The Financial Econometrics of Option Markets

Similar documents
Parametric Pricing of Higher Order Moments in S&P500 Options

Smile in the low moments

Which GARCH Model for Option Valuation? By Peter Christoffersen and Kris Jacobs

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market

Assicurazioni Generali: An Option Pricing Case with NAGARCH

Value at Risk Ch.12. PAK Study Manual

1. What is Implied Volatility?

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

LOG-SKEW-NORMAL MIXTURE MODEL FOR OPTION VALUATION

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Tommi Huhta PERFORMANCE OF THE BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON S&P 500 CALL OPTIONS IN 2014

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

MODELLING VOLATILITY SURFACES WITH GARCH

A Note on the Pricing of Contingent Claims with a Mixture of Distributions in a Discrete-Time General Equilibrium Framework

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

**BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** A random sample of five observations from a population is:

Two hours. To be supplied by the Examinations Office: Mathematical Formula Tables and Statistical Tables THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER

Financial Econometrics

Walter S.A. Schwaiger. Finance. A{6020 Innsbruck, Universitatsstrae 15. phone: fax:

Extreme Return-Volume Dependence in East-Asian. Stock Markets: A Copula Approach

Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

GARCH Options in Incomplete Markets

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

Monte Carlo Methods in Financial Engineering

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management

FX Smile Modelling. 9 September September 9, 2008

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

THE INFORMATION CONTENT OF IMPLIED VOLATILITY IN AGRICULTURAL COMMODITY MARKETS. Pierre Giot 1

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES Quantitative Finance and Investment Advanced Exam Exam QFIADV AFTERNOON SESSION

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Appendix. 1 Several papers have dealt with the topic of warrant pricing. Examples include Schwartz

Forecasting Stock Index Futures Price Volatility: Linear vs. Nonlinear Models

THE GARCH STRUCTURAL CREDIT RISK MODEL: SIMULATION ANALYSIS AND APPLICATION TO THE BANK CDS MARKET DURING THE CRISIS

The histogram should resemble the uniform density, the mean should be close to 0.5, and the standard deviation should be close to 1/ 12 =

Counterparty Credit Risk Simulation

The Black-Scholes Model

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty

Distributed Computing in Finance: Case Model Calibration

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

Statistical Analysis of Data from the Stock Markets. UiO-STK4510 Autumn 2015

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

STOCK INDEX FUTURES MARKETS: STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS AND SMILES

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

Implied Volatility Spreads and Expected Market Returns

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach

STOCK RETURNS AND INFLATION: THE IMPACT OF INFLATION TARGETING

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

The Black-Scholes Model

Asymmetric Price Transmission: A Copula Approach

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms

ESTIMATION OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS: MARKET VS. REPRESENTATIVE AGENT THEORY

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Introduction to Energy Derivatives and Fundamentals of Modelling and Pricing

Forecasting jumps in conditional volatility The GARCH-IE model

Option-based tests of interest rate diffusion functions

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Conditional Heteroscedasticity

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

Empirical Approach to the Heston Model Parameters on the Exchange Rate USD / COP

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models

Pricing Convertible Bonds under the First-Passage Credit Risk Model

Financial Models with Levy Processes and Volatility Clustering

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

Chapter 1. Introduction

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

Are Financial Markets Stable? New Evidence from An Improved Test of Financial Market Stability and the U.S. Subprime Crisis

Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions

The Black-Scholes Model

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

The stochastic calculus

Subject CS1 Actuarial Statistics 1 Core Principles. Syllabus. for the 2019 exams. 1 June 2018

Financial Times Series. Lecture 6

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS: CALIBRATION, PRICING AND HEDGING. Warrick Poklewski-Koziell

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Linda Allen, Jacob Boudoukh and Anthony Saunders, Understanding Market, Credit and Operational Risk: The Value at Risk Approach

Center for Economic Institutions Working Paper Series

P VaR0.01 (X) > 2 VaR 0.01 (X). (10 p) Problem 4

Application of Moment Expansion Method to Option Square Root Model

A comment on Christoffersen, Jacobs and Ornthanalai (2012), Dynamic jump intensities and risk premiums: Evidence from S&P500 returns and options

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Energy Price Processes

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model:

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options

12. Conditional heteroscedastic models (ARCH) MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, 2006.

Online Appendix to Grouped Coefficients to Reduce Bias in Heterogeneous Dynamic Panel Models with Small T

Portfolio Management Using Option Data

Transcription:

of Option Markets Professor Vance L. Martin October 8th, 2013 October 8th, 2013 1 / 53

Outline of Workshop Day 1: 1. Introduction to options 2. Basic pricing ideas 3. Econometric interpretation to pricing 4. Speci cation of price dynamics 5. The Black-Scholes model 6. Eyeballing options data 7. Estimation (a) Using returns data (b) Using options data (c) Using returns and options data October 8th, 2013 2 / 53

Outline of Workshop Day 2: 1. Testing the Black-Scholes model (a) Biasedness (b) Heteroskedasticity (c) Smiles and smirks 2. Relaxing the assumptions of Black-Scholes (a) Distribution (b) Pricing skewness and kurtosis (c) Functional forms and nonparametrics (d) Time-varying volatility (GARCH, stochastic volatility, forward looking) (e) Jumps (Poisson, Hawkes) 3. Monte Carlo pricing methods 4. Application to Exchange options and contagion October 8th, 2013 3 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Consider the empirical model based on Black-Scholes c i = c BS i (σ) + u i where c i represents the observed price of the i th option and ci BS (σ) is the price of the i th option contract based on Black-Scholes with d i de ned as c i = p i Φ(d i ) k i e r i h i Φ(d i σ p h i ) d i = log(p i /k i ) + (r i + 1 2 σ2 )h i σ p h i The Black-Scholes model imposes very strong restrictions on the underlying process which can be tested using various inferential methods. Three tests of the model are now investigated. 1. Biasedness 2. Heteroskedasticity 3. Smiles and Smirks October 8th, 2013 4 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Biasedness The empirical model does not contain an intercept in the conditional mean suggesting that the conditional mean of the call option price equals the Black-Scholes price E [c i j p i ] = c BS i = p i Φ(d i ) k i e rh i Φ(d i σ p h i ) as E [u i ] = 0. This result is interpreted as the call option price is unbiased. To allow for the possibility of the observed option price being biased the empirical model is extended to include an intercept c i = β 0 + p i Φ(d i ) k i e rh i Φ(d i σ p h i ) + u i where β 0 is the unknown intercept. A test of the unbiasedness property is that the intercept is zero is based on the hypothesis β 0 = 0 This restriction can be tested using a standard t-test. October 8th, 2013 5 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Biasedness Example (Testing for Biasedness) The number of iterations for the algorithm to converge is 142 yielding a log-likelihood value of log L b θ = 31050.49 The parameter estimates are n o bθ = bσ 2 = 0.014184, bω 2 = 0.551221, bβ 0 = 0.810496 As se(bβ 0 ) = 0.009125, a test of biasedness is given by the t-statistic tstat = 0.810496 0.0 0.009125 = 88.818 This constitutes signi cant bias and a rejection of Black-Scholes. October 8th, 2013 6 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Biasedness Example (Testing for Biasedness continued) Nonetheless, the volatility estimate is similar to when β 0 = 0 as the estimate of the annualised volatility is bσ = p 0.014184 = 0.1191 or 11.91% compared to 13.05% with β 0 = 0. October 8th, 2013 7 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Biasedness The biasedness property can be extended to allow for di erent biasedness for di erent contracts. This is achieved by including a dummy variable for di erent strike prices. As there is an intercept and there are 30 strike prices the regression equation is augmented to include just the rst 29 strike prices to circumvent the dummy variable trap. Alternatively, an equivalent approach is to include all 30 strike price dummy variables and exclude the intercept. October 8th, 2013 8 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Biasedness The empirical model is now expanded as c i = β 0 + 29 j=1 β i D j,i + p i Φ(d i ) k i e rh i Φ(d i σ p h i ) + u i where D j,i, j = 1, 2,, 29, are dummy variables de ned as a dummy variable corresponding to the highest strike price of k = 550, is not needed as the equation contains an intercept term, thereby avoiding the 1 : k = 350 D 1,i = D 2,i =. D 29,i = 0 : otherwise 1 : k = 370 0 : otherwise 1 : k = 530 0 : otherwise October 8th, 2013 9 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Biasedness Instead of constructing dummy variables for each strike price, dummy variables can be grouped together in terms of moneyness. A possible classi cation of moneyness is DUM_OUT j = DUM_AT j = DUM_IN j = ( ( ( p 1 : k < 0.97 0 : otherwise 1 : 0.97 < p k < 1.03 0 : otherwise 1 : 1.03 < p k 0 : otherwise If the model contains an intercept term then again it will only be necessary to include two of the moneyness variables. October 8th, 2013 10 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Biasedness Instead of just including dummy variables based on strike prices, dummy variables corresponding to other characteristics of option contracts can be used to augment the model. For example, dummy variables on the three types of maturities in the stock option data set would be de ned as 1 : hi = 0.123288 D MAY,i = 0 : otherwise 1 : hi = 0.200000 D JUNE,i = (1) 0 : otherwise 1 : hi = 0.457534 D SEPT,i = 0 : otherwise corresponding respectively to May, June and September option contracts. As before, only two of the three dummy variables need to be included if the model already contains an intercept term. October 8th, 2013 11 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Heteroskedasticity An important assumption of the empirical model is that the variance of the disturbance term ω 2, is constant across all contract types. To relax the assumption of homoskedasticity the dummy variables de ned for strikes and maturities in can be used to allow the disturbance variance to change over the sample. In the case of the maturity dummy variables, the pricing error disturbance term is speci ed as ω 2 i = exp (α 0 + α 1 D MAY,i + +α 2 D JUNE,i ) A joint test of the restrictions α 1 = α 2 = 0 is a test of homoskedasticity which can be performed using a likelihood ratio test for example. October 8th, 2013 12 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Smiles and Smirks In estimating the option price models the data consist of option contracts corresponding to 30 strike prices and 3 maturities, a total 90 di erent types of call option contracts. An important feature of the estimated model is that there is just a single estimate of the volatility parameter σ, regardless of the type of option contract. This is a restriction of the model which can be tested by reestimating the model for alternative strike prices and alternative maturities. October 8th, 2013 13 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Smiles and Smirks A test of the assumption that σ is invariant to strike prices k is to group the data for each k and reestimate σ for each group. 1. If the Black-Scholes model is consistent with the data then the estimates of σ for each group should not be statistically di erent from each other. 2. If the estimates σ are di erent across groups this is evidence against the Black-Scholes model. In practice there are two types of relationships between σ and k. 1. Volatility Smile - there is a U-shape relationship between σ and k, centered around the at-the-money options. Occurs in currency options. 2. Volatility Smirk or skew - there is an inverse relationship between σ and k, with volatility being relatively high for in-the-money options and low for out-of-the-money options. Occurs in stock options. October 8th, 2013 14 / 53

Testing the Black-Scholes Model Smiles and Smirks Example (Volatility Smirk in Stock Options) The model is estimated using option prices separately for each of the 30 groups of strike prices for the European call options written on the S&P500 stock index on April 4, 1995. The tted line is based on a nonparametric kernel regression. There is evidence of a smirk with estimates of σ ranging from 0.3 to 0.1.This result is evidence of misspeci cation..36.32.28 IMVOL.24.20.16.12.08 320 360 400 440 480 520 560 STRIKE October 8th, 2013 15 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Evidence of volatility smiles and smirks in particular have led to the speci cation of more general models of asset prices. Some potential speci cations are: 1. Relaxing the assumption of lognormality and adopting a more general speci cation. 2. Relaxing the assumption of constant volatility. 3. Allow for additional e ects in the mean. 4. Allow for additional e ects in the variance of the pricing error (heteroskedasticity). October 8th, 2013 16 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Mixture of Lognormals Melick and Thomas (1997) specify a mixture of lognormal distributions. The empirical option pricing model is c i = αc BS 1,i (σ 1 ) + (1 α) c BS 1,i (σ 2 ), where BS (σ j ), j = 1, 2, is the Black-Scholes price c BS j,i = p i Φ(d j,i ) k i e rh i Φ(d j,i σ j p hi ) with constant volatility, σ j, j = 1, 2 and d j,i = log(p i /k i ) + (r i + 1 2 σ2 j )h i σ j p hi The parameter 0 α 1, is the mixing parameter which weights the two subordinate lognormal distributions. October 8th, 2013 17 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Mixture of Lognormals Example (Estimating the Mixture Model) The number of iterations for the algorithm to converge is 76 yielding a log-likelihood value of log L b θ = 12142.95 The parameter estimates are n o bθ = bσ 2 1 = 0.000917, bσ 2 1 = 0.042563, bα = 0.551565, bω 2 = 0.140724 The estimates of the volatilities of the two distributions, σ 2 1 and σ2 1, suggest that the two lognormal distributions have very di erent shapes. October 8th, 2013 18 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Mixture of Lognormals Example (Estimating the Mixture Model) The estimate of α is 0.551565 suggesting that these two distributions have roughly equal weights. A test of equal weights given by the t-statistic 0.551565 0.5 tstat = 0.001567 = 32.907 suggests a rejection of the hypothesis α = 0.5 at conventional signi cance levels. October 8th, 2013 19 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Pricing the Risk from Skewness and Kurtosis: Jarrow-Rudd Model The class of semi-nonparametric option pricing models discussed here are based on an augmentation of the normal returns density through the inclusion of higher order terms. Jarrow and Rudd (1982) were the rst to adopt this approach, which was implemented by Corrado and Su (1997) and Capelle-Blancard, Jurczenko and Maillet (2001). Let g (z t+h ) represent the true conditional price distribution of the standardised returns z t+h = log z t+h log z t r 1 2 σ2 h σ p h October 8th, 2013 20 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Pricing the Risk from Skewness and Kurtosis: Jarrow-Rudd Model Using an Edgeworth expansion of g (z t+h ) around the normal density gives g (z t+h ) = φ (z t+h ) + (κ 4 (G ) κ 4 (Φ)) 4! (κ 3 (G ) κ 3 (Φ)) 3! d 4 φ (z t+h ) dz 4 t+h d 3 φ (z t+h ) dz 3 t+h + ε (z t+h ) where ε (z t+h ) is an approximation error arising from the exclusion of higher order terms in the expansion and κ i is the i th cumulant of the associated distribution with κ 1 = 0 and κ 2 = 1 to standardize the distribution to have zero mean and unit variance. October 8th, 2013 21 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Pricing the Risk from Skewness and Kurtosis: Jarrow-Rudd Model Using the properties of the normal distribution z "1 3 t+h 3z t+h + γ 1 where g (z t+h ) = φ (z t+h ) +γ 2 z 4 t+h 6z 2 t+h + 3 24 6 # + ε (z t+h ) γ 1 = (κ 3 (G ) κ 3 (Φ)), γ 3! 2 = (κ 4 (G ) κ 4 (Φ)) 4! are the unknown parameters which capture respectively skewness and kurtosis. The expression shows that the di erence between the true density, g (z t+h ) and the normal density φ (z t+h ), is determined by the third and fourth moments. October 8th, 2013 22 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Pricing the Risk from Skewness and Kurtosis: Jarrow-Rudd Model As from the transformation of variable technique f (p t+h jp t ) = jjj g (z t+h ) where J is the Jacobian of the transformation from z t+h to p t+h, then z "1 3 t+h 3z t+h + γ 1 f (p t+h jp t ) = jjj φ (z t+h ) +γ 2 z 4 t+h 6z 2 t+h + 3 24 where for simplicity the approximation error is ignored. 6 # October 8th, 2013 23 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Pricing the Risk from Skewness and Kurtosis: Jarrow-Rudd Model Using this density to price options yields the Jarrow-Rudd option pricing model ci JR = ci BS + γ 1 Q 3,i + γ 2 Q 4,i where c BS i and is the Black-Scholes price for the i th contract and Q 3,i = e rh Z k (p t+h k) jjj z 3 t+h 3z t+h φdp t+h 6 Q 4,i = e rh Z k (p t+h k) jjj z 4 t+h 6zt+h 2 + 3 φdp t+h 24 October 8th, 2013 24 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Pricing the Risk from Skewness and Kurtosis: Jarrow-Rudd Model Potential problem: the risk neutral probability distribution in is not constrained to be positive over the support of the density. Interestingly, this problem appears to have been ignored in the literature so far. The problem arises as the returns distribution is a function of cubic and quartic polynomials, which can, in general, yield negative values. The problem of negativity can be expected to be more severe when the Jarrow-Rudd approximation does not model the true distribution accurately, causing the polynomial terms to over-adjust, especially in the tails of the estimated distribution. October 8th, 2013 25 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Pricing the Risk from Skewness and Kurtosis: Jarrow-Rudd Model To impose non-negativity on the underlying risk neutral probability distribution the semi-nonparametric density of Gallant and Tauchen (1989) is speci ed p (z t+h ) = φ (z t+h ) "1 + λ 1 z 3 t+h 3z t+h 6 zt+h 4 6zt+h 2 + λ + 3 # 2 2 24 where the augmenting polynomial is now squared, forcing the probabilities to be greater than or equal to zero for all values of z t+h. Using this expression for the standardised returns yields the semi-nonparametric option pricing model which is referred to as the SNP option pricing model. October 8th, 2013 26 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Nonparametric Pricing Based on Arti cial Neural Networks The Black-Scholes option price shows that there is a nonlinear relationship between the option price ct BS, and the remaining arguments, p t, k, h, r, σ. For more general option price models it is not always possible to derive an analytic expression for the price of the option. One way to proceed is to use nonparametric methods based on for example, arti cial neural networks (ANN). An example of an ANN model of option prices is given by where c i = α 0 + α 1 (p i k i ) + α 2 h i + α 3 L i + v i (2) L i = 1 1 + exp [ (γ 0 + γ 1 (p i k i ) + γ 2 h i )] and v i is a disturbance term. The function L i represents the arti cial neural network where the form of the ANN is the logistic squasher. October 8th, 2013 27 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Nonparametric Pricing Based on Arti cial Neural Networks To estimate the parameters of the model in (2) an iterative maximum likelihood estimator can be used. Equivalently, the parameters can be chosen using MLE or even more simply a standard nonlinear least squares algorithm to minimise N vi 2 i=1 where N is the number of option contracts in the data set. The option prices are given by the tted values bc i = bα 0 + bα 1 (p i k i ) + bα 2 h i + bα 3 bl i where bl i = 1 1 + exp [ (bγ 0 + bγ 1 (p i k i ) + bγ 2 h i )] October 8th, 2013 28 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Nonparametric Pricing Based on Arti cial Neural Networks Having estimated the ANN it is possible to compute various hedge parameters to be used in a risk management strategy. An estimate of the options s delta is given by where bl i = bc i p = bα 1 + bα 3 bγ 1 bl i exp [ (bγ 0 + bγ 1 (p i k i ) + bγ 2 h i )] (1 + exp [ (bγ 0 + bγ 1 (p i k i ) + bγ 2 h i )]) 2 which is the logistic density function. October 8th, 2013 29 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Time-varying Volatility GARCH (Engle and Mustafa) A common method to allow for time-varying volatility is to use a GARCH speci cation. The model of asset prices over a day ( = 1/250) is log p t+1 log p t = r 1 2 σ2 t + p σ 2 t z t+1 σ 2 t+1 = α 0 + α 1 σ 2 t zt 2 + β 1 σ 2 t z t+1 N (0, 1) The variance is time-varying due to 1. Lagged squared shocks from the mean α 1 σ 2 t z2 t. Allows for memory in the variance to be one period. 2. Lagged conditional variance β 1 σ 2 t. Allows for memory in the variance to be longer than one period. But pricing options is more di cult as there is no closed form solution for the option price. Can use Monte Carlo methods. October 8th, 2013 30 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Time-varying Volatility GARCH (Heston and Nandi) An alternative GARCH model to Engle and Mustafa that yields an analytical formula for pricing European options. The model of asset prices over a day ( = 1/250) is log p t+1 log p t = r + γσ 2 p t + σ 2 t z t+1 σ 2 t+1 = β 0 + β 1 σ 2 t + β 2 (z t β 3 σ t ) 2 z t+1 N (0, 1) Under risk neutrality the model becomes log p t+1 log p t = r 1 2 σ2 t + p σ 2 t z t+1 σ 2 t+1 = β 0 + β 1 σ 2 t + β 2 (z t β 3 σ t) 2 z t+1 N (0, 1) where the z t+1 = z t+1 + (λ + 1/2) σ t under the risk neutral measure A quasi closed form expression is now available to price options. October 8th, 2013 31 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Time-varying Volatility Stochastic Volatility (Heston) A common method to allow for time-varying volatility is the stochastic volatility model. The model of asset prices over a day ( = 1/250) is log p t+1 log p t = z 2,t+1 r 1 2 σ2 t + p σ 2 t z 1,t+1 σ 2 t+1 σ 2 t = κ φ σ 2 p t + β σ 2 t z 2,t+1 z1,t+1 0 1 ρ N, 0 ρ 1 This model introduces an additional disturbance term z 2,t, in contrast to GARCH volatility models. It is for this reason why stochastic volatility models tend to be more di cult to estimate. October 8th, 2013 32 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Time-varying Volatility Stochastic Volatility (Heston) The volatility process is mean reverting to the long-run parameter φ, with the rate of conversion controlled by κ. The strength of the stochastic volatility is controlled by β, ie the parameter that controls the volatility of volatility. The volatility also displays the CIR speci cation with p β σ 2 t. (Model speci cation used by Heston (1993)). The two stochastic processes are allowed to be correlated with parameter ρ. Sometimes referred to as the leverage e ect. Heston derives European option prices for this model, although numerical procedures are needed to evaluate the option prices. October 8th, 2013 33 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Time-varying Volatility Forward Looking Volatility (Engle and Rosenberg) The GARCH volatility speci cation is backward looking as σ 2 t is a function of past shocks. A speci cation that is a function of future shocks is σ t+hjt = exp (β 1 + β 2 ln (p t+h /p t )) This speci cation shows that conditional volatility is stochastic, as it is a function of the future return over the life of the option, ln (p t+h /p t ). Special cases 1. β 2 > 0 : the relationship between volatility and future return is positive. 2. β 2 < 0 : there is an inverse relationship between future return and volatility (leverage e ect). 3. β 2 = 0 : constant volatility speci cation which underlies the Black-Scholes model. October 8th, 2013 34 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Time-varying Volatility Forward Looking Volatility (Engle and Rosenberg) A more natural speci cation to adopt in the context of option pricing as option prices are based on an evaluation of the future evolution of the underlying spot price. In common with a GARCH-type volatility speci cation, an additional error term is not introduced, with all randomness deriving from randomness in the asset price itself. This contrasts with a stochastic volatility model, in which the volatility process has its own random innovations. This speci cation has computational advantages compared with the GARCH and stochastic volatility speci cations. October 8th, 2013 35 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Jump Models Poisson Processes The aim is to allow for infrequent jumps in asset prices. The rst form of jumps is based on a Poisson process. The model of asset prices over a day ( = 1/250) is log p t+1 log p t = r 1 z t+1 N (0, 1) dn t+1 Po (λ) 2 σ2 + p σ 2 z t+1 + J N t+1 where the size of the jump is J and N t+1 is a Poisson process with jump intensity parameter λ given by P ( N t+1 = 0) = 1 λ + o ( ) P ( N t+1 = 1) = λ + o ( ) P ( N t+1 > 1) = o (dt). The larger is λ, the more likely a jump will occur. October 8th, 2013 36 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Jump Models Poisson Processes Note that the probabilities are a function of the time interval which in general will be small. This means that: 1. The occurrence of no jump is relatively high with probability of 1 λ. 2. The occurrence of one jump is relatively low with probability of λ. 3. The occurrence of more than one jump is e ectively zero. A problem with the Poisson process is that the jumps are independent. This is especially not the case during nancial crises where there tends to be a sequence of related jumps. October 8th, 2013 37 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Jump Models Hawkes Processes One way to relax the assumption that jumps are independent is to use a Hawkes process. The model of asset prices over a day ( = 1/250) is log p t+1 log p t = r 1 2 σ2 + p σ 2 z t+1 + J N t+1 λ t+1 λ t = α 1 (λ λ t ) + β N t+1 z t+1 N (0, 1) N t+1 Po (λ t ) The jump intensity parameter is now time-varying as given by the second equation. October 8th, 2013 38 / 53

Relaxing the Black-Scholes Assumptions Jump Models Hawkes Processes An example of a simulated time series with jumps. October 8th, 2013 39 / 53

Monte Carlo Pricing Methods A feature of the option price solutions is that as the assumptions of the Black-Scholes model are relaxed, such as log-normality, constant volatility and no jumps, the calculation of the option price quickly becomes more di cult using analytical methods, if not impossible. In the latter situation numerical methods based on Monte Carlo simulations are available. Consider the 5 simulated time paths of the asset reported in the previous lecture, but reported here again for convenience. 6.5 6.0 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 P1 P2 P3 P4 P5 K October 8th, 2013 40 / 53

Monte Carlo Pricing Methods This Figure 40 was based on simulating the model log p t+h log p t = r 1 2 σ2 + p σ 2 hz t+h z t+h N (0, 1) where the interest rate is r = 0.05, the volatility is σ = 0.2 and = 1/250 represents daily movements. For a 6-month option (h = 0.5) with a strike price of k = 4.8, the Black-Scholes call option price was computed numerically as c t = exp ( rh) 1 N N max (p t+h k, 0) = 0.5025 i=1 with N = 5. October 8th, 2013 41 / 53

Monte Carlo Pricing Methods The e ect of increasing the number of simulation paths N, on the price of the option are summarised in following Table??. Number of Simulation Paths (N) Option Price 5 0.5025 10 0.3822 50 0.4248 100 0.4757 200 0.4639 Analytical 0.4611 October 8th, 2013 42 / 53

Monte Carlo Pricing Methods For comparison the Black-Scholes call option price based on the analytical solution is c t = p t Φ(d) ke rh Φ(d σ p h) = 5.00 0.7041 4.80 exp ( 0.05 0.5) 0.6535 = 0.4611 where d = log(p t /k) + (r + 1 2 σ2 )h σ p h = log(5.00/4.80) + (0.05 + 0.5 0.22 ) 0.5 0.2 p 0.5 = 0.5361 while Φ(d) = Φ(0.5361) = 0.7041 and Φ(d σ p h) = Φ(0.5361 0.2 p 0.5) = Φ(0.3947) = 0.6535. October 8th, 2013 43 / 53

Monte Carlo Pricing Methods The results show that as the number of simulation paths increases the numerical price becomes more accurate. When the number of sample paths increases to N = 200, the numerical price is 0.4639, compared to the analytical price of 0.4611, an error of less than 1%. Monte Carlo methods can be made more accurate through 1. Antithetic variates (resimulate the model changing the sign of the residuals) 2. Control variates (compute the bias between an analytical solution and its simulated value). Can price options where 1. Stochastic volatility 2. Jumping behaviour 3. Nonnormalities October 8th, 2013 44 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion Introduction Asset mispricing can be particularly signi cant during periods of nancial crises and contagion. Co-dependence structures across nancial markets change dramatically during periods of nancial turbulence that extends beyond the usual changes in volatilities and correlations. Additional crisis transmission channel operating through higher order co-moments of asset returns (see Fry, Martin and Tang (JBES, 2010)), proved to be signi cant during many nancial crises. Important implications for market participants engaged in the hedging of nancial risks and for nancial regulators seeking to manage risks across the nancial institutions October 8th, 2013 45 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion Descriptive Statistics Noncrisis Subprime Great European Recession Debt US Mean 0.062-0.063-0.027 0.032 Std dev. 0.629 1.235 2.246 1.070 Skewness -0.545-0.040 0.111-0.410 France Mean 0.087-0.089-0.025-0.042 Std dev. 1.010 1.593 2.887 2.017 Skewness -0.312-0.200 0.177 0.058 Greece Mean 0.117-0.153-0.099-0.200 Std dev. 1.196 1.707 2.896 2.626 Skewness -0.479 0.049-0.202 0.388 October 8th, 2013 46 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion Descriptive Statistics (cont d) Statistics on coskewness Noncrisis Subprime Great European Recession Debt US (i = 1) France -0.200 0.089 0.001-0.030 Greece -0.181 0.237-0.238 0.095 France (i = 1) Greece -0.203-0.008-0.016 0.120 US -0.255-0.119-0.140-0.208 Greece (i = 1) France -0.168-0.120 0.040 0.035 US -0.296-0.049-0.217-0.127 October 8th, 2013 47 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion Objectives Investigate the implications of changes in the co-moments of the returns distribution that arise from contagion, in the context of pricing and hedging exchange options. Examine the potential size of mispricing from ignoring higher order co-moments of asset returns by comparing the simulated prices that allow for coskewness with the Black-Scholes price during periods of crises and contagion. Potential hedging losses from using the deltas that are derived based on the Black-Scholes price. October 8th, 2013 48 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion Approach Use exchange options to capture co-dependence. Noncrisis period is given by Black-Scholes where returns y i,t = log p i,t log p i,t 1, are bivariate normal Crisis period is represented by returns being distributed as bivariate generalized normal (GEN) f (r 1, r 2 ) = exp θ 1 r 2 1 + θ 2 r 2 2 + θ 3 r 1 r 2 + θ 4 r 3 1 + θ 5 r 2 1 r 2 +θ 6 r 1 r 2 2 + θ 7 r 3 2 + θ 8 r 4 1 + θ 9 r 4 2 η, where η is the normalising constant such that R R f (r 1, r 2 ) dr 1 r 2 = 1. To compute the option price assuming that returns are based on the generalized normal distribution, option prices are computed using Monte Carlo methods with N = 10000 simulation paths Ct GEN = exp [ rph] 1 N N max p1,t+h i i=1 p i 2,t+h, 0 October 8th, 2013 49 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion Generalized Joint Lognormal Price Distributions Associated with the bivariate GEN distribution of returns, there is the bivariate generalised lognormal distribution. Using the transformation of variable technique g (p 1,t, p 2,t ) = jjj f (ln p 1,t ln p 1,t 1, ln p 2,t ln p 2,t 1 ) where the Jacobian is jjj = 1 p 1,t p 2,t October 8th, 2013 50 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion Generalized Joint Lognormal Price Distributions The bivariate distribution of prices conditional on lagged prices is g (p 1,t, p 2,t j p 1,t 1, p 2,t 1 ) h = exp θ 1 (log p 1,t log p 1,t 1 ) 2 + θ 2 (log p 2,t log p 2,t 1 ) 2 +θ 3 (log p 1,t log p 1,t 1 ) (log p 2,t log p 2,t 1 ) +θ 4 (log p 1,t log p 1,t 1 ) 3 +θ 5 (log p 1,t log p 1,t 1 ) 2 (log p 2,t log p 2,t 1 ) +θ 6 (log p 1,t log p 1,t 1 ) (log p 2,t log p 2,t 1 ) 2 +θ 7 (log p 2,t log p 2,t 1 ) 3 + θ 8 (log p 1,t log p 1,t 1 ) 4 i +θ 9 (log p 2,t log p 2,t 1 ) 4 1 η p 1,t p 2,t October 8th, 2013 51 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion Generalized Joint Lognormal Price Distributions October 8th, 2013 52 / 53

Application to Exchange Options and Contagion E ect of Crisis and Contagion on Asset Pricing The following experiments are conducted. 1. E ect of mispricing of options when incorrectly using Black-Scholes when the true distribution is bivariate GEN. 2. E ect on delta hedging when assume the wrong distribution. 3. E ect on replicating risk free portfolios from incorrect choice of distribution. October 8th, 2013 53 / 53