Chapter 3. Elasticities. 3.1 Price elasticity of demand (PED) Price elasticity of demand. Microeconomics. Chapter 3 Elasticities 47

Similar documents
Price Elasticity of Demand

3.4 Price elasticity of supply (PES)

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 4 - ELASTICITY.

2011 Pearson Education. Elasticities of Demand and Supply: Today add elasticity and slope, cross elasticities

2011 Pearson Education. Elasticities of Demand and Supply: Today add elasticity and slope, cross elasticities

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

Elasticity and its Application

A scenario. Elasticity. Price Elasticity of Demand. Price Elasticity of Demand. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Elasticity and Its Applications. Copyright 2004 South-Western

What is Elasticity? Elasticity: shows how sensitive a change in quantity is to a change in price

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Elasticity. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Elasticity 1 / 32

File: Ch02, Chapter 2: Supply and Demand Analysis. Multiple Choice

Economics Elasticity. A scenario. Price Elasticity of Demand. Price Elasticity of Demand. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

Microeonomics. 5 this chapter, Elasticity and its Application. Elasticity. A scenario. look for the answers to these questions: N.

Elasticity and Its Application

ECON. CHAPTER Elasticity of. McEachern Micro. Demand and Supply. Designed by Amy McGuire, B-books, Ltd.

LECTURE 4: ELASTICITY

ALGEBRAIC REPRESENTATION

No books, notes, or other aids are permitted. You may, however, use an approved calculator. Do not turn to next pages until told to do so by examiner.

File: Ch02, Chapter 2: Supply and Demand Analysis. Multiple Choice

Elasticities of Demand and Supply CHAPTER 5

Elasticity. The Concept of Elasticity

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Full file at

Describing Supply and Demand: Elasticities

Lecture 3 ( 3): April 20 and 22, 2004 Demand, Supply, and Price Stiglitz: pp

is a concept that relates the responsiveness (or sensitivity) of one variable to a change in another variable. Elasticity of A with respect to B = %

CMA Part 2 Financial Decision Making

SOLUTIONS. ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Midterm Test # 1 LAST NAME FIRST NAME STUDENT NUMBER. University of Toronto June 22, 2006

Elasticity & Applications of Supply & Demand Analysis. UAPP693 Economics in the Public & Nonprofit Sectors Steven W. Peuquet, Ph.D.

GRAPHS IN ECONOMICS. Appendix. Key Concepts. Graphing Data

Econ 301 Summer 2003 Asinski

If it is important to you, you will find a way If not, you will find an excuse. Frank Banks

What is the most you would be willing to pay for the following items?

1 Supply and Demand. 1.1 Demand. Price. Quantity. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text.

Note 1: Indifference Curves, Budget Lines, and Demand Curves

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 1 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2, Question 1

EQ: What is Elasticity?

EQ: How Do I Calculate Elasticity?

Practice Problem Solutions for Exam 1

THE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

Week3: Elasticity and Its Applications. 17 th March 2014

Elasticity. McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Copyright 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Describing Supply and Demand: Elasticities

To download more slides, ebook, solutions and test bank, visit

Price, Income and Cross Elasticity

Introduction to Microeconomics AP/ECON C Test #2 (c)

Economics 101 Fall 2016 Answers to Homework #1 Due Thursday, September 29, 2016

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

CH 8. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Equalities. Equalities

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

UNIT 16 BREAK EVEN ANALYSIS

why how price quantity

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECON 100: INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS ROBERT GAZZALE, PHD PRACTICE PROBLEMS: ELASTICITY

2013 CH 11 sample questions

1) Refer to Figure 4-1. Arnold's marginal benefit from consuming the third burrito is A) $1.25. B) $1.50. C) $2.50. D) $6.00.

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Price. Quantity. Economics 101 Fall 2013 Homework 4 Due Tuesday, November 5, 2013

QOD #10 Elasticity. 1. Provide an example of something is greatly affected by price?

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

Concordia University Econ 201

Lecture # 6 Elasticity/Taxes

Homework #1 Microeconomics (I), Fall 2010 Due day: 7 th Oct., 2010

Unit 2: Supply, Demand, and Consumer Choice

11 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans1

This is Interest Rate Parity, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

CHAPTER 2 REVENUE OF THE FIRM

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 3 Production and Costs 3.1 PRODUCTION FUNCTION

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

a. Find the price elasticity of demand (4 points) b. Based on your calculation above, is demand elastic, inelastic, or unit elastic?

ECON 251 Exam 1 Pink Fall 2012

6/4/2009. Consumer Choice Using Utility Theory. 1 of of 39. In February 2006, Apple Computer sold its billionth song at its itunes music store.

Laugher Curve. Demand. Demand. The Law of Demand. The Law of Demand

PowerPoint Lecture Notes for Chapter 6: Principles of Economics 5 th edition, by N. Gregory Mankiw Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

Midterm 1 - Solutions

8 POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES. Chapter. Key Concepts. The Budget Line

1. You have an income of $40 to spend on two commodities. Commodity 1 costs $10 per unit and commodity 2 costs $5 per unit.

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis July 7, 2010 Instructor: John Parman. Midterm - Solutions

PBAF 516 YA Prof. Mark Long Practice Midterm Questions

1. [March 6] You have an income of $40 to spend on two commodities. Commodity 1 costs $10 per unit and commodity 2 costs $5 per unit.

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

3: Balance Equations

Section 7C Finding the Equation of a Line

Summer 2016 Microeconomics 2 ECON1201. Nicole Liu Z

University of Siegen

Chapter 2. The Basics of Supply and Demand. Why 1,000 Won? Who determined it? Qustion: Suppose you bought an apple for 1,000 Won.

Basic Concepts. MICROECONOMICS: deals with specific economic units and a detailed consideration of these individual units.

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester. ECON 101 Mid term Exam

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 1

Lecture 3: Tax incidence

Transcription:

Microeconomics Chapter 3 Elasticities Elasticity is a measure of the responsiveness of a variable to changes in price or any of the variable s determinants. In this chapter we will examine four kinds of elasticities, with numerous applications to important economic problems. 3.1 rice elasticity of demand (E) rice elasticity of demand Explain the concept of price elasticity of demand, understanding that it involves responsiveness of quantity demanded to a change in price, along a given demand curve. Understanding price elasticity of demand (E) According to the law of demand, there is a negative relationship between price and quantity demanded: the higher the price, the lower the quantity demanded, and vice versa, all other things equal. We now want to know by how much quantity responds to change in price. rice elasticity of demand (E) is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity of a good demanded to changes in its price. E is calculated along a given demand curve. In general, if there is a large responsiveness of quantity demanded, demand is referred to as being price elastic; if there is a small responsiveness, demand is price inelastic. The formula for E Calculate E using the following equation. percentage change in quantity demanded E = percentage change in price Suppose we are considering price elasticity of demand (E) for good X. The formula used to measure its E is: price elasticity of demand = E = The sign of E percentage change in quantity of good X demanded percentage change in price of good X If we abbreviate change in by the Greek letter Δ, this formula can be rewritten as: E = %Δ x %Δ x Simplifying, the above formula can be rewritten as: Δ x Δ x 1 x E = Δ x x 1 State that the E value is treated as if it were positive although its mathematical value is usually negative. Since price and quantity demanded are negatively (indirectly) related, the E is a negative number. For any percentage increase in price (a positive denominator), there results a percentage decrease in quantity demand (a negative numerator), leading to a negative E. Similarly, for a percentage price decrease the result will be a percentage price increase, again leading to a negative E. However, the common practice is to drop the minus sign and consider E as a positive number. (In mathematics this is called taking the absolute value.) This is done to avoid confusion when making comparisons between different values of E. Using positive numbers, we can say, for example, that a E of 3 is larger than a E of 2. (Had we been using the minus sign, 2 would be larger than 3.) = x Δ x x Chapter 3 Elasticities 47

The use of percentages Elasticity is measured in terms of percentages for two reasons: We need a measure of responsiveness that is independent of units. First, we want to be able to compare the responsiveness of quantity demanded of different goods; it makes little sense to compare units of oranges with units of computers or cars. Secondly, we want to be able to compare responsiveness across countries that have different currencies; an elasticity measured in terms of euros will not be comparable with an elasticity measured in yen or pounds. By computing changes in quantity and changes in price as percentages, we express them in common terms, thereby making it possible to compare responsiveness for different goods and across countries. It is meaningless to think of changes in prices or quantities in absolute terms (for example, a $15 increase in price or a 2 unit decrease in quantity) because this tells us nothing about the relative size of the change. For example, a $15 price increase means something very different for a good whose original price is $1 than for a good whose original price is $5. In the first case there is a 1 increase, and in the second there is a.3% increase. Using percentages to measure price and quantity changes allows us to put responsiveness into perspective. The same arguments apply to all other elasticities we will consider. Calculating E Calculate E between two designated points on a demand curve using the E equation above. We can now use the formula above to calculate E. Suppose consumers buy 6 V players when the price is $255 per unit, and they buy 5 V players when the price is $3. E = 6 5 5 255 3 3 = 1 5 45 3.2 = = 1.33 or 1.33.15 since we drop the minus sign. Therefore E for V players is 1.33. 1 Test your understanding 3.1 1 (a) Explain the meaning of price elasticity of demand. (b) Why do we say it measures responsiveness of quantity along a given demand curve? 2 Why do we treat E as if it were positive, even though it is usually negative? 3 It is observed that when the price of pizzas is $16 per pizza, 1 pizzas are sold; when the price falls to $12 per pizza, 12 pizzas are sold. Calculate price elasticity of demand. 4 A 1% increase in the price of a particular good gives rise to an 8% decrease in quantity bought. What is the price elasticity of demand? The range of values for E Explain, using diagrams and E values, the concepts of price elastic demand, price inelastic demand, unit elastic demand, perfectly elastic demand and perfectly inelastic demand. The value of E involves a comparison of two numbers: the percentage change in quantity demanded (the numerator in the E formula) and the percentage change in price (the denominator). This comparison yields several possible values and range of values for E. These are illustrated in Figure 3.1 and summarised in Table 3.1. 1 You may note that the value of this elasticity of demand depends on the choice of the initial price quantity combination. In the calculation above, this was taken to be 3, 5. If we had taken 255, 6 as the initial price quantity combination, we would get a E value of.94. (You could calculate this as an exercise.) This difficulty can be overcome by use of the midpoint formula : In the previous example, 1 E = 55 45 277.5 = 1.12, where 55 = (5 + 6) 2 (255 + 3) and 277.5 = 2 Δ x average x E =. Δ x i.e. we use the average of the two x values and the average of the two x values instead of the initial x and initial x. average x 48 Section 1: Microeconomics

emand is price inelastic when E < 1 (but greater than zero). The percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller than the percentage change in price, so the value of E is less than one; quantity demanded is relatively unresponsive to changes in price, and demand is price inelastic. Figure 3.1(a) illustrates price inelastic demand: the percentage change in quantity demanded (a decrease) is smaller than the percentage change in price (a 1% increase), therefore E is less than one. Value of E Classification Interpretation Frequently encountered cases < E < 1 (greater than zero and less than one) 1 < E < (greater than 1 and less than infinity) Special cases inelastic demand elastic demand quantity demanded is relatively unresponsive to price quantity demanded is relatively responsive to price E = 1 unit elastic demand percentage change in quantity demanded equals percentage change in price E = perfectly inelastic demand quantity demanded is completely unresponsive to price E = perfectly elastic demand quantity demanded is infinitely responsive to price Table 3.1 Characteristics of price elasticity of demand (a) rice inelastic demand: < E <1 Frequently encountered cases (b) rice elastic demand: 1 < E < 2 2 1 1% 1 2 1 2 1 Special cases 1% (c) Unit elastic demand: E = 1 (d) erfectly inelastic demand: E = (e) efectly elastic demand: E = 2 1 1 2 1 1 Figure 3.1 emand curves and E Chapter 3 Elasticities 49

emand is price elastic when E > 1 (but less than infinity). The percentage change in quantity demanded is larger than the percentage change in price, so the value of E is greater than one; quantity demanded is relatively responsive to price changes, and demand is price elastic. In Figure 3.1(b) the percentage change in quantity demanded ( 1%) is larger than the percentage change in price (), therefore E is greater than one. In addition, there are three special cases: emand is unit elastic when E = 1. The percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to the percentage change in price, so E is equal to one; demand is then unit elastic. Figure 3.1(c) shows a unit elastic demand curve, where the percentage change in quantity demanded ( ) is equal to the percentage change in price (). emand is perfectly inelastic when E =. The percentage change in quantity demanded is zero; there is no change in quantity demanded, which remains constant at 1 no matter what happens to price; E is then equal to zero and demand is perfectly inelastic. For example, a heroin addict s quantity of heroin demanded is unresponsive to changes in the price of heroin. Figure 3.1(d) shows that a perfectly inelastic demand curve is vertical. emand is perfectly elastic when E = infinity. When a change in price results in an infinitely large response in quantity demanded, demand is perfectly elastic. As shown in Figure 3.1(e) the perfectly elastic demand curve is horizontal. At price 1, consumers will buy any quantity that is available. If price falls, buyers will buy all they can (an infinitely large response); if there is an increase in price, quantity demanded drops to zero. This apparently strange kind of demand will be considered in Chapter 7 (at higher level). The numerical value of E can therefore vary from zero to infinity. In general, the larger the value of E, the greater the responsiveness of quantity demanded. E for most goods and services is greater than zero and less than infinite, and other than exactly one. The cases of unit elastic, perfectly inelastic and perfectly elastic demand are rarely encountered in practice; however, they have important applications in economic theory. Variable E and the straight-line demand curve versus the slope Explain why E varies along a straight line demand curve and is not represented by the slope of the demand curve. When E varies Along any downward-sloping, straight-line demand curve, the E varies (changes) as we move along the curve. This applies to all demand curves of the types shown in Figure 3.1 (a) and (b). It excludes unit elastic, perfectly inelastic and perfectly elastic demand curves (where E = 1, E = and E = infinity, respectively, and does not vary). We can see in Figure 3.2 that when price is low and quantity is high, demand is inelastic; as we move up the demand curve towards higher prices and lower quantities, demand becomes more and more elastic. The figure shows the E values along different parts of the demand curve (you will be asked to do the E calculations as an exercise see Test your understanding 3.2). The reason behind the changing E along a straight-line demand curve has to do with how E is calculated. At high prices and low quantities, the percentage change in is relatively large (since the denominator of Δ/ is small), while the percentage change in is relatively small (because the denominator of Δ/ is large). Therefore the value of E, given by a large percentage change in divided by a small percentage change in results in a large E (elastic demand). At low prices and high quantities the opposite holds. The value of E is ($) 5 45 4 35 3 25 2 15 1 5 f E = 4 e d elastic portion of demand curve E = 1 c 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 units of good A b inelastic portion of demand curve E =.25 a 9 1 Figure 3.2 Variability of E along a straight-line demand curve 5 Section 1: Microeconomics

given by a low percentage change in divided by a high percentage change in, resulting in a low E (elastic demand). On any downward-sloping, straight-line demand curve, demand is price-elastic at high prices and low quantities, and price-inelastic at low price and large quantities. At the midpoint of the demand curve, there is unit elastic demand. Therefore, the terms elastic and inelastic should not be used to refer to an entire demand curve (with the exception of the three special cases where E is constant throughout the entire demand curve). Instead, they should be used to refer to a portion of the demand curve that corresponds to a particular price or price range. The relationship between E and the slope (Higher level topic) The varying E along a straight-line demand curve should be contrasted with the slope, which is always constant along a straight line (see uantitative techniques chapter on the C-ROM, page 28). In the special case of demand (and supply) functions, whose corresponding curves plot the dependent variable on the horizontal axis (in contrast to mathematical convention), the slope is defined as Δ, or the Δ horizontal change between two points on the curve divided by the vertical change between the same two points. A comparison of the slope with E shows that the two should not be confused: slope of demand curve = Δ Δ Δ E = %Δ %Δ = = Δ Δ Δ = slope In these two expressions we can see why the slope is constant, while E varies along a straight-line demand curve. In a straight line, the ratio Δ, or the Δ slope, does not change between any pairs of points on the line. However, E is defined as the slope (which is constant) times, which clearly changes as we move along the demand curve, thus accounting for the changing E. The slope of the demand curve measures the responsiveness of quantity demanded to changes in price in absolute terms, while E measures the same responsiveness in percentage terms. E is far more useful as a measure of responsiveness for the reasons discussed on page 48. (See also the discussion in uantitative techniques chapter on the C- ROM, page 28.) E should not be confused with the slope of a demand curve. Whereas the slope is constant for a linear (straight-line) demand curve, E varies throughout its range. eterminants of price elasticity of demand Explain the determinants of E, including the number and closeness of substitutes, the degree of necessity, time and the proportion of income spent on the good. We will now consider the factors that determine whether the demand for a good is elastic or inelastic. Number and closeness of substitutes The more substitutes a good (or service) has, the more elastic is its demand. If the price of a good with many substitutes increases, consumers can switch to other substitute products, therefore resulting in a relatively large drop (large responsiveness) in quantity demanded. For example, there are many brands of toothpaste, which are close substitutes for each other. An increase in the price of one, with the prices of others constant will lead consumers to switch to the others; hence demand for a specific toothpaste brand is price elastic. If a good or service has few or no substitutes, then an increase in price will bring forth a small drop in quantity demanded. An increase in the price of petrol (gasoline) is likely to lead to a relatively small decrease in quantity demanded, because there are no close substitutes; therefore, demand for petrol is price inelastic. Also important is the closeness of substitutes. For example, Coca-Cola and epsi are much closer substitutes than Coca-Cola and orange juice; we say that Coca-Cola and epsi have greater substitutability. The closer two substitutes are to each other, the greater the responsiveness of quantity demanded to a change in the price of the substitute, hence the greater the E, because it is easier for the consumer to switch from one product to the other. A factor that affects the number of substitutes a good has is whether the good is defined broadly or narrowly. For example, fruit is a broad definition of a good if it is considered in relation to specific fruits such as oranges, apples, pears, and so on, which are narrowly defined. Note that a broad or narrow definition involves how goods are defined in relation to each other. If we had considered fruit in relation to Chapter 3 Elasticities 51

food, food is the broadly defined good, and specific foods such as fruits, vegetables, grains, fish, and so on, are narrowly defined. (Therefore, fruit is broadly defined in relation to specific fruits, and narrowly defined in relation to food.) The point here is that the narrower the definition of a good, the more the close substitutes and the more elastic the demand (compared with the broadly defined good). The demand for apples is more elastic than the demand for fruit, because of the availability of oranges, pears or other fruits that are close substitutes for apples. The demand for fruit is more elastic than the demand for food. Similarly, a Honda has a higher price elasticity of demand than all cars considered together. Necessities versus luxuries Necessities are goods or services we consider to be essential or necessary in our lives; we cannot do without them. Luxuries are not necessary or essential. The demand for necessities is less elastic than the demand for luxuries. For example, the demand for medications tends to be very inelastic because people s health or life depend on them; therefore, quantity demanded is not very responsive to changes in price. The demand for food is also inelastic, because people cannot live without it. On the other hand, the demand for diamond rings is elastic as most people view them as luxuries. In general, the more necessary is a good, the less elastic the demand. A special case of necessity is a consumer s addiction to a good. The greater the degree of addiction to a substance (alcohol, cigarettes, and so on), the more inelastic is the demand. A price increase will not bring forth a significant reduction in quantity demanded if one is severely addicted. Length of time The longer the time period in which a consumer makes a purchasing decision, the more elastic the demand. As time goes by, consumers have the opportunity to consider whether they really want the good, and to get information on the availability of alternatives to the good in question. For example, if there is an increase in the price of heating oil, consumers can do little to switch to other forms of heating in a short period of time, and therefore demand for heating oil tends to be inelastic over short periods. But as time goes by, they can switch to other heating systems, such as gas, or they can install better insulation, and demand for heating oil becomes more elastic. roportion of income spent on a good The larger the proportion of one s income needed to buy a good, the more elastic the demand. An item such as a pen takes up a very small proportion of one s income, whereas summer holidays take up a much larger proportion. For the same percentage increase in the price of pens and in the price of summer holidays, the response in quantity demanded is likely to be greater in the case of summer holidays than in the case of pens. Real world focus What happens when demand is highly price inelastic? A girl sells lemonade at a stand for 5 cents (= $.5) a cup. On a very hot day, the lemonade becomes even more popular, and the girl realises she can raise her price a little and still sell all her lemonade. One afternoon, a diabetic boy comes along asking for lemonade with extra sugar because his blood sugar has fallen to dangerously low levels. The girl sees an opportunity and increases her price by. The boy doesn t have enough money, but she tells him she will give him the lemonade right away provided he promises to run home afterward, get the money and return to pay her the full price. Having no choice, the boy agrees. Source: Adapted from Teymour Semnani, Free markets don t always do the right thing regarding health care in The eseret News, 15 November 29. Applying your skills 1 (a) What can you conclude about the boy s price elasticity of demand for sweet lemonade at that particular moment? (b) What determinant of E accounts for this? 2 What would have happened to the quantity of lemonade demanded if the other children were faced with a increase in its price? Explain in terms of their price elasticity of demand for lemonade. 52 Section 1: Microeconomics