professional Level Essentials Module, Paper P2 (IRL)

The Production of Financial Corporations and Price/Volume Split of Financial Services And Non-Life Insurance Services

JOINT OECD/ESCAP MEETING ON NATIONAL ACCOUNTS

Invitation to comment Exposure Draft ED/2017/5 Accounting Policies and Accounting Estimates - Proposed amendments to IAS 8

A regulatory estimate of gamma under the National Gas Rules

Learning Objectives. 1. Describe how the government budget surplus is related to national income.

Property, Plant and Equipment

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. The Very Basics of Value. Discounted Cash Flow and the Gordon Model: CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION COMMON QUESTIONS

Question 1 Adjusting the contractual service margin

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES AGGREGATION ISSUES IN INTEGRATING AND ACCELERATING BEA S ACCOUNTS: IMPROVED METHODS FOR CALCULATING GDP BY INDUSTRY

Keywords: arm s length principle, transfer pricing, MNE economic rent, BEPS

Sources for Other Components of the 2008 SNA

BUSINESS VALUATIONS REVISED Introduction. 3.0 Definitions. 2.0 Scope INTERNATIONAL VALUATION GUIDANCE NOTE NO. 6

Changes in Existing Decommissioning, Restoration and Similar Liabilities

In transition The latest on IFRS 17 implementation

Capital Stock Measurement in New Zealand

Fourteenth Meeting of the IMF Committee on Balance of Payments Statistics Tokyo, Japan, October 24-26, 2001

How Important Are U.S. Capital Flows into Mexico?

Subject: IPSASB Consultation Paper - Recognition and Measurement of Social Benefits

The measurement of financial services in the national accounts and the financial crisis

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Asset Accounts. SEEA Training Seminar for ESCAP. February 23-26, 2016 Chiba, Japan. Joe St. Lawrence Statistics Canada

The Economy Wide Benefits of Increasing the Proportion of Students Achieving Year 12 Equivalent Education

Estimating gamma for regulatory purposes

Review of the Australian Consumer Price Index

Proposed amendments to IAS 19 and IFRIC 14. IFoA response to IASB

PUBLIC BENEFIT ENTITY INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC SECTOR ACCOUNTING STANDARD 21 IMPAIRMENT OF NON-CASH-GENERATING ASSETS (PBE IPSAS 21)

Appendix 4.2 Yukon Macroeconomic Model

Amended Accounting Standards_ Intermediate

RESPONSE TO DISCUSSION PAPER ON A REVIEW OF THE CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR FINANCIAL REPORTING

Submission to the Productivity Commission Draft Report on Migrant Intake into Australia

Ecosystem service valuation and consistency with other valuation approaches

Fisheries accounts, a summary of current work in New Zealand and Australia

COMMITTEE OF EUROPEAN SECURITIES REGULATORS

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

Benefit-Cost Analysis: Introduction and Overview

Naina Gadia, ACA IMPAIRMENT (AS 28) Naina & Co. Bangalore th August, Naina & Co

March Basis for Conclusions Exposure Draft ED/2009/2. Income Tax. Comments to be received by 31 July 2009

Publication of narrow money data: the implications of money market reform

VIII. FINANCIAL STATISTICS

Chapter 17. Provisions, Contingencies & Events after the Reporting Period

British Bankers Association

ICAEW REPRESENTATION 196/16

Property, Plant and Equipment

International Financial Reporting Standard 2. Share-Based Payment

IASB TENTATIVE DECISIONS UNDER IFRS 4: INSURANCE CONTRACTS

The CPI purpose and definition - the Australasian Debate

TOPIC 1: IS-LM MODEL...3 TOPIC 2: LABOUR MARKET...23 TOPIC 3: THE AD-AS MODEL...33 TOPIC 4: INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT...41 TOPIC 5: MONETARY POLICY

What does the Eurostat-OECD PPP Programme do? Why is GDP compared from the expenditure side? What are PPPs? Overview

Property, Plant and Equipment: Proceeds before Intended Use (Amendments to IAS 16)

Re: Toward a Measurement Framework for Financial Reporting by Profit-Oriented Entities

CHAPTER 11. Depreciation, Impairments, and Depletion 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 10, 13, 19, 20, 28 7, 8, 9, 12, 30

Reporting on the Long-Term Sustainability of an Entity s Finances

The International Comparison Program (ICP) provides estimates of the gross domestic product

Manual on the Changes between ESA 95 and ESA 2010

14 October 2013 Rev 25 SNA BASIC CONCEPTS (BASED ON SNA 2008)

Must know Transition Resource Group debates IFRS 17 implementation issues

Loan Valuation Issues May 31, 2004

Measuring the Services of Commercial Banks in the NIPAs

Income Taxes. International Accounting Standard 12 IAS 12. IFRS Foundation A625

Improvements to IFRSs PART I

Privatisation and Infrastructure Australian Federal Tax Framework (January 2017 Draft)

New Zealand Equivalent to International Accounting Standard 12 Income Taxes (NZ IAS 12)

Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary Level and Advanced Level 9706 Accounting November 2014 Principal Examiner Report for Teachers

ED/2013/7 Exposure Draft: Insurance Contracts

The Expenditure-Output

OIL AND GAS DEVELOPMENT COMPANY LIMITED BALANCE SHEET AS AT 30 JUNE 2013

Transcription:

TIME PASSING AND THE MEASUREMENT OF DEPLETION Peter Comisari Centre of Environment and Energy Statistics Australian Bureau of Statistics Note prepared for the London Group meeting on Environmental and Economic Accounting. Brussels, 29 September 3 October 2008 Executive summary 1. This note is intended as a contribution to the continuing debate within London Group on the treatment of depletion of natural resource assets within the updated SEEA. It specifically addresses treatment of time passing ; an element of the Net Present Valuation (NPV) method of calculating depletion of natural resource assets. 2. The discussion here is a response to the reconsideration and suggestions raised by London Group member Ole Gravgård Pedersen in a paper circulated in advance of the 2008 London Group meeting in Brussels: Accounting for the value of time passing and the depletion of natural resources, Reconsideration and some suggestions (Gravgård, 2008). 3. Two key points are raised in Ole s paper. The first is that the time passing element should not form part of the measure of depletion; instead, it should be treated as a holding gain and accounted for in the revaluation account. Secondly, that the time passing element, while not a form of production, could nevertheless be treated as income by following a Hicksian interpretation. 4. This note provides some reasoning why the time passing element is not a holding gain. In particular, if the price of a natural resource (or its price relativities) does not rise then there can be no holding gain. Time passing has long been recognised as an element of SNA consumption of fixed capital and, given the conceptual similarity of depletion and consumption of fixed capital, I suggest that the time passing element be treated consistently between the SNA and SEEA systems. It is therefore suggested that the time passing element be off-set against resource rent in deriving and presenting depletion in SEEA. 5. A direct consequence of treating the time passing element as a holding gain is that depletion equates to the full value of the resource rent. This would effectively leave extractive enterprises with a near-zero depletion-adjusted operating surplus. Ole s paper circumvents this consequence by treating this holding gain as a form of (Hicksian) income. 6. This note suggests that altering the concept of income to encompass certain holding gains is a fundamental change of principle. As such, it needs to be supported by a compelling case, rather than simply being a convenient solution to the consequences of treating time passing as a holding gain. 1

Resource rent, depletion and valuation of natural resource stocks 7. This section sets out a basic understanding of the relationship between estimated resource rent, depletion and return on natural resource (natural capital) assets. 8. The unit price of an extracted natural resource contains a resource rent reflecting the value of a marginal resource unit with respect to its future extraction (Hotelling, 1931). However, resource rents are not directly observable but instead are typically derived as the difference between total revenue generated from the extraction of natural resources less costs incurred during the extraction process including the cost of produced capital (which itself includes a return to produced capital). 9. Or, as stated more simply in SEEA-2003: "the value of capital service flows rendered by the natural resources, or their share in gross operating surplus, is the...resource rent (para 7.167) 10. Depletion is then derived as resource rent minus the opportunity costs of capital invested in the natural resource (SEEA-2003, para 10.30). Depletion represents the change in value of the natural resource stock due to extraction (SEEA-2003, para 7.168). This is consistent with the SNA definition of depletion. 11. For enterprises or industries using a mixture of produced and non-produced assets as capital inputs to the production process, gross operating surplus can be decomposed into consumption of fixed capital and net operating surplus. The net operating surplus can be further decomposed into a return to produced assets, a return to non-produced assets and a measure of depletion (the latter two when added together are termed resource rent). This decomposition of net operating surplus is typical of say a mining enterprise extracting subsoil assets, or a forestry enterprise harvesting natural forest. The relationship is depicted in diagram 1. Diagram 1. Producers using produced and natural capital assets Capital services - produced capital Consumption of fixed capital Consumption of fixed capital Return to produced assets Gross operating surplus Net operating surplus Return to natural capital assets Resource depletion Capital services natural capital (resource rent) 2

12. Since market values on undeveloped natural resources are frequently unavailable, it is generally accepted that a reasonable proxy for market value is achieved by summing the (discounted) stream of future resource rents expected from developing the resource. 13. The natural resource used as an input to extractive activity is valued at its below-ground 1 price. This is the price at which the input enters the production process. Through the productive process of extraction, the resource is transformed into a different product and a different price applies. For natural resource assets, the crux of our valuation problem is that typically only output prices are observable so that in practice we are forced to deduce the price of the inputs from these observed output prices and from what we know about the proposed schedule of production. Depletion and consumption of fixed capital 14. A natural resource asset in its natural state becomes a different product after it has been extracted. And it is the process of extraction itself that causes this change a process that utilises natural resources below ground as an input to production and delivers the extracted resource (above ground) as an output of production. The two different products have different prices, and extraction proceeds on the assumption that a unit above ground will be worth more than a unit below ground. 15. The depletion provision can be thought of as the amount needed to be set aside from current operating surplus to allow replacement of the natural resource asset. So what price applies to the depletion provision? That is, what exactly is the depletion provision seeking to replace? 16. A central feature of the System of National Accounts (SNA) is the requirement to provide (charge) for the using up of produced capital. So, in the first instance at least, we could take our cue from SNA s treatment of consumption of fixed capital. If we consider that the amount of consumption of fixed capital charged as a cost of production should be sufficient to enable the assets to be replaced, if desired (cf. SNA 2008, 1.67). 17. This must be interpreted as recommending a charge of sufficient value to replace the capital used as an input to the production process. It is not saying we should enable replacement of the full value of capital services achievable from using the produced capital. Similarly for depletion, it is the value of the natural resource as an input to the extraction process that we should charge against production, not the full value of the resource rent resulting from the extractive process. 1 The terms below ground and above ground are used throughout this paper to refer to, respectively, natural resources in their natural state; and the extracted product. The terms are used here to apply to all SEEA natural resource assets, even though they will not always accurately describe their physical characteristics. 3

18. SNA 2008 states that the depletion of natural resources covers the reduction in the value of deposits of sub-soil assets as a result of the physical removal and using up of the assets. (SNA 2008, para 12.26). This means that we set aside an amount that can replace the value of the natural resource as an input to production (i.e. its below ground value), not the value of outputs that the resource can generate. SNA2008 s valuation basis is entirely appropriate and applicable to SEEA. Time passing and depletion 19. Given the available techniques of extraction, the physical characteristics of the deposit and the demand for the asset, there will emerge an optimal schedule for the extraction of the natural resource asset. If we know the physical size of the resource, and our capacity for extraction within each period, it is possible to specify this schedule as the extraction of a sequence of quantities over the expected life of the asset (n). The value of the stock of the asset below ground at the start of period t (V 1 ) is determined by the present value of expected receipts, less expected extraction costs, derived from the progressive extraction and sale of the natural resource throughout the expected production schedule. n RR t V t = Σ [equation 1] t=1 (1+r) t Where: V = net present value, RR = resource rent, r = discount rate, n = asset life 20. Depletion in any one year is the change in the value of the resource between the beginning and end of the year arising purely from the extraction of the resource. By re-arranging equation 1, depletion in the year can also be shown to be equal to the year s resource rent minus a return on the natural resource asset (equation 2). d = V 1 V 2 = RR rv 1 [equation 2] Where d is depletion, V 1 and V 2 are the opening stock value at period 1 and 2, respectively, RR is the resource rent of period 1, r is the discount rate, and rv 1 is the income component of the resource rent. 21. Depletion therefore consists of two inter-related components: the current value of the quantity extracted; and the increase in the present value of the quantities remaining in stock. It has been known for many years (see for example, Hotelling, 1925) that these two components likewise occur for produced capital in the derivation of consumption of fixed capital i.e. consumption of fixed capital consists of the current price value of capital services used up in the course of production less the increase in current value of services remaining to be released by the asset over its 4

remnant service life. Conventional international practice is to simply net-off these two effects in the derivation of consumption of fixed capital estimates. 22. The central question we need to address is how to treat these two components of resource rent: depletion; and the item denoted by rv 1 in equation 2 (the so called time passing element). 23. It is worth noting at the outset that the time passing effect is not passive. Value does not simply accrue because we have taken one temporal step closer to future production. The value of the natural resource (and of the time passing effect) are rooted in an expectation that the owner of the asset will use it according to an identified schedule of production, with expected output prices and production costs (among other assumptions). The calculation of asset values (and therefore depletion) is entirely based on an expectation of benefits arising from a defined schedule of extractive activity. 24. SNA provides a comprehensive framework to understand various possible causes of asset valuation change over time. Essentially, the change in value of an asset can be accounted for in one of three ways: (i) (ii) (iii) Stock changes due to consumption within a production process. Or due to quantities acquired or disposed of in transactions with other economic entities. These changes are recorded in the transaction accounts (e.g. depletion is recorded in the production account); Changes due to events not related to economic transactions, for example, catastrophic losses. Recorded in the other changes in volume of assets account ; or Changes may be caused by asset price changes. These holding gain/losses are recorded in the revaluation account. 25. Depletion falls into the first category and is therefore restricted to the effect on the value of the asset solely caused by its use in production. Any effect deemed to be a holding gain/loss or an other change in volume cannot be part of our measure of depletion. 26. As a way of illustrating the characteristics of depletion and of the time passing element consider the following scenarios apparently similar but with different implications for time passing and therefore for measured depletion. Consider one natural resource for which extraction cannot commence immediately but which must instead wait one year to start. As production has yet to commence, we see in equation 2 that the resource rent is zero, while the rv 1 ( time passing ) item is positive. As a result, our measure of the natural resource asset value has actually increased as it moves closer to the period in which it can be used. Under this scenario measured depletion is negative for the first period. Compare this scenario to one in which the schedule of production has had to be delayed for one year (say, due to the impact of a catastrophic natural event) and the whole production schedule moved back one year. Under this second scenario the resource rent is again zero but there has been no increase in the present value of the quantities remaining in stock (i.e. no time passing effect) because they are no closer to being realised than they were at the start of the period. Under this second scenario there has been no increase in the value of the stock in the ground and measured depletion is zero. Therefore, simply knowing that a natural resource remains unused for one period does not, of itself, provide enough detail to understand and estimate depletion. 5

27. The increase in the value of the asset s unused natural capital services is a part of an asset s economic characteristics and reflects the necessity of waiting to release these services in the process of production. This increase in value corresponds generally with the expected schedule of extractive activity; it does not always follow precisely. Its inevitable lack of complete precision can lead to counterfactual results (such as the negative depletion cited in the previous paragraph) and this simply reinforces the need to closely observe the assumptions, workings and outputs of the NPV technique. 28. When extractive activity takes place and is expected to follow a schedule of production into the future, what happens as we move forward one period? A certain amount of the natural resource is used up in extraction, causing a decline in the value of the asset (depletion). In the absence of readily available market values, we cannot observe the precise value of this depletion. It must be inferred from the resource rent; which is itself inferred from observed values of operating surplus. 29. But we know that the value of the resource rent derives from above-ground prices achieved on sales of the extracted resource. The depletion value is based on below ground prices. We therefore generally expect the value of resource rent to exceed that of the depletion, though in concept (as well as in practice) this is not necessary. The difference between resource rent and depletion is income and is the return to the extractor for undertaking extractive activity. The time passing effect relates directly to this income component. It is the release of one year of this income from the stock of future expected resource rents embodied in the value of the natural resource asset. 30. Typically, as we move forward one period, resource rent arises from production and the entire quantum of this resource rent enters the accounts as a part of operating surplus. We do not need to adjust any extra income into the accounts. However, we do need to add a charge for depletion. If the natural resource asset is valued by NPV approach, depletion must be modelled and the primary observation we work with is resource rent the NPV model is essentially built around the observed resource rent and a range of assumptions and expectations. One of the assumptions underlying the model is that resource rent is comprised of income and depletion components. If we were to assume, for example, that depletion is equal to the entire amount of resource rent, our model would operate differently. 31. Our charge for depletion is estimated from our model i.e. it appears as part of the unwinding of value from the natural resource asset according to our expected production schedule. Resource rent is already included in the production and income accounts, as is the income component of resource rent. Neither of these items is needed for our depletion adjustment, the only component required is the depletion measure. 32. If the objective of our exercise is to derive the depletion measure, why also explicitly record the measures of resource rent and income? Why mislead users by labelling resource rent as depletion? It means that we need to correct this mislabelling with a contra-item called time passing (or similar). Neither the balance sheet nor the flow accounts benefit from this presentation. Why not simply record what we want to record; the decline in asset value due to its physical removal and using up i.e. depletion? In the SNA, a similar NPV exercise is used in deriving consumption of fixed capital where it is well known that the time passing effect also occurs. Its meaning, treatment and presentation has been debated in SNA-related forums and it is now standard practice to simply net-off the capital services and time 6

passing effects in the derivation of consumption of fixed capital. This treatment is now a relatively uncontroversial part of SNA principles and practice. Implications of treating time passing as a holding gain 33. Assume, however that we were to accept that the effect of time passing on natural resource asset values is a holding gain, what is the impact on SEEA aggregates? 34. The most important change is that depletion would equate to the entire value of the resource rent. Therefore, in deriving depletion-adjusted measures of production and income, the full amount of the resource rent would need to be deducted from current production. That is, we would deduct not only the decline in value of the natural resource caused by its extraction, but also that part of operating surplus generated from using the natural resource. In practice, it would remove much of the operating surplus of extractive industries and, for economies with significant extractive activity it would have a significant downward impact on measures of adjusted GDP. An analyst examining these accounts would be unclear as to why anybody would engage in extractive activity. 35. Integrated Economic and Environmental accounts will gain quicker and more complete acceptance if they reflect the realities of interactions between environment and economy. Based on current experience in Australia, acceptance of these accounts requires recognition that the using up of natural resources incurs a cost to the nation. Equally, though, there needs to be continuing recognition that the extraction of natural resources generates income. For example, Australia recently announced an intention to create a Building Australia Fund to finance future infrastructure development. This initiative is largely being funded by taxation receipts related to the current resources boom and is recognition that eventually natural capital will need to be replaced by other means of generating income. It is a reality that business receipts (and government revenue) are boosted by extractive activity. Treating time passing as a holding gain in the accounts means that these receipts are effectively removed from SEEA s production and income accounts. Income received from extractive activity would remain more or less unaffected throughout cycles of natural resource boom and bust. 36. It has been suggested however that the time passing element, if treated as a holding gain, could nevertheless be reclaimed as income using Hicksian logic. In this way, resource rent would be split into depletion and (redefined, Hicksian) income components. This would effectively restore the SEEA measure of depletion to equate with resource rent less the time passing element, thereby placating the concerns raised in the preceding paragraphs. Time passing redefined as (Hicksian) income 37. Two fundamental SNA principles are: that income derives from production; and holding gains on assets do not of themselves constitute production. So, for example, a share price increase (holding gain) is not production since no good or service has been produced. The increase in the share price is not SNA income. 7

38. Treating the time passing effect as a holding gain represents a fundamental change of concept with significant implications for key SEEA aggregates. If we propose to treat certain holding gains as income, this needs to be done because there are compelling reasons to do so. We should not recommend treating the time passing effect as income simply as a way of achieving the right measure of depletion. 39. It s generally agreed that SEEA and SNA both benefit from a consistency in the basic conceptual underpinnings of their economic measures. Concepts of economics are well established in the SNA through comprehensive processes of consultation and review, therefore, proposals to change these concepts need to be convincing. If the arguments are, at best, mildly appealing then why create a series of fundamental inconsistencies in the integrated environmental and economic accounts? 40. The proposal creates counter-intuitive results. It would deliver different economic treatments to growth in non-renewable natural resources subject to identical natural processes. For example, tree growth in a plantation forest would be treated as a form of production leading to income, while the corresponding process in a natural forest would also generate income, but without any production occurring. Imagine there was a community decision to convert a commercial forest plantation into a natural forest. This would lead to; no change in environmentally-adjusted national income; but a fall in environmentally adjusted GDP. The approach agreed to at the December 2007 meeting of London Group would result in no change to either environmentally-adjusted national income or environmentally adjusted GDP because it applies consistent treatment of tree growth across both natural and plantation forests. 41. The time passing element must be calculated using NPV methodology. For those natural resources yet to commence production, the passage of time will not of itself lead to a real-world price change and therefore no holding gain is discernable from observed market prices. In this unique situation the holding gain is a phantom gain it cannot be observed in the real world. Estimation of the time passing effect would be a unique case where we cannot use market prices but instead must use an NPV approach. Comments on the practice of estimating depletion of natural resource assets 42. It is worth making a number of observations on the practice of estimating natural resource asset values and related depletion. The following comments are drawn from the experience of the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS). 43. In estimating natural resource asset values, resource rent and depletion, close scrutiny must be paid to results generated. Any problems in the underlying measures of gross operating surplus, consumption of fixed capital or estimates of return to produced capital will impact on our estimate of resource rent. For example, while it is possible to generate negative resource rents, we would not expect this to continue for an extended period of time. It might be necessary, for example, to reassess estimates of capital services on produced capital used in the extractive process. 44. Estimation of the depletion and income components of resource rent also tends to be an iterative process. For example, negative depletion should not be 8

allowed to occur; in practical terms, its existence indicates a problem with one or more of the data inputs or assumptions used. It might be necessary, for instance, to reassess and adjust the discount rate used. 45. The time passing element is not separately identifiable in the Australian accounts. It is combined with the resource rent to generate depletion of natural resource assets. In this respect it is consistent with the presentation used for consumption of fixed capital in the SNA and the Australian national accounts. 46. In the Australian balance sheets, holding gains on natural resources are dealt with as a separate exercise to the NPV calculation of asset values and depletion. Holding gains can be derived by applying pure (observed) price changes to the balance sheet. They can also be derived residually if the balance sheet open and close positions and transactions and other volume changes are known. Unit prices of natural resources used in NPV estimation must be consistent with the index used to derive the holding gains. 9

References Comisari, P. (2007) Issues Paper: Depletion in the SEEA Narrowing Down the Options. London Group Meeting, Johannesburg, 26-30 March 2007. Gravgård Pedersen, O. (2008) Accounting for the value of time passing and the depletion of natural resources, Reconsideration and some suggestions. London Group meeting, Brussels, 29 September 3 October 2008. Hartwick, J. and Hageman, A. (1993) Economic Depreciation of Mineral Stocks and the Contribution of El Serafy, in E. Lutz (ed.), Toward Improved Accounting for the Environment, The World Bank, Washington. Hill, P. (1998) Accounting for depletion in the SNA. Presented at the One Day Meeting on Accounting for Environmental Depletion, Paris, 28 September 1998. Hotelling, H. (1925) A General Mathematical Theory of Depreciation. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 20 pp 340-353. United Nations, International Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, World Bank and Commission of the European Communities, System of National Accounts 1993, Brussels/Luxembourg, New York, Paris, Washington D.C., 1993. United Nations, European Commission, International Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, World Bank, Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting 2003, Brussels/Luxembourg, New York, Paris, Washington D.C., 2003. 10