Commentary: The Role of Demand Management Policies in Reducing Unemployment

Similar documents
OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

Issue Brief for Congress

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

Ways to increase employment

Basic information. Tax-to-GDP ratio Date: 29 November 2010

Chapter 12 Government and Fiscal Policy

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government?

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

Monetary Union: Benefits, Costs and a Better Alternative

Working Group Social Protection statistics

Sources. * (Economist) mid 1998 **1992, Manufacturing. (US Bur. Lab. Stats, Washington DC) Total: 1990 (US Bur. Lab. Stats, Washington DC);

Basic information. Tax-to-GDP ratio Date: 24 October 2012

IRELAND NEEDS A WAGE INCREASE

Is the Western Welfare State Still Sustainable?

OECD III: EMU. Gavin Cameron Lady Margaret Hall. Michaelmas Term 2004

Investing for our Future Welfare. Peter Whiteford, ANU

WikiLeaks Document Release

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland

Commentary: Macroeconomic Policy and Long-Run Growth

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

Research US Further downgrade of US debt likely in 2012

Swedish Fiscal Policy. Martin Flodén, Laura Hartman, Erik Höglin, Eva Oscarsson and Helena Svaleryd Meeting with IMF 3 June 2010

In 2008 gross expenditure on social protection in EU-27 accounted for 26.4 % of GDP

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

The Architectural Profession in Europe 2012

Aggregate demand &long-run unemployment L. Ball 1999

Is Government the Problem or the Solution to U.S. Labor Market Challenges?

Basic Income as a policy option: Can it add up?

Distributional Implications of the Welfare State

A NOTE ON PUBLIC SPENDING EFFICIENCY

Labor Market Protections and Unemployment: Does the IMF Have a Case? Dean Baker and John Schmitt 1. November 3, 2003

The intergenerational divide in Europe. Guntram Wolff

Statistical Annex ANNEX

EUROPA - Press Releases - Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax...of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

OECD THEMATIC FOLLOW-UP REVIEW OF POLICIES TO IMPROVE LABOUR MARKET PROSPECTS FOR OLDER WORKERS. NORWAY (situation mid-2012)

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

The Outlook for the U.S. Economy and the Policies of the New President

THE NEED FOR MORE SOCIAL SECURITY AND SECURE PENSIONS

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

Statistical Annex. Sources and definitions

V. MAKING WORK PAY. The economic situation of persons with low skills

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 8. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

TAX POLICY: RECENT TRENDS AND REFORMS IN OECD COUNTRIES FOREWORD

Cross-country risk-sharing in the EMU:

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

Aviation Economics & Finance

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15-64 years)

Unemployment and the Labor Market

European Investment Fund Venture Capital Portfolio. Performance EIF own resources Vintage and Team Location As at 30/06/17

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

Assessing Developments and Prospects in the Australian Welfare State

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15 64 years)

DICE REPORTS* WORK LOST DUE TO ILLNESS AN INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON. DICE Reports

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries

REGULATION, UNIONS, ANDLABOR MARKETS

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017

This DataWatch provides current information on health spending

THE GROSS AND NET RATES OF REVENUES REPLACEMENT WITHIN THE RETIRING PENSIONS

Taxation trends in the European Union Further increase in VAT rates in 2012 Corporate and top personal income tax rates inch up after long decline

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 17 European Monetary Unification and the Euro

T5-Europe The Jus Semper Global Alliance 01/09/16 1 6

3 Labour Costs. Cost of Employing Labour Across Advanced EU Economies (EU15) Indicator 3.1a

3 Labour Costs. Cost of Employing Labour Across Advanced EU Economies (EU15) Indicator 3.1a

SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet

Rethinking Macro Policy II

15 th. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson. First page. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson

The Net Worth of Irish Households An Update

How Tax Reform Can Address America s Diminishing Investment and Economic Growth

STATISTICS IN FOCUS Economy and finance

International comparison of poverty amongst the elderly

Fiscal rules in Lithuania

Quarterly Financial Accounts Household net worth reaches new peak in Q Irish Household Net Worth

Development Assistance for HealTH

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people

May 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.9 bn euro 3.8 bn euro deficit for EU27

3 Lower interest rates and sectoral changes in interest income

The welfare state in the US and Europe: why so different?

Commentary: Long-Term Tendencies in Budget Deficits and Debt

Tax Working Group Information Release. Release Document. September taxworkingroup.govt.nz/key-documents

DESIGNING GOOD TAX POLICY: A PRIMER

Executive Summary. The Transatlantic Economy Annual Survey of Jobs, Trade and Investment between the United States and Europe

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

First estimate for 2011 Euro area external trade deficit 7.7 bn euro bn euro deficit for EU27

Chartbook of International Labor Comparisons: The Americas, Asia/Pacific, Europe

STAT/12/ October Household saving rate fell in the euro area and remained stable in the EU27. Household saving rate (seasonally adjusted)

Maintaining Adequate Protection in a Fiscally Constrained Environment Measuring the efficiency of social protection systems

Trust and Fertility Dynamics. Arnstein Aassve, Università Bocconi Francesco C. Billari, University of Oxford Léa Pessin, Universitat Pompeu Fabra

Swedish Lessons: How Important are ICT and R&D to Economic Growth? Paper prepared for the 34 th IARIW General Conference, Dresden, Aug 21-27, 2016

Fiscal Policy in Japan

10% 10% 15% 15% Caseload: WE. 15% Caseload: SS 10% 10% 15%

On the Structure of EU Financial System. by S. E. G. Lolos. Contents 1

June 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 14.9 bn euro 0.4 bn euro surplus for EU27

The Paradox of Thrift: Lose weight by eating more

Productivity and Sustainable Consumption in OECD Countries:

Transcription:

Commentary: The Role of Demand Management Policies in Reducing Unemployment Welfare State Unemployment: A Comment Allan H. Meltzer Charles Bean has written an informative discussion of unemployment that brings to a larger audience some parts of his comprehensive discussion of European unemployment (Bean, 1994). His current paper also discusses the role that policy might take to reduce unemployment. I will put policy issues aside initially to concentrate on the causes of unemployment. I begin by stating and commenting on four main points about the causes of unemployment that I draw from his work, particularly his survey paper. Why European unemployment rose First, most of the increase in unemployment within the European Union is on the supply side. Chart 1 in Bean's conference paper, and his earlier survey paper (1994, Figure 2), show that the steady-state unemployment rate rose from less than 2'/2 percent in the late 1960s to about 10 percent twenty years later. Bean's chart, reproduced as Chart 1, shows that the unemployment rate at any rate of inflation is higher in all countries but, outside the European Community (EC), the increases are modest. The rise in the EC is almost a constant rate of increase over a fifteen-year period. Since the rise in the unemployment

Allan H. Meltzer Chart 1 Unemployment and Inflation 20.0 Bean: European Unemployment: A Survey United States 0.0 ' I I I I 0.0 2.5 5.O 7.5 10.0 12.5 Unemployment Rate (%) 20.0 17.5 - - 15.0-12.5-22 $ 10.0.- 0 1974 Non-EC Europe 5.0 1992 0.0 0.0 2.5 5.0 7.5 10.0 12.5 Unemployment Rate (%)

Commentary Chart E Unemployment an&.inflation continued 0.0 0.0 2.5 5.O 7.5 10.0 12.5 Unemployment Rate (%) I I 4 I I h a2 a-, 20.0 17.5-15.0-12.5-2 10.0- E:.- 0 ;;j 7.5 - % " 5.0 1974-1978 1969 2.5-1990 1986 9 I I I 0.0 0.0 2.5 5.O 7.5. 10.0 12.5 Unemployment Rate (%)

158 Allan H. Meltzer rate is mainly on the supply side, it is not "Keynesian unemployment." I suggest that a better name is "welfare state unemployment." A distinguishing difference between welfare state and Keynesian unemployment is that the former, unlike the latter, cannot be reduced permanently by policies that increase aggregate demand. Welfare state unemployment raises the natural rate of unemployment. Bean's (1994, p. 575) survey suggests that the natural rate has increased in the last twenty years in the United States, Europe outside the EC, Japan, and in the EC. The increase in the rate for the EC, however, is orders of magnitude greater than in the other regions. I concentrate on this long-term rise. Second, cyclical fluctuations in aggregate demand play a much smaller role. Bean's data suggest that, at its worst in the mid-1980s, cyclical unemployment was 2% percent, so the unemployment rate, in the EC or European Union (EU), would have been less than 5 percent instead of more than 10 percent had welfare state or supplyside unemployment remained at the late 1960s level. Third, Bean concludes that there is no accepted explanation of the rise in European unemployment. His survey suggests that economists have worked hard investigating many plausible explanations without reaching a firm conclusion. The explanations include the oil price shocks, changes in the terms of trade, slower productivity growth, higher and longer-lasting unemployment benefits, and minimum wages. Some of these explanations are incomplete as they stand. The lasting effects of productivity growth, oil shocks, and changes in the terms of trade should be on real wages, not unemployment, and any effect of the oil shocks should have reversed when real oil prices fell. Other, more inventive economists, have proposed fanciful explanations of persistence or, as some prefer, hysteresis. In one popular version, workers are said to lose their skills when they remain unemployed. Such explanations neglect some facts. Much of the rise in unemployment is not the result of employed workers losing jobs. Unemployment in the EU is heavily concentrated among new entrants. In Bean's words (1994, p. 576): "The high levels of unemployment in

Commentary 159 the European Community are thus associated primarily with the reduction in the probability of finding a job, rather than an increased likelihood of losing one." Further, to reach the remarkably low unemployment rates of the 1950s and 1960s, the labor force absorbed the generation that experienced the depression of the 1930s and the war in the 1940s. This generation had no problem finding and keeping jobs in the 1950s and 1960s despite a lengthy absence from the labor force. Fourth, Bean's (1994) survey suggests that most of the research on the role of the welfare state has concentrated on unemployment benefits and taxation. He dismisses these policies as an explanation of an increased steady-state unemployment rate. Bean recognizes (1994, pp. 592 and 602) that the duration of unemployment benefits is indefinitely long in several EC countries that now have high unemployment rates, whereas the duration of benefits is limited in the Nordic countries (and the United States) where unemployment rates rose much less in the 1980s.l He dismisses any long-term effect of taxes and permanent benefits by arguing that the two should be offsetting on an individual's choice of labor and leisure. His argument is that leisure depends on permanent income. Higher taxes reduce permanent income but the higher benefits restore the loss. In Bean's model, the permanent effects on unemployment cancel (1994, p. 589). I believe that the error in this argument is the fallacy of aggregation. Taxes on earned income or labor income (whether assessed on employers or employees) are paid by those who work. Unemployment benefits are paid to those who are idle. Hence work or effort is discouraged and leisure or idleness is encouraged. Or, workers move into the underground economy. Permanent benefits that cannot be taken away (to use a now familiar phrase) have a double effect on the unemployment rate if paid for by taxes on earned or labor income. Far from canceling, the two effects are reinforcing. Burda (1988, p. 407) studied the relation between the duration of unemployment benefits and the proportion of the unemployed out of work for six months or longer. Chart 2 reproduces his data. The correlation between long-term unemployment and duration of benefits

I60 Allan H. Melrzer Chart 2 Long-term Unemployment Rates and the Level @ of Unemployment Insurance in 1985 90 tz$ 58 80-4 E w 70-3 5; 60-6% 50- Ex Ea 40- g; Cr,g 30- e* F. IRL GB*. B.E ' NL ZZ 20- N *us 8" a 10, I I I, I 2,000 4,000 6,000 8,000 Unemployment benefit (adjusted percent-weeks) Note: A = Austria, B = Belgium, D = West Germany, E = Spain, F = France, GB = Great Britain, IRL = Ireland, J = Japan, N =Norway, NL = Netherlands, S = Sweden, SF = Finland, US = United States. a..s SF is 0.75 for 1985 based on across-section of Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries. At the time, duration of. benefits was unlimited in the United Kingdom, Belgium, the Netherlands, Germany, and Spain, and two and one-half years in France, compared to twenty-one and one-half weeks in Switzerland, thirty weeks in Austria, and thirty-four weeks in the United States. These differences help to explain the differences in unemployment rates and the duration of unemployment in the EC compared to non-ec Europe and the United States. Permanent unemployment benefits and taxes on labor income are not the whole story. They are only one of the contributions of the welfare state to unemployment. Role of the welfare state Three features of the welfare state are important for the steady-state unemployment rate. To have a significant effect on measured unemployment, benefits must be (1) comprehensive, (2) independent of the 'D

Commentary 161 amount of work performed, and (3) permanent or of long duration. Not all benefits are of this kind, so correlations of tax rates or transfer payments are not likely to be relevant or revealing. At least since Burda's (1988) study, the duration of benefits has been recognized as important in the analysis of unemployment compensation. Bean's survey brings this work up to date. Duration of benefits explains part of the difference in measured unemployment rates within Europe or between the EC and the United States. Less attention has been paid to other aspects of the welfare state. Many studies of the response of unemployment to the welfare state concentrate on the effect of taxes. Taxes distort the individual's labor-leisure tradeoff and increase the measured unemployment rate. This effect is one of many distortions but, if benefits are not comprehensive and permanent, the effect appears to be relatively small. Analysis of the effect of a negative income tax and in-kind benefits suggests why the permanent, comprehensive benefits of modern welfare states distort labor-leisure choices and increase measured unemployment rates (Meltzer and Richard, 1985). Decisions to work are less affected if benefits are not comprehensive. For example, giving food stamps, housing allowances, or other in-kind transfers reduces employment less than an equivalent payment of cash. Beneficiaries must work to purchase the goods and services not provided by the welfare state. A cash equivalent payment, therefore, reduces the incentive to work. The more comprehensive and durable the benefits, and the more they are independent of labor force participation, the larger is the reduction in employment. The extreme case is a cash transfer, or negative income tax, paid permanently as an entitlement. The effect is diluted if benefits can be sold, but housing allowances, health care, and education are difficult to sell. The United States has housing allowances, food stamps, and some medical care, but cash payments for welfare recipients are small relative to the average wage, and unemployment benefits are not permanent. In countries with permanent unemployment benefits that are a large share of the average wage, the unemployed also receive a variety of in-kind transfers independent of their work history. Health care, housing allowances, and schooling for children supplement the

permanent cash payment. Studies that neglect these differences in welfare state benefits are likely to mismeasure the role of the welfare state in reducing labor force participation and increasing the equilibrium unemployment rate. This is particularly true in some European countries where unemployment has much lower turnover than in the United States. Bean (1994, Table 2) reports that in 1988 long-term unemployment was 55 percent of total unemployment in the EC, and 7 percent in the United States. Sweden illustrates some of the problems in assessing the role of a welfare state. Sweden has a comprehensive welfare state on most measures. Cash benefits to the unemployed, however, are paid for less than one year. Training and retraining programs, and special programs for disabled workers, absorbed between 1 '/z to 2% percent of the labor force from 1985 to 1990. This is close to the share of the labor force that is reported as unemployed, so reported unemployment rates were understated relative to countries with smaller training programs.2 The Swedish example is one reason for mismeasurement of unemployment rates. A more widespread problem is the difference in government hiring or overmanning in state-owned firms. Two frequent criticisms of this line of reasoning are that the welfare state antedates the rise in unemployment rates, and some welfare states have not experienced the rise in unemployment rates reported for the EC. Bean's survey paper shows average unemployment rates for nineteen of the twenty-three countries in the OECD during sub-periods from 1969 to 1992. In the first sub-period, 1969-73, the range of average unemployment rates was from less than 1 percent to nearly 6 percent, and the unweighted average was 2.5 percent. By 1986-92, the bottom of the range had increased almost to the 1969-73 average. The average rose to 7.7 percent, and the range to 2.3 percent to 18.1 percent. The average unemployment rate increased in all nineteen co~ntries.~ More importantly, the data suggest that relative positions were not very different in the two periods. A rank correlation coefficient between countries' average unemployment rates in 1969-73 and 1986-92 is 0.66, significant at the 1 percent level. The median percentage

Commentary 163 increase is 270 percent? Many countries in the EC are close to the median increase and show about the same percentage increase as such non-ec countries as Austria, Finland, and Norway. While it is true that eight or nine countries above the median unemployment rate in 1986-92 are in the EC, the same is true for six of the nine countries above the median unemployment rate in 1969-73. The prior existence of welfare states does not pose a problem if the size and scope of welfare states increased in rough proportion to their levels in 1969-73. Social benefits rose in many of the European countries in which unemployment increased. Alesina and Perotti (1994) compiled data on social expenditures as a share of GDP in the EC for 1960 and 1988. Dese are shown in Table 1 for eight countries. Also shown are the changes in the unemployment rate for the same countries using data for 1969-73 and 1986-92 from Bean (1994). Except for Ireland, the rise in the unemployment rate correlates well with the increase in welfare spending. Table 1 Changes in Social Expenditure as a Percentage of GDP and Changes in the Unemployment Rate Country Changes in Social Change in Average Spendin GDP 1 Unem lo ment Rate 1988 if 960 19889l- 1969173 Spain Denmark France Belgium Italy United Kingdom Germany Ireland Sources: Alesina and Perotti (1994), Bean (1994). 'social expenditure includes sickness, disability, old age, unemployment, family allowance, maternity. vocational training, and housing.

164 Allan H. Melrzer The data are not for the same period, so caution is in order. Also, data are not available for the full sample. Nevertheless, the increase in unemployment is not unrelated to the increase in welfare spending. Policy issues Bean looks with more favor than I on monetary manipulation, ' demand stimulus, and temporary incomes policy as an aid to reducing unemployment. He opposes policy coordination even within Europe. And he sees little scope for demand-side fiscal policy to increase demand because most countries have large deficits relative to GDP. ~iskain policy recommendation is for supply-side reforms, but he is not very specific about the particular reforms he favors. He proposes modest monetary stimulus and incomes policies to support the transition to the new steady state at lower unemployment rates. Bean recognizes-indeed emphasizes-that both policymakers and economists face considerable uncertainty about the prevailing equilibrium rate of unemployment. In the face of this uncertainty, it seems wrong to suggest that policymakers should increase uncertainty about the future price level by engaging in monetary fine tuning or try to fool workers and owners into thinking real demand is higher than it is. A coherent, consistent, well-articulated monetary policy to achieve zero expected inflation in each country seems a better way to take advantage of the latitude provided by current exchange rate bands and floating rates. I believe Bean dismisses fiscal action too quickly. Reductions in transfers payments could be financed by equivalent reductions in taxes on labor. Since those who receive the transfers and those who bear tax burdens are not the same, incentives to work can be increased by reductions in taxes and benefits. The dynamic effects on aggregate output and income would lower the deficit. This suggestion, like many other proposals for supply-side policies, raises political issues about redistribution. Welfare state policies are chosen, or at least supported, by voters. The economic equilibrium that sustains a high measured unemployment rate appears to be not just an economic but a political equilibrium. The unemployed and

Commentary 165 their legislative representatives do not demonstrate or demand reductions in taxes and transfers to increase employment. Most often they ask for increased transfers financed by taxes on earned income. Such policies increase measured unemployment or the number of "discouraged workers." Demands for reductions in welfare state benefits come mainly from those in the middle and upper income groups who pay taxes in excess of the benefits they receive. Typically the latter demands exclude the transfers received by the taxpaying groups.5 Most politicians act as if they doubt that amajority of their constituents favor reductions in comprehensive benefit programs. Finally, a few words about the alleged tradeoff between low-paying service jobs and higher unemployment rates discussed in other papers at this conference. During the last election campaign in the United States, some economists and their friends in the media misled the public by promoting the idea that many of the 20 million jobs created during the 1980s were low-paying service sector jobs. A different version of the same idea is that the United States has kept unemployment rates low by replacing high-paying jobs in goods producing industries with low-paying service sector jobs. Chart 3 compares the distributions of weekly wages in goods and service producing industries in 1992. The two distributions overlap to a considerable extent. This should dispose of the false notion that service sector jobs are low-paying jobs and, with it, the idea that most of the new jobs created in the 1980s were low-paying jobs.6 The policies of the 1980s drew people into the labor force where many developed the skills and work experience essential for increasing lifetime income. Author's Note: I have benefited from several discussions with Bennett McCallum.

Chart 3 Wage Distributions, Goods and Services, 1992 Proportion of workers Weekly wages (dollars) Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Commentary Endnotes '~ncreases in unemployment rates in Sweden and Finland in the 1990s have not lasted long enough to be described as persistent. 'ln 1993-94, Swedish unemployment rates rose to about the European average. The number of workers in training programs rose also but less than proportionally. (Ministry of Finance, 1993, p. 48) 3~atare not available for Greece, Luxembourg, Portugal, and Turkey. 4~ince several countries reported unemployment rates below 1 percent for 1969-73, the mean percentage change is misleading. or models of this political-economic equilibrium with taxes and redistribution, see Meltzer, Cukierman, and Richard (1991). 6 ~ Kosters s (1994) shows, the main reason for the recent sh~ft in income distributions is the higher premium for college-educated workers in the 1980s. References Alesina, A,, and R. Perotti. "The Welfare State and Competitiveness," NBER Working Paper 4810, (July 1994). Bean, Charles R. "European Unemployment: A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature 32 (June 1994), pp. 573--619. Burda, M. "Wait Unemployment in Europe," Economic Policy 7 (October 1988). pp. 393-416. Kosters, Marvin. Trade and Wages, in J. Bhagwati and M. Kosters, eds. Washington: American Enterprise Institute, 1994. Meltzer, Allan H., and Scott F. Richard. "A Positive Theory of In-Kind Transfers and the Negative Income Tax." Public Choice 47, pp. 231--65. Reprinted in A.H. Meltzer, A. Cukierman, and S.F. Richard (1991). Political Economy, 1985. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 53-75. Ministry of Finance. Sweden$ Economy, (January 1993). Stockholm.