MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Similar documents
1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

A Moment Matching Approach To The Valuation Of A Volume Weighted Average Price Option

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Calculation of Volatility in a Jump-Diffusion Model

The Black-Scholes Model

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

The stochastic calculus

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Lévy models in finance

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model

The Normal Distribution

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

In this lecture we will solve the final-value problem derived in the previous lecture 4, V (1) + rs = rv (t < T )

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory).

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Universität Regensburg Mathematik

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

The Black-Scholes Equation

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

The Derivation and Discussion of Standard Black-Scholes Formula

1 The continuous time limit

Non-semimartingales in finance

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

Financial Risk Management

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

In chapter 5, we approximated the Black-Scholes model

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

Risk Neutral Valuation

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Likelihood Estimation of Jump-Diffusions

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Finance II. May 27, F (t, x)+αx f t x σ2 x 2 2 F F (T,x) = ln(x).

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

King s College London

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Stochastic Modelling Unit 3: Brownian Motion and Diffusions

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Risk Neutral Measures

Computational Finance

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

A discretionary stopping problem with applications to the optimal timing of investment decisions.

Merton s Jump Diffusion Model

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE. A Modern View on Merton s Jump-Diffusion Model Gerald H. L. Cheang and Carl Chiarella

Path Dependent British Options

CHAPTER 5 ELEMENTARY STOCHASTIC CALCULUS. In all of these X(t) is Brownian motion. 1. By considering X 2 (t), show that

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Transcription:

MSc Financial Engineering 2012-13 CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 Department EMS, Birkbeck Introduction The assignment consists of Reading and understanding the introductory text on Ito calculus for jump-diffusions in Part I below. Answering the three exercise of Part II, in which you are asked to develop part of the Merton jump-diffusion model for option pricing. Literature may of course be consulted, but the answers will have to be phrased in your own words. 1. Part I: Ito calculus for jump diffusions Stock prices can exhibit sudden large jumps, for example on arrival of unexpected good or bad news. These jumps can t be modelled very well by Brownian motion, and have to be added separatedly. The archetypical stochastic jump process is the so-called Poisson process, and we will model our stock return by the sum of a Brownian diffusion and a Poisson process with random jumps. Such processes are known as jump diffusions. This section introduces the Poisson process, and extends the Ito-lemma to jump-diffusions. In part 2 you will be asked to apply this to option pricing. 1.1. Poisson process. A stochastic process (N t ) t 0 is called a Poisson process if 1. N t only takes on values 0, 1, 2,... and N 0 = 0. 2. If s t, then N t N s is Poisson-distributed with mean λ(t s): this means that (λ(t s))n (1) P(N t N s = n) = e λ(t s), n = 0, 1, 2,... n! 3. If u s < t, then N u and N t N s are independent. Here λ > 0 is a constant which is called the intensity of the Poisson process. The definition of a Poisson process is quite similar to that of a Brownian motion, except that we have replaced the normal distribution by the 1

2 Poisson distribution. Note N t is an increasing (in the sense of nondecreasing) function of t: s t implies that N s N t, since the event that N t N s < 0 has probability 0, by 2. A Poisson process will jump from 0 to 1 at some time T 1, then from 1 to 2 at some time T 2, etc. In general, it will jump to i at (2) T i := the smallest t such that N t i. We artificially put T 0 = 0. The jump times T 1, T 2,... are random times, and it can be shown that the waiting times between T i T i 1 between jumps are independent and exponentially distributed. Instead of just jumping by an amount of 1, we can generalize the process by admitting stochastic jumps of J i at the successive jump times T i of a Poisson process. We will do this below, but first have a look at Ito calculus for a Poisson process. 1.2. Stochastic Calculus with Poisson processes. We start by considering the stochastic differential of N t, and then study the differential of functions on N t. By definition, (3) dn t := N t+dt N t ; Note that dn t can only take on values 0, 1, 2, etc. It will do so with probabilities 1 P(dN t = k) = λk (dt) k e λt = 0 if k 2, k! since dt is an infinitesimal: (dt) 2 = (dt) 3 = = 0. It follows that dn t is either 0 or 1, with probabilities and e λdt = 1 λdt + (λdt)2 2 = 1 λdt, (λdt)e λdt = λdt(1 λdt + (λdt)2 ) = λdt, 2 respectively, using the Taylor expansion of the exponential and the fact that dt is an infinitesimal. Summarizing: 1, probability λdt (4) dn t = 0, probability 1 λdt. If we now consider a function f(n t ) of N t, then df(n t ) := f(n t+dt ) f(n t ) = f(n t + dn t ) f(n t ), and we therefore have f(nt + 1) f(n df(n t ) = t ), probability λdt 0, probability 1 λdt. 1 take t s = dt in (1)

Since df(n t ), like dn t, takes on only two different values, one of which is 0, and with the same probabilities as dn t does, this can be summarized in a single equation: (5) df(n t ) = (f(n t + 1) f(n t )) dn t. 1.3. Stochastic calculus: Poisson processes with random jumps. More generally, let us consider a process (X t ) t 0 which jumps at the same times as a Poisson process, but whose jumps are given by random variables J t (if the jump takes place at time t). Using stochastic differentials, such a process can be denoted by (6) dx t = J t dn t. By similar arguments as before we now have f(xt + J df(x t ) = t ) f(x t ), probability λdt 0, probability 1 λdt hich e can write more succintly as (7) df(x t ) = (f(x t + J t ) f(x t )) dn t. We will always assume that the jumps are independent of the Poisson process. Later on we will also assume that they are mutually independant and identically distributed (that is, have the same probability distributions). 1.4. Stochastic calculus with jump-diffusions. A jump-diffusion process is a stochastic process (X t ) t 0 whose stochastic differential is given by (8) dx t = A t dt + B t dw t + J t dn t, where (W t ) t 0 and (N t ) t 0 are, mutually independent, Brownian motion and Poisson processes, respectively. We assume that A t and B t are adapted to the filtration generated by (W s, N s ) : s < t}, that is, A t and B t are functions of the Brownian and Poisson trajectories up till, but not including 2 time t; we also say in this situation that A t and B t are previsible. We furthermore assume that J t is conditionally independent of dn t, given this filtration (that is, given such trajectories). We then have the Theorem 1.1. (Ito s lemma for jump-diffusion processes). Let f(x, t) be a C 2 -fundtion of x and t. Then ( f df(x t, t) = t + A f t x dt + 1 ) 2 f f (9) 2 B2 t dt + B x 2 t x dw t + (f(x t + J t, t) f(x t, t)) dn t, } 3 2 for Brownian motion it does not matter whether we include t or not: by continuity, knowing W s for all s < t implies knowing W t; for N t it is important not to include t, since a jump might happen precisely at t

4 were all derivatives of f are to be evaluated at (X t, t), that is, just before any (potential) jump in (t, t + dt]. Proof. The proof is a combination of the Ito-lemma for Brownian motion and the previous arguments for pure jump processes. To simplify notations, we put dy t = A t dt + B t dw t, the diffusion part of dx t. Also to simplify the exposition, we limit ourselves to functions f(x) of x only, leaving the more general case to the reader. Then df(x t, t) = f(x t+dt ) f(x t ) f(xt + dy = t ) f(x t ), probability 1 λdt f(x t + J t + dy t ) f(x t ), probability λdt. The usual Ito-lemma applied to the first line gives We can re-write the second line as f (X t )dy t + 1 2 f (X t )(dy t ) 2. f(x t + J t + dy t ) f(x t + J t ) + f(x t + J t ) f(x t ), and again apply the usual Ito-lemma to the first term. Hence f df(x t, t) = (X t )dy t + 1f (X 2 t )(dy t ) 2, f (X t + J t )dy t + 1f (X 2 t + J t )(dy t ) 2 + f(x t + J t ) f(x t ), with probabilities 1 λdt and λdt, respectively. In terms of dn t, df(x t ) = f (X t )dy t + 1 2 f (X t )(dy t ) 2 + (f (X t + J t ) f (X t )) dy t + 12 (f (X t + J t ) f (X t )) (dy t ) 2 } dn t + f(x t + J t ) f(x t )} dn t. We now argue that all terms in the second line are equal to 0. Indeed, dy t dn t and (dy t ) 2 dn t are all random variables with mean and variance 0: we have for example that E(dW t dn t ) = E(dW t )E(dN t ) = 0, and 3 var(dw t dn t ) = E(dW 2 t )E(dN t ) 2 ) = dt (λdt + λ 2 (dt) 2 ) = 0. Hence dw t dn t = 0. Similarly, dtdn t = 0. Using the adaptedness of the coefficient processes A t, B t, the same conclusion follows for dy t dn t and, a forteriori, for (dy t ) 2 dn t. Hence df(x t ) = f (X t )dy t + 1 2 f (X t )(dy t ) 2 + ( f(x t + J t ) f(x t ) ) dn t, which is the same as (9) for the f s considered. 3 since one easily computes that the variance of Nt N s is λ(t s), t > s

Now that we have extended the Ito-calculus to jump-diffusion processes, we can do derivative pricing à la Black and Scholes, using such processes as the fundamental drivers of asset prices. 1.5. Merton s jump-diffusion model. Merton s model assumes that the underlying asset price evolves according to ds t (10) = µdt + σdw t + (J t 1)dN t, S t where S t stands for the value of S just before a jump at t, if there is one. We assume that jump-sizes J t are identically distributed and mutually independent. We also assume that the three processes (W t ) t 0, (N t ) t 0 and (J t ) t 0 are independent. To explain the J t 1, consider what happens with the asset price when a jump occurs at T i. Letting S Ti be the asset price just before the jump, we have that ds Ti S Ti = S T i S Ti S Ti = (J Ti 1), or S Ti = J Ti S Ti. Since prices should not become negative, we will assume wlog that J Ti 0. With the previous observation, the SDE (10) becomes easy to solve: S t evolves like a Geometric Brownian motion between jumps, and gets multiplied by J Ti at the jump-times T 1 < T 2 < of the Poisson process. To simplify notations, we will write J i := J Ti. Then, S 0 e (µ 1 2 σ2 )t+σw t, 0 t < T 1, S (11) S t = 0 J 1 e (µ 1 2 σ2 )t+σw t, T 1 t < T 2, S 0 J 1 J 2 e (µ 1 2 σ2 )t+σw t, T 2 t < T 3, etc. Equivalently, the usual GBM gets multiplied by J 1 J k if there are k jumps in [0, t]: (12) S t = S 0 J 1 J 2 J k e (µ 1 2 σ2 )t+σw t if N t = k, which sometimes is summarized in the single formula: ( Nt ) (13) S t = S 0 J ν e (µ 1 2 σ2 )t+σw t, ν=0 where we artificially put J 0 := 1. 5

6 2. Part II: Derivative pricing in jump-diffusion models Suppose the asset price S t follow a jump-diffusion process (10), and consider a derivative contract written on the asset, with price a function V (S t, t) of S t and of t. Exercise 2.1. Set up a portfolio Π t at time t by going long the derivative, and shorting t of the underlying asset. The amount t can only depend on information avialable prior to a (potential) jump at t. (a) By using Ito s lemma for jump diffusions, show that ( ( ) V V dπ t = t + µs t S t + 1 ) 2 σ2 St 2 2 V dt S ( ) 2 V + σs t S t dw t + (V (JS t, t) V (S t, t)) t S t (J t 1)) dn t, with derivatives evaluated in (S t, t) (that is, pre-jump). (b) There are now two sources of risk: the familiar diffusion risk coming from the dw t -term, but also the jump risk. Explain why it is not possible anymore to completely eliminate the risk, and why it is not even possible to totally eliminate the jump-risk on its own. (What would t have to be? Can it, given that it has to depend on pre-jump information only?). (c) Choose t = V/ S(S t, t) to eliminate the diffusion risk. Merton assumed that financial markets would not reward jump-risk, since it is asset specific, and can in principle be diversified away. The expected return of the resulting portfolio would therefore be the risk-free return. Under this assumption, show that V (S, t) satisfies (14) V t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V V + (r κ)s + λe (V (JS, t) V (S, t)) = rv, S2 S where J is a random variable which is identically distributed with J t, and where κ is given by κ = λe(j 1), λ being the intensity of the Poisson process. For a European-style derivative this has to be solved for t < T, with boundary condition V (S, T ) = F (S), F (S) representing the pay-off. (d) Equation (14) is sometimes called a partial integral-differential equation or PIDE. To understand why, re-write the equation in terms of the pdf f J (x) of the jump J.

Exercise 2.2. (Feynman-Kac for jump diffusions) There are several ways of solving (14). This exercise explains the Feynman-Kac approach. Introduce a new process (Ŝt) t 0 by (15) dŝt = (r κ)ŝt dt + σŝt dw t + (J 1)Ŝt dn t. 7 (a) Suppose that V (S, t) solves (14). Show that e rt V (Ŝt, t) is a martingale. ( ) Hint: Compute d e rt V (Ŝt, t) = A t dt + B t dw t + C t dn t ; this is a martingale precisely when 0 = E t (dx t ) = A t dt + E t (C t dn t ), E t being expectation conditional on S t. To compute the E t (C t dn t )- term, use the independence of the jumps. (b) Suppose that V (S, T ) = F (S). Show that ( ) V (S, t) = e r(t t) E F (ŜT ) Ŝt = S, which is the Feynman-Kac solution for (14) with final condition V (S, T ) = F (S). (c) By using the explicit solution of the SDE (15), show that ( ( ( Nτ ) ) ) V (S, t) = e rτ E F S J ν e (r κ 1 2 σ2 )τ+σ(w T W t) (16) = k=0 ν=0 (λτ) k ( ( ) ) e (r+λ)τ E F SJ 1 J k e (r κ 1 2 σ2 )τ+σ(w T W t). k! where τ := T t and N τ = N T N t. Hint: for the second line, condition on the different values N τ can take.

8 Exercise 2.3. (Merton s formula for European call prices under jump diffusion) Suppose now that the jumps are log-normally distributed: Show that C(S, t; K, T ) = where k=0 J i = e Y i, Y i N(α, β 2 ). (λτ) k ) e (Se λτ κτ+kα+ 1 2 kβ2 Φ(d 1,k ) Ke rτ Φ(d 2,k ), k! d 1,k = log(s/k) + (r + 1 2 σ2 κ)τ + k(α + β 2 ) σ2 τ + kβ 2, and d 2,k = log(s/k) + (r 1 2 σ2 κ)τ + kα σ2 τ + kβ 2, with τ = T t, and κ = λe(j 1) = λ(e α+ 1 2 β2 1). In practice, λτ would usually be small, and one only would take the first few terms of this series (e.g. first two). Hint: apply (16); exploit that SJ 1 J k e (r κ 1 2 σ2 )τ+σ(w T W t) = e (r κ 1 2 σ2 )τ+σ(w T W t)+y 1 + +Y k =: Se R k, with R k a normal random variable whose mean and variance are easily computed as sum of independent normals. To work out the expectations with the call-type pay-off, use that if S, K are positive constants, and if R N(a, b 2 ), then E ( max ( Se R K, 0 )) = Se a+ 1 2 b2 Φ(d 1 ) K Φ(d 2 ), where log(s/k) + a + b2 d 1 =, d 2 = log(s/k) + a = d + b, b b and Φ is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. (This can be shown by similar computations as the ones we used for establishing the Black and Scholes formula.)