Money in an RBC framework

Similar documents
Money in a Neoclassical Framework

Transactions and Money Demand Walsh Chapter 3

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Lecture 17 Real Business Cycles Money. Noah Williams

Monetary Economics. Money in Utility. Seyed Ali Madanizadeh. February Sharif University of Technology

Cash-in-Advance Model

Topic 6. Introducing money

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Lecture 15 Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Discussion: The Optimal Rate of Inflation by Stephanie Schmitt- Grohé and Martin Uribe

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Problem set Fall 2012.

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Inflation & Welfare 1

Money Demand. ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Cash in Advance Models

1 Dynamic programming

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

Chapter 10 Money, Interest and Prices

GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL POLICY IN JUNE 16, 2010 THE CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL (CONTINUED) ADYNAMIC MODEL OF THE GOVERNMENT

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

The Neoclassical Growth Model

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

Lecture 12 Ricardian Equivalence Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

Fluctuations in the economy s output. 1. Three Components of Investment

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Overlapping Generations Model: Dynamic Efficiency and Social Security

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

Slides III - Complete Markets

The Real Business Cycle Model

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Monetary/Fiscal Interactions: Cash in Advance

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

1 Continuous Time Optimization

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

6. Deficits and inflation: seignorage as a source of public sector revenue

Final Exam Solutions

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

1 No capital mobility

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited. Working Paper 752 July 2018

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 15 Problem 3 / 15 Problem 4 / 20 Problem 5 / 25 TOTAL / 100

Macroeconomic Cycle and Economic Policy

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy

Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective

Exchange Rate Policies at the Zero Lower Bound

Money Demand. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Inflation. David Andolfatto

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

The New Keynesian Model

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Business Cycles II: Theories

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982

Money, Output, and the Nominal National Debt. Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman (AER 1990)

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Monetary Economics Basic Flexible Price Models

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Optimal Capital Income Taxation

Public budget accounting and seigniorage. 1. Public budget accounting, inflation and debt. 2. Equilibrium seigniorage

Lecture 3. Chulalongkorn University, EBA Program Monetary Theory and Policy Professor Eric Fisher

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

MONETARY AND FINANCIAL MACRO BUDGET CONSTRAINTS

Transcription:

Money in an RBC framework Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 1 / 36

Money Two basic questions: 1 Modern economies use money. Why? 2 How/why do changes in the amount of money affect nominal and real variables in the economy? Uses/functions of money: (1) Unit of account: contracts are usually denominated in terms of money. (2) Store of value: money allows consumers to trade current goods for future goods. (3) Medium of exchange: facilitates transactions. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 2 / 36

Money in Exchange Non-monetary transactions require barter: one good or service is exchanged directly for another. Requires a double coincidence of wants: each party must want what other has. Other objects, like stocks and bonds, can be store of value and medium of exchange. Can dominate as store of value since they give a positive rate of return. But stocks and bonds are not efficient in exchange: 1 Agents not well-informed about the exact value of stocks. 2 It is not always easy to sell these assets. (Liquidity) Money very efficient in exchange. Facilitates specialization. In absence of regular money, other objects appear as media of exchange (cigarettes in POW camps). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 3 / 36

Types of money Ancient Greek coins, ca 700 BC Cowry shells Stone money of the island of Yap Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 4 / 36

M1 and Its Currency Component 2,800 M1 Money Stock Currency Component of M1 2,400 (Billions of Dollars) 2,000 1,600 1,200 800 400 0 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Shaded areas indicate US recessions - 2014 research.stlouisfed.org Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 5 / 36

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 6 / 36

Incorporating money To employ the neoclassical framework to analyze monetary issues, a role for money must be specified so that the agents will wish to hold positive quantities of money. Money dominated as an asset. Three general approaches to incorporating money into general equilibrium models have been followed: 1 Assume that money yields direct utility by incorporating money balances directly into the utility functions of the agents of the model (Sidrauski 1967). 2 Impose transactions costs 1 Make asset exchanges costly (Baumol 1952, Tobin 1956) 2 Require that money be used for certain types of transactions (Clower 1967) 3 Assume time and money can be combined to produce transaction services that are necessary for obtaining consumption goods 4 Assume direct barter of commodities is costly (Kiyotaki and Wright 1989). 3 Treat money like any other asset used to transfer resources intertemporally (Samuelson 1958). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 7 / 36

A basic MIU model First approach: MIU Sidrauski (1967) Real money balances enter directly in the utility function. Given suitable restrictions on the utility function, such an approach can guarantee that, in equilibrium, agents choose to hold positive amounts of money so that money will be positively valued. Representative household takes prices as given and maximizes E t i=0 β i U (C t+i, m t+i, L t+i ) subject to a budget constraint. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 8 / 36

A basic MIU model Budget constraint, in nominal terms: W t (1 L t ) + (r t + 1 δ) P t K t 1 +(1 + i t 1 )B t 1 + M t 1 + P t τ t = P t C t + P t K t + B t + M t where τ are real, lump-sum transfers to the household (can be negative). In real terms: or w t (1 L t ) + (r t + 1 δ) K t 1 +(1 + i t 1 ) B t 1 P t + M t 1 = C P t + τ t + K t + B t + M t t P t P t w t (1 L t ) + (r t + 1 δ) K t 1 +(1 + i t 1 ) P t 1 P t b t 1 + P t 1 = C P t m t 1 + τ t + K t + b t + m t t Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 9 / 36

A basic MIU model First order conditions: U C λ t = 0 U L w t λ t = 0 U L U C = w t λ t + βe t (r t+1 + 1 δ) λ t+1 = 0 ( ) Pt λ t + β(1 + i t )E t λ t+1 = 0 P t+1 ( ) Pt U m λ t + βe t λ t+1 = 0 P t+1 First three look just as before (except U C and U L may depend on m). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 10 / 36

A basic MIU model The FOC for money can be written Solve forward to yield λ t = U m + βe t P t P t ( ) 1 1 = E t P t λ t i=0 ( λt+1 P t+1 ) [ ] β i Um (C t+i, m t+i, L t+i ) P t+i Value of money equals expected present value of discounted utility return. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 11 / 36

A basic MIU model Combining the first and third conditions yields the Euler condition: U C (C t, m t, L t ) = βe t (r t+1 + 1 δ) U C (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) Similarly, ( ) Pt U C (C t, m t, L t ) = β(1 + i t )E t U C (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) P t+1 From fourth and fifth, But so U m U C U m U C = βi t E t ( Pt P t+1 1 = β(1 + i t )E t ( Pt = βi t E t ( Pt P t+1 P t+1 ) UC (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) U C (C t, m t, L t ) ) UC (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) U C (C t, m t, L t ) ) UC (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) U C (C t, m t, L t ) = i t 1 + i t. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 12 / 36

A basic MIU model Firm side of model is same as in basic RBC model. Collecting equilibrium conditions Given an exogenous process for the productivity shock and the nominal stock of money, equilibrium consists of time paths for output, real money balances, consumption, capital, employment, wages, the nominal rate of interest, the price level, and rental rates that satisfy Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 13 / 36

A basic MIU model U L (C t, m t, 1 N t ) U C (C t, m t, 1 N t ) = w t U m U C = i t 1 + i t. U C (C t, m t, 1 N t ) = βe t (r t+1 + 1 δ) U C (C t+1, m t+1, 1 N t+1 ) ( ) Pt U C (C t, m t, L t ) = β(1 + i t )E t U C (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) P t+1 Y t = F (N t, K t 1, Z t ) F N (N t, K t 1, Z t ) = w t F K (N t, K t 1, Z t ) = r t Y t = C t + K t (1 δ)k t 1 P t m t = M t Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 14 / 36

A basic MIU model Steady-state Standard RBC relationships plus 1 = β U m (C, m, 1 N) U C (C, m, 1 N) = ( ) 1 + i 1 + π i 1 + i P t = M 0(1 + π) t m = 1 β 1 + π These imply the Fisher equation 1 + i = (r + 1 δ) (1 + π) or i r + π Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 15 / 36

Superneutrality If U L and U C independent of m, real side identical to basic RBC model. (Steady state and dynamics) Neutrality: One time changes in the nominal quantity of money affect only the price level. Superneutrality: Changes in growth rate of money do not affect real variables. Changes in the rate of growth of money affect only the inflation rate, the nominal interest rate, and real money balances. If F displays constant returns to scale and U L and U C depend on m, still get steady-state capital-labor ratio independence of money growth. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 16 / 36

Money in the Long Run Reported by McCandless and Weber (1995), Lucas (1996) There is a high (almost unity) correlation between the rate of growth of monetary supply and the rate of inflation. There is no correlation between the growth rates of money and real output. There in no correlation between inflation and real output. These are consistent with monetary neutrality. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 17 / 36

Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 18 / 36

Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 19 / 36

Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 20 / 36

Welfare cost of inflation Because money holdings yield direct utility and higher inflation reduces real money balances, inflation generates a welfare loss. Questions: How large is the welfare cost of inflation? Is there an optimal rate of inflation that maximizes the steady-state welfare of the representative household? Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 21 / 36

Welfare cost of inflation The optimal rate of inflation addressed by Bailey (1956) and M. Friedman (1969). Basic intuition: the private opportunity cost of holding money depends on the nominal rate of interest. The social marginal cost of producing money is essentially zero. The wedge that arises between the private marginal cost and the social marginal cost when the nominal rate of interest is positive generates an inefficiency. This inefficiency would be eliminated if the nominal rate of interest were zero. So the optimal rate of inflation is a rate of deflation approximately equal to the real return on capital. In the steady state, real money balances are directly related to the inflation rate, so the optimal rate of inflation is also frequently discussed under the heading of the optimal quantity of money. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 22 / 36

Welfare cost of inflation The major criticism of this result is that of Phelps (1973), who pointed out that money growth generates revenue for the government the inflation tax. The implicit assumption so far has been that variations in money growth are engineered via lump-sum transfers. Any effects on government revenue can be offset by a suitable adjustment in these lump-sum transfers (taxes). But if governments only have distortionary taxes available for financing expenditures, then reducing inflation tax revenues to achieve the Friedman rule for optimal inflation requires that the lost revenue be replaced through increases in other distortionary taxes. To minimize the total distortions associated with raising a given amount of revenue, it may be optimal to rely to some degree on the inflation tax. More recent work has reexamined these results (see Chari, Christiano, and Kehoe 1991, 1996, Correia and Teles 1996, 1999, Mulligan and Sala-i-Martin 1997). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 23 / 36

Cash-in-advance models Clower (1967), goods buy money and money buys goods, but goods don t buy goods. And because goods don t buy goods, a medium of exchange that serves to aid the process of transacting will have value. The demand for money is then determined by the nature of the economy s transactions technology. Rather than allowing substitutability between time and money in carrying out transactions, cash-in-advance (CIA) models simply require that money balances be held to finance certain types of purchases; without money, these purchases cannot be made. CIA models. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 24 / 36

Household Problem: Timing At the start of the period, the household has three assets: Money M t 1, nominal bonds B t 1, and capital K t 1. Household consists of two members, a worker and a shopper. Worker supplies labor to firm, earns wage. Shopper takes M t 1 to store and purchases consumption goods At the end of the period household members pool resources, rebalance portfolio of assets. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 25 / 36

Alternative Timing Timing assumptions also are important in CIA models. In Lucas (1982), agents are able to allocate their portfolio between cash and other assets at the start of each period, after observing any current shocks but prior to purchasing goods. The asset market opens first and then the goods market opens. If there is a positive opportunity cost of holding money and the asset market opens first, agents will only hold an amount of money that is just sufficient to finance their desired level of consumption. In Svensson (1985), the goods market opens first. This implies that agents have available for spending only the cash carried over from the previous period, and so cash balances must be chosen before agents know how much spending they will wish to undertake. If uncertainty is resolved after money balances are chosen, an agent may find that she is holding cash balances that are too low to finance her desired spending level. Or she may be left with more cash than she needs, thereby forgoing interest income. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 26 / 36

Cash-in-advance models The representative agent Maximizes present discounted value of expected utility subject to a sequence of new constraints. If the goods markets open first and the agent enters the period with money holdings M t 1 and receives a lump-sum transfer T t (in nominal terms), the CIA constraint takes the form P t c t M t 1 + T t, where c is real consumption, P is the aggregate price level, and T is the nominal lump-sum transfer. In real terms, c t M t 1 + T t = m t 1 + τ t, P t P t Π t where m t 1 = M t 1 /P t 1, Π t = P t /P t 1 is 1 plus the inflation rate, and τ t = T t /P t. Income from production during period t will not be available for consumption purchases during period t. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 27 / 36

Cash-in-advance models Budget constraint in real terms, ω t c t + m t + b t + k t where ω t f (k t 1 ) + (1 δ)k t 1 + τ t + m t 1 + (1 + i t 1 )b t 1 Π t, and m and b are real cash and bond holdings. Let a t = b t + m t. Then budget constraint implies ω t+1 = f (k t ) + (1 δ)k t + τ t+1 + R t a t ( it Π t+1 ) m t. This form highlights that there is a cost to holding money when the nominal interest rate is positive. This cost is (1 + i t )/Π t+1. This is the same expression for the opportunity cost of money in an MIU model. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 28 / 36

Cash-in-advance models The decision problem Define the value function V (ω t, m t 1 ) = max{u(c t ) + βv (ω t+1, m t )}, where the maximization is subject to the budget constraint ω t c t + m t + b t + k t, the CIA constraint, and the definition of ω t+1. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 29 / 36

Cash-in-advance models The decision problem Letting λ t (µ t ) denote the Lagrangian multiplier associated with the budget constraint (the CIA constraint), the first order necessary conditions for the agent s choice of consumption, capital, bond, and money holdings take the form [ β R t u c (c t ) λ t µ t = 0 β [f k (k t ) + 1 δ] V ω (ω t+1, m t ) λ t = 0 i t Π t+1 βr t V ω (ω t+1, m t ) λ t = 0 ] V ω (ω t+1, m t ) + βv m (ω t+1, m t ) λ t = 0. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 30 / 36

Cash-in-advance models From the envelope theorem, V ω (ω t, m t 1 ) = λ t ( ) 1 V m (ω t, m t 1 ) = µ t. Π t λ t is equal to the marginal utility of wealth. The marginal utility of consumption exceeds the marginal utility of wealth by the value of liquidity services, µ t. The individual must hold money in order to purchase consumption, so the cost, to which the marginal utility of consumption is set equal, is the marginal utility of wealth plus the cost of the liquidity services needed to finance the transaction. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 31 / 36

Cash-in-advance models The first order conditions imply ( ) λt+1 + µ λ t = β t+1 1 ( 1 = P t Π t+1 λ t ) β ( λt+1 + µ t+1 P t+1 This equation can also be interpreted as an asset pricing equation for money. The price of a unit of money in terms of goods is just 1/P t at time t; its value in utility terms is λ t /P t. Solving this equation forward implies that ( ) 1 1 ( ) = β i µt+i. P t λ t i=1 P t+i Value of money related to present discounted value of Lagrangian multipliers on CIA constraint. ). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 32 / 36

Cash-in-advance models The nominal rate of interest Since λ t = βr t λ t+1 = β ( ) λ t+1 + µ t+1 /Πt+1, or R t Π t+1 λ t+1 = ( ) λ t+1 + µ t+1 and 1 + it = R t Π t+1, the nominal interest rate is given by ( ) λt+1 + µ i t = t+1 1 = µ t+1. λ t+1 λ t+1 The nominal rate of interest is positive if and only if money yields liquidity services (µ t+1 > 0). In particular, if the nominal interest rate is positive, the CIA constraint is binding (µ > 0). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 33 / 36

Cash-in-advance models Marginal utility of consumption We can use the relationship between the nominal rate of interest and the Lagrangian multipliers to rewrite the expression for the marginal utility of consumption as u c = λ(1 + µ/λ) = λ(1 + i) λ. Since λ represents the marginal value of income, the marginal utility of consumption exceeds that of income whenever the nominal interest rate is positive. Even though the economy s technology allows output to be directly transformed into consumption, the price of consumption is not equal to 1; it is 1 + i since the household must hold money to finance consumption. Thus, in this CIA model, a positive nominal interest rate acts as a tax on consumption; it raises the price of consumption above its production cost. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 34 / 36

Cash-in-advance models Modifications Cash and Credit Goods Lucas and Stokey (1983, 1987) introduced the idea that the CIA constraint may only apply to a subset of consumption goods. The marginal utility of cash goods will be equated to λ + µ λ, while the marginal utility of credit goods will be equated to λ. Hence, the CIA requirement for cash goods drives a wedge between the marginal utilities of the two types of goods. It is exactly as if the consumer faces a tax of µ/λ = i on purchases of the cash good. Higher inflation, by reducing holdings of real cash balances, serves to raise the tax on cash goods and generates a substitution away from the cash good and toward the credit good. CIA and Investment Goods The inflation tax applies to both consumption and investment goods. Higher rates of inflation will tend to discourage capital accumulation lower the steady-state capital-labor ratio. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 35 / 36

Welfare costs of inflation In CIA models, inflation acts as a tax on goods or activities whose purchase requires cash. This tax then introduces a distortion by creating a wedge between the marginal rates of transformation implied by the economy s technology and the marginal rates of substitution faced by consumers. Since the CIA model, like the MIU model, offers no reason for such a distortion to be introduced (there is no inefficiency that calls for Pigovian taxes or subsidies on particular activities, and the government s revenue needs can be met through lump-sum taxation), optimality calls for setting the inflation tax equal to zero. The inflation tax is directly related to the nominal rate of interest; a zero inflation tax is achieved when the nominal rate of interest is equal to zero. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 36 / 36