Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Similar documents
1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Lévy models in finance

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

The Black-Scholes Model

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Option Pricing Models for European Options

The Black-Scholes Model

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

The stochastic calculus

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

Monte Carlo Simulations

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Non-semimartingales in finance

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Financial Economics & Insurance

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

The Black-Scholes Model

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Ṽ t (H) = e rt V t (H)

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Probability in Options Pricing

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model.

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Risk Neutral Pricing Black-Scholes Formula Lecture 19. Dr. Vasily Strela (Morgan Stanley and MIT)

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

WITH SKETCH ANSWERS. Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

1 Geometric Brownian motion

Hedging under Arbitrage

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

King s College London

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

European call option with inflation-linked strike

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Path Dependent British Options

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus With Applications

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

The Black-Scholes Equation

VII. Incomplete Markets. Tomas Björk

Financial Risk Management

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

Derivative Securities

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Deriving and Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Calculating Implied Volatility

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Risk Neutral Valuation

Option Hedging with Transaction Costs

Risk Neutral Measures

The End-of-the-Year Bonus: How to Optimally Reward a Trader?

Computational Finance

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Transcription:

Bluff our Way Through Black-Scholes Saurav Sen December 000 Contents What is Black-Scholes?.............................. 1 The Classical Black-Scholes Model....................... 1 Some Useful Background Mathematics..................... 1 Assumptions in the Classical Black-Scholes Model............... 5 The Equation ds/s = µdt + σdw........................ 6 Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation: Method I................ 6 Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation: Method II................ 7 Comparison of Methods I and II......................... 8 What is Delta-Hedging?............................. 8 Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation: Method III............... 8 Market Price of Risk or Sharpe Ratio...................... 9 Solving the Black-Scholes PDE......................... 9 Pricing a European Call Using Black-Scholes.................. 9 Why is there no µ in the Black-Scholes formula?................ 1 References..................................... 1 What is Black-Scholes? Black-Scholes is a framework for pricing options and corporate liabilities, according to the title of the 1973 paper by Fisher Black and Myron Scholes which started everything. The Classical Black-Scholes Model The so-called classical Black-Scholes model is a simplification of the general Black-Scholes framework. It is very well-known and widely used in practice, even though it has some obvious shortcomings. The main reason for this seems to be that the cost/benefit ratio of using a significantly more accurate version is too high for most everyday purposes. Specifically, the quantity that is of greatest interest is usually the volatility of stock returns, σ. Classical Black-Scholes assumes a constant σ, and empirical evidence suggests that the first generalisation which is significantly more accurate for out-of-sample data is a stochastic volatility model, where σ is determined as the solution to another stochastic differential equation SDE. Additionally, classical Black-Scholes often provides a fairly good insight into option 1

pricing anyway. For this and other reasons, we concentrate on classical Black-Scholes in the present course. Some Useful Background Mathematics 1. Brownian Motion: Brownian motion can be defined in several equivalent ways. Here is one simple definition: The process {W t : t 0 is called a Brownian motion with respect to the probability measure P if W 0 = 0 and W t has continuous sample paths. W t N P 0, t, i.e. W t is normally distributed with mean 0 and variance t under the probability measure P. W t W s N P 0, t s and is independent of the history of the process until time s. In words, Brownian motion has independent, Gaussian increments. The covariance function for a Brownian motion is calculated as follows. If t > s, E [W t W s ] = E [ ] W t W s W s + Ws = E [W t W s ] E [W s ] + E [ ] Ws = s The first term on the second line follows from independence of increments. Similarly, if s > t, then we can show that E [W t W s ] = t. Thus we have the result: E [W t W s ] = min {t, s Brownian motion is a martingale. A martingale is a constant expectation process. M t is called a P martingale if For a Brownian motion, E P t [M T ] = M t E P t [W T ] = E P t [W T W t + W t ] = E P t [W T W t ] + W t = W t The first term on the second line has expected value zero, and the second term is known at time t, hence we can write W t instead of E P t [W t ]. For other properties of Brownian motion, see the references and exercise sheets.. Ito Integrals: Ito integrals are one way of assigning meaning to the symbol I = T 0 f t, W t dw t

They are defined in a manner similar to Riemann integrals in deterministic calculus, i.e. as the limit of an approximation by discrete sums. I N 1 n=0 f t n, W tn { W tn+1 W tn Note that the function is evaluated at the left end point t n of each sub-interval. For deterministic integrals, the choice does not matter - we could choose any point in the sub-interval and the sum would converge to the same value provided the function was integrable. However, for stochastic integrals they can give different answers. The Ito definition uses the left end-point. The Stratanovich definition uses the midpoint of each subinterval, t n + t n+1 /. The Stratanovich definition has the advantage that rules of classical Newtonian calculus translate directly to the stochastic setting. However, the Ito definition is more relevant in the context of finance, since it is non-anticipating We know prices at the start of each time period - not halfway through into the future. The main thing to note about Ito integrals is that I is a random variable unlike the deterministic case. Additionally, since I is essentially the limit of a sum of normal random variables, I is normally distributed too, and can be characterised by its mean and variance. The two main results used by us are: [ ] T E f t, W 0 t dw t = 0 [ T ] E f t, W T 0 t dw t g t, W 0 t dw t = T E [f t, W 0 t g t, W t ] dt A consequence of the second property is that [ ] T E f t, W 0 t dw t = T E [ f t, W 0 t ] dt This is called the Ito isometry. 3. Ito s Lemma: Ito s lemma forms the basis for defining a set of calculus-like rules for stochastic processes. In a simple form, it says that if dx t = µ t dt + σ t dw t where µ t and σ t are F t adapted, i.e. known for sure at time t, and if f t, x is continuously differentiable once in the first argument and twice in the second, then f t, X t is also an F t adapted process, and df t, X t = { f t t, X f t + µ t x t, X t + 1 f σ t x t, X t dt + σ t f x t, X t dw t One way of deriving Ito s lemma is to Taylor-expand f, use the fact that dw dt as dt 0, and retain terms to order dt. See the exercise sheets for examples on how to apply Ito s lemma. 3

4. Moment-Generating Functions MGF s: ou can find information on MGF s in any textbook on basic probability. If X is a random variable, then its MGF is defined as M X θ := E [ e θx] = E [ 1 + θx + 1! θ X + 1 3! θ3 X 3 +... + 1 n! θn X n +... ] = 1 + θe [X] + 1! θ E [ X ] + 1 3! θ3 E [ X 3] +... + 1 n! θn E [X n ] +... The reason for the name should now be obvious: The k th moment of X is the k th derivative of the MGF, evaluated at θ = 0. One result that is particularly relevant in finance is the MGF of a normal distribution. If X N µ, σ, then Here is a proof: where φ N 0, 1. Hence M X θ = e θµ+ 1 θ σ X N µ, σ X = µ + σφ M X θ = E [ e θx] = E [ e θ{µ+σφ] = e θµ E [ e θσφ] The MGF of X is therefore equal to the MGF of φ, with θ replaced by θσ. So we calculate the easier MGF of φ : Thus E [ e θφ] = 1 π = 1 π = 1 π = 1 π = e 1 θ 1 π = e 1 θ e θx e x / dx e θx x / dx e 1 x θx+θ θ dx e 1 x θ + 1 θ dx e u / du where u = x θ M X θ = E [ e θx] = e θµ E [ e θσφ] = e θµ+ 1 θ σ 5. Kolmogorov Backward Equation: Kolmogorov s backward equation relates the solution of the PDE F t + 1 σ t, x F xx + µ t, x F x + r t F = 0 F T, x = ψ x 4

with the solution of the SDE Consider the function H t, x = F t, x exp dx = µ t, x dt + σ t, x dw { t 0 r s ds = F t, x R t F t Since R is a function of time alone, the usual product rule of differentiation can be applied dh = F dr + RdF = rf Rdt + R {F t + 1 σ F xx + µf x dt + σf x dw [ = R F t + 1 ] σ F xx + µf x + rf + σrf x dw The first term is zero because F satisfies the PDE. In integrated form H T, x T H t, x t = T Taking expectations, we have, since E [dw ] = 0, H t, x t = E t [H T, x T ] F t, x exp { t 0 r s ds F t, x = E t [ψ x exp In other words, if x is a solution of the SDE then the solution of the PDE t σ s, x R s F x s, x dw s { T = E t [F T, x exp { T t r s ds ] dx = µ t, x dt + σ t, x dw F t + 1 σ t, x F xx + µ t, x F x + r t F = 0 F T, x = ψ x 0 r s ds ] is given by { ] T F t, x = E t [ψ x exp r s ds t Note that this works even when r is stochastic! Thus we have a recipe for solving PDE s: form the appropriate SDE and then take expectations as above. For more on Kolmogorov s backward equation, see the model solutions. 5

Assumptions in the Classical Black-Scholes Model The market consists of a continuous-trading, perfectly elastic economy. Perfect elasticity means that the process driving the stock price is unaffected by swings in demand, or equivalently that all investors are price-takers. Assets are stock risky, cash riskless and a derivative defined in terms of the stock price at maturity. Efficient Market Assumption: All information about the past performance of the stock is contained in the stock price S, which is observable to all market participants. This means that the stock price is a Markov process. There are no transaction costs. Stock can be infinitely subdivided and short selling selling something you do not own is allowed, i.e. fractional and negative holdings of stock are permitted. The risk-free continuously compounded interest rate r is constant. Stock prices are assumed to evolve according to the SDE: ds S = µdt + σdw where µ and σ are constants and W is a standard Brownian motion. The price of an option at time t, which we write as V t, S is a deterministic function of t and S. The Equation ds/s = µdt + σdw The equation ds S = µdt + σdw is often referred to as the geometric Brownian motion assumption in Black-Scholes. This is because the solution to the equation is S t = S 0 e µ 1 σ t+σw which looks like geometric growth driven by a drifting Brownian motion. To see this, define = f t, S = log S. Then using Ito s lemma, we have: f t = 0; f S = 1/S; f SS = 1/S d = df t, S = f t + µsf S + 1 σ S f SS dt + σsfs dw = µ 1 σ dt + σdw i.e. d log S = µ 1 σ dt + σdw 6

We can now integrate this sum of linear differentials to get log S t log S 0 = µ 1 σ t + σw t i.e. S t = S 0 e µ 1 σ t+σw Note that unlike the deterministic case, the derivative of log S is not 1/S. See model solutions to the exercises for more on this point. µ represents the average rate of growth of the stock and σ the uncertainty. It is easy to check, using the moment generating function technique, that µt t E t S T = S t e Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation: Method I The stock price and riskless cash evolve as follows Using Ito s lemma, ds/s = µdt + σdw db/b = rdt dv = V t + 1 σ S V SS + µsv S dt + σsvs dw Want to construct a self-financing replicating portfolio x, y of x cash and y stock for this option. The value of this portfolio is In continuous time, self-financing means π = xb + ys dπ = xdb + yds To replicate, we want V and π to follow the same SDE s. dπ = xrb + yµs dt + yσsdw Matching the volatility terms of dv and dπ, we get y = V S. Now matching drift terms, we get V t + 1 σ S V SS = xrb With this choice, π = V, so we can write xb = π ys = V SV S. Substituting this into the equation above gives: which is the Black-Scholes equation. V t + 1 σ S V SS + rsv S rv = 0 7

Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation: Method II Here is a method given by Wilmott, Howison and Dewynne. Ito s lemma implies, as before: Now we construct a portfolio ds/s = µdt + σdw dv = V t + 1 σ S V SS + µsv S dt + σsvs dw Π = V S consisting of one option and short of the stock. Then dπ = dv ds = V t + 1 σ S V SS + µs V S dt + σs V S dw Choose = V S to knock out the dw term. Now the portfolio grows at a deterministic rate. By no-arbitrage, this rate must equal r, i.e. dπ = V t + 1 σ S V SS dt = rπdt = r V SVS dt Rearranging this equation gives Black-Scholes V t + 1 σ S V SS + rsv S rv = 0 Comparison of Methods I and II In method 1, we chose a self-financing portfolio of cash and stock to replicate the option. In method, we chose a portfolio of option and stock to replicate cash. What is Delta-Hedging? In finance jargon, the option delta refers to the amount of stock needed to hedge the option position. This is shown more explicitly in method, where = V S is the amount of stock that needs to be sold to make the hedged portfolio Π instantaneously riskless. In method 1, the delta is given by y = V S and here it is the amount of stock that needs to be bought, since we are replicating the option and not cash as in method. In the perfect Black-Scholes world where uncertainty is driven by a standard Brownian motion and time is continuous, delta-hedging is a perfect strategy. More realistically, the delta-hedging eliminates leading order risk. See Bjork for a description of Gamma-neutral hedging. 8

Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation: Method III In the market measure P, ds/s = µdt + σdw = rdt + σ dw + µ r σ dt is sufficiently well-behaved and it is for the constant-parameter classical Black-Scholes case, we can write dw + µ r dt as d W, a standard Brownian motion under an equivalent and σ in this case unique probability measure P. For the interested reader, this is a consequence of Girsanov s theorem. Under this new measure, If µ r σ ds/s = rdt + σd W Since the average rate of growth of the stock under this new measure is r, we recognise P to be the risk-adjusted measure. In fact, it can be verified that the relative price process Z = B 1 S is a martingale under this measure. Now if V t, S is the price of an option, then Ito s lemma gives: dv = V t + 1 σ S V SS + rsv S dt + σsvs dw In the risk-adjusted measure, all assets grow at the average rate r, i.e. we can write Ẽ [dv ] = V t + 1 σ S V SS + rsv S dt = rv dt Cancelling dt and rearranging gives the Black-Scholes equation V t + 1 σ S V SS + rsv S rv = 0 Market Price of Risk or Sharpe Ratio In the market measure, µ represents the average rate of growth of the stock. Since the stock is risky, we expect µ > r. The difference µ r measures the amount of risk inherent in the stock. σ, on the other hand, measures volatility, or market-wide risk. The quantity µ r σ therefore represents the excess return over the risk-free rate for the stock, normalised by market volatility. This is called the market price of risk. Solving the Black-Scholes PDE The Black-Scholes PDE is V t + 1 σ S V SS + rsv S rv = 0 V T, S T = ψ S T 9

Here, V t, S is the price of the derivative at time t, and its value at time T is a deterministic function of the stock price at that time. We recognise this as a Kolmogorov backward PDE, and so the solution is simply given as follows: V t, S = e rt t E Q t [ψ S T ] Here, we use the measure Q since the corresponding SDE is ds S = rdt + σdw The drift is r, which means we must be in the risk-adjusted measure. The solution of this SDE is S T = S t exp { r 1 σ T t + σw T t Thus under the measure Q, S T is lognormally distributed with parameters r 1 σ T t and σ T t, conditional on S t. In principle at least, we can now evaluate the expectation and price the derivative in one step. There is of course another way to solve the Black-Scholes PDE, by transforming it to a standard heat equation. A very good outline of this method can be found in Wilmott, Howison & Dewynne, so it is not repeated here. Pricing a European Call Using Black-Scholes A European call option is a contract that gives its holder the right but no obligation to buy a unit of the underlying stock for a specified price K, called the strike price, at a specified future date T called the maturity date, but not before that hence, European. The payoff from a European call is ψ S = max {S K, 0 Black and Scholes showed that the price of such an option is given by C t, S; T, K = SΦ d 1 Ke rt t Φ d where Φ. stands for the cumulative distibution of a standard Gaussian random variable N 0, 1, and d 1, = log S/K + r ± 1 σ T t σ T t To prove this, we use the Kolmogorov solution C t, S; T, K = e rt t E Q t [max {S K, 0] 10

Write w X x for the probability density function of the random variable X. Then C = e rt t max {S K, 0 w S S ds 0 = e rt t S K w S S ds K = e rt t Sw S S ds Ke rt t w S S ds K = Term I - Term II Term II = Ke rt t Pr [S T > K] = Ke rt t Pr [log S T > ] [ = Ke rt t Pr log S t + r 1σ T t + σ ] T tφ > [ = Ke rt t Pr φ > /S t r 1σ ] T t σ T t [ = Ke rt t Pr φ > log S/K r 1σ ] T t σ T t = Ke rt t 1 Φ d = Ke rt t Φ d Term I = e rt t Sw S S ds K = e rt t K e w d where = log S. Now since is normally distributed, rt t { e [ r 1 Term I = exp σ T t ] d πσ T t σ T t t { e rt = exp d πσ = = = = = t e rt πσ t e rt πσ t e rt πσ t e rt πσ e rt t πσ e µ + 1 σ { exp 1 [ µ ] σ σ { exp 1 σ { exp 1 σ { exp 1 σ exp σ + µ + µ d µ + σ + µ + σ µ + σ + µ d [ µ + σ ] µ + σ + µ d [ µ + σ ] µ σ σ 4 d { 1 σ [ µ + σ 11 ] d

Now we have µ + 1 σ = log S t + r 1 σ T t + 1 σ T t = log S t + r T t Therefore, e rt t e µ + 1 σ = e log St = S t Additionally, if we write U = µ + σ = log S t r + 1 σ T t Then 1 { exp 1 πσ T t σ 1 = πσ log St r+ 1 σ T t [ µ + σ exp { U du σ ] d Now if we write Z = U/σ, then the above integral becomes Therefore, 1 π /St r+ 1 σ T t = Pr [ σ T t e 1 Z dz φ > /S t r + 1 σ T t σ T t = Pr [φ > d 1 ] = 1 Φ d 1 = Φ d 1 Term I = SΦ d 1 Adding Term I and Term II, we have the result C t, S; T, K = SΦ d 1 Ke rt t Φ d ] 1

Why is there no µ in the Black-Scholes formula? Black-Scholes prices derivatives in terms of the underlying stock. If we wanted to price the stock itself, we d need to know µ. Stock returns are assumed to be normally distributed, and a normal distribution can be described completely by its mean and variance. Since we ultimately take expectations, we can knock out the first moment of returns, and so the price of a derivative is now explicitly dependent on the stock price itself and the second moment of returns, i.e. the volatility. A useful analogy is that the definition of a metre itself might be fairly tricky, but once it is unambiguously defined, we can measure the length of a room precisely in terms of metres. Black-Scholes does not attempt to price stocks. Rather, it uses the price of the underlying as given and prices derivatives in terms of this underlying stock price. References 1. Arbitrage Theory in Continuous Time by Tomas Bjork covers basic stochastic calculus and the Black-Scholes model. See this book also for a discussion on the greeks - delta, gamma, vega and rho.. The Mathematics of Financial Derivatives by Wilmott, Howison and Dewynne has a good overview of the PDE techniques for solving the Black-Scholes equation. 3. Stochastic Calculus by Bernt Oksendal has an excellent introduction to Ito calculus. 13