Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios

Similar documents
Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios

Lifetime Portfolio Selection: A Simple Derivation

Asset Location and Allocation with. Multiple Risky Assets

Portfolio Choice with Capital Gain Taxation and the Limited Use of Losses

Non-qualified Annuities in After-tax Optimizations

Portfolio Choice with Capital Gain Taxation and the Limited Use of Losses

Portfolio Choice with Capital Gain Taxation and the Limited Use of Losses

Optimal Tax Timing with Asymmetric Long-Term/Short-Term. Capital Gains Tax

Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion

MODELLING OPTIMAL HEDGE RATIO IN THE PRESENCE OF FUNDING RISK

Dynamic Portfolio Allocation in Goals-Based Wealth Management

Tax management strategies with multiple risky assets $

Optimal Tax-Timing and Asset Allocation when Tax Rebates on Capital Losses are Limited

Online Appendix: Extensions

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Portfolio Choice with Capital Gain Taxation and the Limited Use of Losses

Asset-Liability Management

Characterization of the Optimum

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

The Diversification of Employee Stock Options

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples

Introduction Credit risk

MONTE CARLO BOUNDS FOR CALLABLE PRODUCTS WITH NON-ANALYTIC BREAK COSTS

Valuation of a New Class of Commodity-Linked Bonds with Partial Indexation Adjustments

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Common Misconceptions about "Beta" Hedging, Estimation and Horizon Effects 1

A Model for Tax Advantages of Portfolios with Many Assets

Dynamic Asset Allocation

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

From default probabilities to credit spreads: Credit risk models do explain market prices

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE

Managing the Uncertainty: An Approach to Private Equity Modeling

The Norwegian Government Pension Fund s potential for capturing illiquidity premiums

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

INTRODUCTION TO THE ECONOMICS AND MATHEMATICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS. Jakša Cvitanić and Fernando Zapatero

Some useful optimization problems in portfolio theory

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

induced by the Solvency II project

Optimal Capital Structure, Endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term Structure of Credit Spreads

Optimal Trade Execution: Mean Variance or Mean Quadratic Variation?

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Portfolio Optimization with Transaction Costs and Taxes. Weiwei Shen

STEX s valuation analysis, version 0.0

Monte-Carlo Estimations of the Downside Risk of Derivative Portfolios

The mathematical finance of Quants and backward stochastic differential equations

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

Annuity Decisions with Systematic Longevity Risk. Ralph Stevens

Evaluating the Black-Scholes option pricing model using hedging simulations

Portfolio Choice with Illiquid Assets

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

Discrete-Time Implementation of Continuous-Time Portfolio Strategies

Chapter 8 Statistical Intervals for a Single Sample

Statistics 13 Elementary Statistics

How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Average Portfolio Insurance Strategies

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Stock Repurchase with an Adaptive Reservation Price: A Study of the Greedy Policy

Rebalancing and Returns

Optimal Hedging of Option Portfolios with Transaction Costs

Continuous time Asset Pricing

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

Quantitative Risk Management

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Algorithmic Trading Session 12 Performance Analysis III Trade Frequency and Optimal Leverage. Oliver Steinki, CFA, FRM

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options

Robust Portfolio Decisions for Financial Institutions

Discounting a mean reverting cash flow

ENHANCING ACTIVE TAX-MANAGEMENT through the Realization of Capital Gains

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance

Enhancing Active Tax-Management Through the Realization of Capital Gains

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

The Pennsylvania State University. The Graduate School. Department of Industrial Engineering AMERICAN-ASIAN OPTION PRICING BASED ON MONTE CARLO

How good are Portfolio Insurance Strategies?

Effectiveness of CPPI Strategies under Discrete Time Trading

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs

Market Closure, Portfolio Selection, and Liquidity Premia

The accuracy of the escrowed dividend model on the value of European options on a stock paying discrete dividend

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk

Retirement Income TAX-EFFICIENT WITHDRAWAL STRATEGIES

Approximate methods for dynamic portfolio allocation under transaction costs

Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs

Math 623 (IOE 623), Winter 2008: Final exam

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money

Optimal Consumption and Investment with Transaction Costs and Multiple Risky Assets

Optimal Municipal Bond Portfolios for Dynamic Tax Management

The Returns and Risk of Dynamic Investment Strategies: A Simulation Comparison

Coming up Short: Managing Underfunded Portfolios in a LDI-ES Framework

Portability, salary and asset price risk: a continuous-time expected utility comparison of DB and DC pension plans

Liquidity and Risk Management

Transcription:

Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios Sanjiv R. Das & Daniel Ostrov 1 Santa Clara University @JOIM La Jolla, CA April 2015 1 Joint work with Dennis Yi Ding and Vincent Newell. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 1 / 49

Problem Overview Introduction An investor has a portfolio with a stock and cash position that can be traded periodically. The stock is subject to (very close to) the American taxation system. The portfolio has a given time horizon of T years. Basic question: What fraction, f, of the portfolio should be in stock? More specifically: What is the optimal static interval [f l, f u ] in which to dynamically maintain f over the portfolio s time horizon? Maintaining f within an interval has been repeatedly shown to be the optimal strategy in cases with transaction costs, no taxes, and continuous trading. See, for example, Shreve and Soner (1994); Whaley and Wilmott (1997); Leland (2000); Atkinson and Mokkhavesa (2002); Janacek and Shreve (2004); Rogers (2004); Goodman and Ostrov (2010); and Dai, Liu, and Zhong (2011). We will also consider an optimal dynamic interval where [f l, f u ] can change at time T 2. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 2 / 49

Introduction Outline 1. Introduction 2. The Model 3. Base Case: Results and Observations 4. Alterations to the base case: Parameter Changes 5. Alterations to the base case: Model Changes 6. Conclusions Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 3 / 49

Previous approaches Introduction 1. PDE and Bellman Equation approaches: Require using the average cost basis for capital gains. Dammon, Spatt, and Zhang (2001), Dammon, Spatt, and Zhang (2004), Gallmeyer, Kaniel, and Tompaidis (2006), and Tahar, Soner, and Touzi (2010). 2. Exact optimization with the full cost basis: Dybvig and Koo (1996) - Maximum of 4 trading periods. DeMiguel and Uppal (2005) - Maximum of 10 trading periods. 1% certainty equivalent advantage over average tax basis. Haugh, Iyengar, Wang (wp 2014) - Maximum of 20 assets with 20 periods using simulation and dual relaxation methods. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 4 / 49

Introduction Our approach New approach: Monte Carlo based optimization using 50,000 simulations of stock movement over T years. Advantages: 1. Uses the full cost basis. 2. We used over 400 trading periods. 3. Can accommodate many more of the features of the American tax code than were previously possible. 4. Can accommodate any stochastic process for the stock movement. 5. Can easily extend to incorporate new features such as transaction costs or multiple stocks. 6. Yields many new economic insights, allowing us to answer (or more fully answer) many questions. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 5 / 49

Introduction Some questions to be answered Define f = f l + f u (optimal interval s midpoint) 2 f = f u f l (optimal interval s width) 1. Is f higher in a taxable or tax free account? 2. Is the 5/25 rule of thumb for rebalancing (i.e., f =.10) justified? Or is continually rebalancing better (i.e., f = 0)? 3. How sensitive are f and f to changes in underlying parameters? Parameters: Stock and cash growth rates, Stock volatility, Investor risk aversion, Tax rates for capital losses and for capital gains, Portfolio size, Portfolio horizon T, and Trading period length. E.g.: Should you increase or decrease f if the capital gains rate increases? 4. How do f and f change if the model changes? Model changes: Introducing transaction costs, Investor being alive vs. deceased at time T, Allowing [f l, f u ] to change at time T /2, Using the average vs. full cost basis. E.g.: How big of an advantage does using the full cost basis give over the average tax basis? Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 6 / 49

The Model Assumptions and Notation: Assets 1. Two assets: risky stock and risk free cash. Each can be bought and sold in any quantity, including non-integer amounts with, for the moment, negligible transaction costs. Trading can only occur every h years. (E.g., h = 0.25 for quarterly trading.) 2. Stock: Stock evolves by geometric Brownian motion with a constant expected return, µ, and a constant volatility, σ. For simplicity, we do not consider dividends. 3. Cash: The tax-free (or post-tax) continuously compounded interest rate for the cash position, r, is assumed to be constant. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 7 / 49

The Model Assumptions and Notation: Taxes 1. Tax Rate: We assume the capital loss tax rate, τ l, and the capital gains tax rate, τ g, are constants that apply to both long term and short term gains/losses. 2. Wash Sales: We assume the presence of other stocks or stock indexes in our market with essentially the same value of µ and σ, so we can bypass wash sale rules. Given this, it is always optimal to immediately sell and rebuy any stock with losses. (Constantinides 1983 or Ostrov and Wong 2011). 3. Capital loss limits: No more than $3000 in net losses can be claimed at the end of each year. Net losses in excess of this amount are carried over to subsequent years. 4. Portfolio liquidation at time T : If the investor is alive, all capital gains are taxed. If the investor is deceased, all capital gains are forgiven and any remaining carried over capital losses are lost. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 8 / 49

The Model Optimization Goal and Trading Strategy Optimization Goal: Determine the values for (1) the lower bound f l 0, (2) the upper bound f u 1, and (3) initial stock fraction f l f init f u, that maximize the expected utility of the portfolio worth at a final liquidation time, T, using the following trading strategy at each trading period: Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 9 / 49

The Model Optimization Goal and Trading Strategy Optimization Goal: Determine the values for (1) the lower bound f l 0, (2) the upper bound f u 1, and (3) initial stock fraction f l f init f u, that maximize the expected utility of the portfolio worth at a final liquidation time, T, using the following trading strategy at each trading period: 1. First: Sell and repurchase any stock with a loss. This generates money via a tax deduction. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 9 / 49

The Model Optimization Goal and Trading Strategy Optimization Goal: Determine the values for (1) the lower bound f l 0, (2) the upper bound f u 1, and (3) initial stock fraction f l f init f u, that maximize the expected utility of the portfolio worth at a final liquidation time, T, using the following trading strategy at each trading period: 1. First: Sell and repurchase any stock with a loss. This generates money via a tax deduction. 2. Second: If the portfolio s stock fraction f < f l, buy stock to raise fraction to f l. Keep track of the cost basis for each purchase. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 9 / 49

The Model Optimization Goal and Trading Strategy Optimization Goal: Determine the values for (1) the lower bound f l 0, (2) the upper bound f u 1, and (3) initial stock fraction f l f init f u, that maximize the expected utility of the portfolio worth at a final liquidation time, T, using the following trading strategy at each trading period: 1. First: Sell and repurchase any stock with a loss. This generates money via a tax deduction. 2. Second: If the portfolio s stock fraction f < f l, buy stock to raise fraction to f l. Keep track of the cost basis for each purchase. If the portfolio s stock fraction f > f u, sell stock to lower fraction to f u. Sell stock with the highest basis to minimize immediate capital gains, which means LIFO in our model. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 9 / 49

The Model Utility Power law utility function: U(W T ) = (W T ) 1 α 1 α, where α is the coefficient of relative risk aversion and W T is the portfolio s worth after liquidation at time T. In the case of no taxes like a Roth IRA: Optimal strategy (Merton (1992)) is f = f Merton where f Merton = µ r α σ 2. That is, f l = f init = f u = f Merton (or, equivalently, f = f Merton and f = 0). Note that f is constant in time and does not depend on the portfolio s worth. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 10 / 49

Simulation Algorithm The Model 1. For any given set of (f l, f u, f init ), the expected utility is approximated by the average utility over 50,000 Monte Carlo runs for the stock price evolution. This expected utility estimator is programmed in C, compiled and linked to be callable from the R programming language. 2. The optimization is run using a constrained optimizer in R, under Ubuntu Linux, for the three variables, f l, f u, and f init, under the restriction: 0 f l f init f u 1. 3. We reran this using different sets of 50,000 simulations to check for consistency in the optimal values determined for f l, f u, and f init. 4. The effect of varying f init is quite small. Therefore, we only present the results for f l and f u. Generally, we will express f l and f u using f = f l + f u and 2 f = f u f l. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 11 / 49

Base Case: Results and Observations Base Case Parameter Values We will use the following base case parameter values: the stock growth rate, µ = 7% = 0.07 (per annum) the risk free rate, r = 3% = 0.03 (per annum) the stock volatility, σ = 20% = 0.20 (per annum) the risk aversion parameter, α = 1.5 in our utility function the tax rate on losses, τ l = 28% = 0.28 the tax rate on gains, τ g = 15% = 0.15 the initial portfolio value, W 0 = $100, 000 the time horizon before portfolio liquidation, T = 40 years quarterly rebalancing, h = 0.25 years Later, we will experiment will alterations to each of these nine parameters. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 12 / 49

Base Case: Results and Observations Base Case Results: Roth vs. Taxable For this base case: No tax (Roth IRA): f = f Merton = µ r α σ 2 = 2 3 f = 0. Taxable account (investor alive at T ): f = 0.71 f = 0. Q1: Is f higher in a taxable or tax free account? Here, we see that it s higher in the taxable account. Why? Not because Roth cash is shielded from tax: The interest rate r is tax-free in both scenarios. If it weren t, f would be even higher than 0.71. It s because the capital loss rate, τ l = 0.28, is greater than the capital gain rate, τ g = 0.15! Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 13 / 49

Base Case: Results and Observations Base Case Results: Investor lives vs. dies If the investor dies when the portfolio is liquidated at time T = 40 years, all final capital gains are forgiven: Taxable account (investor alive at T ): f = 0.71 f = 0. Taxable account (investor dies at T ): f = 0.76 f = 0.17. 1. Forgiving capital gains makes stock more desirable, so f increases. 2. Increasing f reduces the number of transactions, which generally generates more capital gains at time T to be forgiven. Even though living or dying at time T only affects the tax treatment at time T, it has a considerable effect on optimal long term investing strategy, especially on the optimal f. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 14 / 49

Base Case: Results and Observations Influences on the Optimal Interval Width f Factors that affect the size of the optimal interval f = f u f l : 1. Two factors that push f to be bigger: The bigger f is, the more capital gains are deferred, which is advantageous even if the investor is alive and pays capital gains at the liquidation time T. If the investor is deceased at T, then the bigger f is, the more gains are likely to be forgiven at time T. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 15 / 49

Base Case: Results and Observations Influences on the Optimal Interval Width f Factors that affect the size of the optimal interval f = f u f l : 1. Two factors that push f to be bigger: The bigger f is, the more capital gains are deferred, which is advantageous even if the investor is alive and pays capital gains at the liquidation time T. If the investor is deceased at T, then the bigger f is, the more gains are likely to be forgiven at time T. 2. Two factors that push f to be smaller: The smaller f is, the closer we can keep the portfolio at or near the stock fraction that optimizes the expected utility. The smaller f is, the more often we rebalance and the more likely we are to have losses, allowing us to take advantage of the fact that τ l > τ g in current American tax law. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 15 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Effect of Parameter Changes We next examine the sensitivity of the optimal stock fraction range, [f l, f u ], or, equivalently, f and f to varying the nine base case parameter values, one at a time. We will work with the case where the investor dies at time T, since f > 0 in this case, permitting us to see the effect on f of changing parameters. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 16 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Stock Growth Rate from µ = 0.07 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 17 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Cash Growth Rate from r = 0.03 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 18 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Constant risk premium µ r = 0.04 What if we increase both µ and r at the same rate? Were there no taxes, there would be no change: f Merton = µ r α σ 2 = 2 3 What happens when there are taxes? Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 19 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying µ, while holding µ r = 0.04 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 20 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Comments on constant risk premia µ r Why are there changes in the taxable case? As µ increases there are more gains and fewer losses, which......reduces the ability to take advantage of the fact that τ l > τ g....makes it more advantageous to put off realizing gains. Therefore, we see that f increases due to both of these effects. f decreases at first because of the decreased advantage of τ l > τ g, then increases as the growth in forgiven gains at death outweigh this factor. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 21 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Stock Volatility from σ = 0.20 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 22 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Risk Aversion from α = 1.5 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 23 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Comments on Risk and Aversion 1. No surprise that f decreases in both of these cases. 2. It is interesting that the effect of σ on f is so small. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 24 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Capital loss rate τ l If the capital loss rate, τ l, increases, should you increase or decrease f? Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 25 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Capital loss rate τ l If the capital loss rate, τ l, increases, should you increase or decrease f? Increase f : As the capital loss tax rate, τ l, increases, stock becomes more desirable, so the stock fraction, f, should increase. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 25 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Capital loss rate τ l If the capital loss rate, τ l, increases, should you increase or decrease f? Increase f : As the capital loss tax rate, τ l, increases, stock becomes more desirable, so the stock fraction, f, should increase. Also decrease f to reset the cost basis more often, thereby generating more losses. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 25 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Capital Loss tax rate from τ l = 0.28 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 26 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Capital gains rate τ g If the capital gains rate, τ g, increases, should you increase or decrease f? Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 27 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Capital gains rate τ g If the capital gains rate, τ g, increases, should you increase or decrease f? Decrease f : As the capital gains tax rate, τ g, increases, stock becomes less desirable, so the stock fraction, f, should decrease. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 27 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Capital gains rate τ g If the capital gains rate, τ g, increases, should you increase or decrease f? Decrease f : As the capital gains tax rate, τ g, increases, stock becomes less desirable, so the stock fraction, f, should decrease. Right? Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 27 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Capital gains rate τ g If the capital gains rate, τ g, increases, should you increase or decrease f? Decrease f : As the capital gains tax rate, τ g, increases, stock becomes less desirable, so the stock fraction, f, should decrease. Right? Wrong! Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 27 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Capital Gains tax rate from τ g = 0.15 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 28 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Comments on τ g Why? 1. Intuition: If f = 1, we have no capital gains. That is, high f means low capital gains in this extreme case. 2. More specifically: Suppose we have a portfolio with no stock volatility, a total worth of one dollar, and a stock fraction f. Our strategy is to annually rebalance the portfolio again to the stock fraction f. After a year, rebalancing generates (µ r)f (1 f ) dollars of capital gains. This parabolic capital gains function equals 0 at f = 0, increases to its maximum value at f = 1 2, and then decreases back to 0 at f = 1. So, if f > 1 2, then increasing f decreases capital gains. Not surprising: As τ g increases, f increases to reduce realizing capital gains. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 29 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Initial Portfolio Worth, W 0 For the case of no taxes: f Merton = µ r α σ 2. That is, there is no dependence on W 0. Were tax policy strictly dictated by proportional factors like τ g and τ l, the optimal strategy with taxes would be also be independent of W 0. However, the $3000 limit on annual claimed losses is not a proportional factor. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 30 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Initial Portfolio Worth from W 0 = $100, 000 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 31 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Comments on W 0 As W 0 increases, there is a mild decline in f due to the fact that the losses, as a proportion, become less useful as W 0 increases. Also, f increases, since creating losses becomes less useful. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 32 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Portfolio Horizon from T = 40 years Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 33 / 49

Comments on T Results for Parameter Changes 1. Initially, f l and f u (and therefore f ) increase since the advantage of deferring/forgiving gains grows as T grows. 2. Then f u decreases. Why? If f u = 1, we never sell stock with a gain. In this case, the bigger T is, the more likely f is to drift into the high end of the [f l, 1] interval. This portfolio has too much risk so reduce f u. If the stock price falls, the portfolio will do even worse, since stock is not sold when it reaches an f u < 1, eliminating the tax loss option. This greater wealth disparity over longer time horizons is penalized by the concavity of the utility function, eventually forcing f u to be reduced as T increases. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 34 / 49

Results for Parameter Changes Varying the Rebalancing Period from h = 0.25 (quarterly) Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 35 / 49

Comments on h Results for Parameter Changes 1. We see a slight increase in f as h grows, but the increase is small. The frequency of rebalancing is not a huge factor in the optimal strategy. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 36 / 49

Changes to the Model Results for Model Changes Our model is quite flexible. We next consider the effects of each of four different changes to our basic model: 1. We incorporate proportional transaction costs for buying or selling stock. 2. The investor is alive, instead of deceased, at the liquidation time T, so there are capital gains on the liquidated stock. 3. We allow the optimal stock fraction range, [f l, f u ], to change values when the portfolio is halfway to liquidation (i.e., at T 2 = 20 years), instead of remaining constant. 4. We use the average cost basis instead of the full cost basis, which allows us to quantitatively measure of the suboptimality generated by the average cost basis. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 37 / 49

Results for Model Changes Proportional Transaction Costs Define e to be the proportion lost in transactions. That is, $1 of cash buys $(1 e) worth of stock. $1 worth of stock can be sold for $(1 e) of cash. We still sell and repurchase any stock with a loss, even though this may no longer be optimal due to the transactions costs generated. Expectation: As e increases, f will increase to reduce the number of transactions. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 38 / 49

Results for Model Changes Varying the Transaction Costs from e = 0 Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 39 / 49

Results for Model Changes Effect of being alive vs. deceased at time T Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 40 / 49

Results for Model Changes Comments on being alive at time T Observations Even though being alive vs. deceased only affects the taxation rules at time T, the effects on the long term optimal strategy can be drastic! Note that these difference do not vanish as T grows. Only for the case of being alive: If f = 0 anywhere, as we see here, it is not surprising to see it remain zero for all T and for f to be constant for all T. You don t expect this necessarily in the case of being deceased. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 41 / 49

Results for Model Changes Rebalance Region changes at T 2. (Dashed = Years 20 40) Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 42 / 49

Results for Model Changes Comments on time-dependent strategy Optimize over five variables instead of three: f init (the initial stock fraction), f l and f u for years 0 20, and f l and f u for years 20 40. When the investor is deceased, f increases in years 20 40 to take advantage of the forgiven gains at T = 40 years. When the investor is alive, f decreases a little in years 20 40, due to the inability to defer capital gains when they are forced to be realized during liquidation at T = 40 years. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 43 / 49

Average cost basis Results for Model Changes We simplified the model to use the average costs basis instead of the full cost basis. We then compared the average cost basis results to the full cost basis results over each data point in each of the previous nine cases where we shifted a model parameter. The results for shifting one these parameters, W 0, is on the next slide. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 44 / 49

Results for Model Changes Average cost basis vs Full cost basis Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 45 / 49

Results for Model Changes Comments on tax basis Over all 9 parameter shifts: f : little change between average and full cost basis. f : shrinks in the full cost basis case by, on average, 6 percentage points. (Maximum in the data: 18.6 percentage points.) The shrunken f makes it more likely to generate losses from the high cost basis positions. But how much worse does the average cost basis case do compared to the full cost basis case? Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 46 / 49

Results for Model Changes Certainty Equivalent advantage Deceased vs. alive: Over the shifting nine parameters, being deceased has, on average, a 10% certainty equivalent advantage over being alive. That is, initially having $1.00 invested with the capital gains forgiven at time T is as desirable to the investor as initially having $1.10 and having to pay all capital gains taxes at time T. (The maximum certainty equivalent advantage in the data: 21.2%.) By comparison: Using the full cost basis has, on average, a 0.27% certainty equivalent advantage (with a maximum certainty equivalent advantage in the data of 1.12%). If the investor is alive, the average is 0.65% (with a maximum of 1.73%). Recall DeMiguel and Uppal (2005) found a 1% certainty equivalent advantage over average tax basis using 10 trading periods. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 47 / 49

Conclusions Results Our Monte Carlo method yields a number of insights for investors using a taxable account: 1. Rebalancing rules such as the 5/25 rule are often not optimal, and should be used with caveats. 2. The frequency of rebalancing has little influence on the optimal strategy. Using a continuous time model vs. a discrete time model makes little difference. 3. Using the average cost basis vs. the full cost basis makes little difference. This justifies the use of the average cost basis needed in Bellman equation approaches. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 48 / 49

Counter-Intuitive Results Conclusions A number of our conclusions are surprising: 1. The optimal f is often higher for taxable accounts than for tax-free accounts like the Roth IRA since τ l > τ g. 2. If the capital gains tax rate increases, then the fraction of the portfolio in stock, should be raised, not lowered. 3. Tax effects that only apply at liquidation can have a considerable effect on the optimal trading strategy, even though the strategy applies throughout the portfolio s lifetime from year 0 to year T. This effect does not dissipate as T. But in contrast, the choice of f init, the initial value of f [f l, f u ], has almost no effect on the performance of the portfolio, even when T is as small as 5 years. Das and Ostrov (Santa Clara University) Efficient Rebalancing of Taxable Portfolios JOIM 2015 49 / 49