BALL STATE UNIVERSITY CENTER FOR BUSINESS AND ECONOMIC RESEARCH

Similar documents
The Relative Tax Burden on Indiana s Business

National Report. About Conexus Indiana. About Ball State CBER 2013 MANUFACTURING + LOGISTICS

Public Finance: The Economics of Taxation. The Economics of Taxation. Taxes: Basic Concepts

WikiLeaks Document Release

Total state and local business taxes

2018 Manufacturing & Logistics Report Card for the United States

2016 Manufacturing & Logistics Report Card for the United States

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States

ECONOMIC SURVEY OF NEW ZEALAND 2007: TWO BROAD APPROACHES FOR TAX REFORM

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

Governor LePage s Tax Reform and Relief Plan

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

Impact of removing stamp duties on insurance. Insurance Council of Australia

DRAFT RESPONSE DOCUMENT 2018 DRAFT RATES AND MONETARY AMOUNTS AND AMENDMENT OF REVENUE LAWS BILL (RATES BILL) Non-VAT issues

Tax and fairness. Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group

Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment in Open Economies

TAX REVENUE VOLATILITY AND A STATE-WIDE EDUCATION SALES TAX

A FLAT RATE INCOME TAX IN GEORGIA

Chapter 9 Sources of Government Revenue

MODERNIZATION OF ARIZONA S SALES TAX

BUOYANCY OF GEORGIA S SALES AND USE TAX

CASE FAIR OSTER PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N. PEARSON 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

CHAPTER 9 Sources of Government Revenue

Martina Lawless and Donal Lynch Scenarios and Distributional Implications of a Household Wealth Tax in Ireland 1

GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES FISCAL RESEARCH PROGRAM MARCH 11, 1998

The Effects of Ageing on the Financing of Social Health Provision. Chris Heady 26 th March 2013

Indiana Lags United States in Per Capita Income

The Cost of Compromise: Impact of the Estate Tax

Submission to the Independent Tax Review Committee, Newfoundland and Labrador

COMMENTARY NUMBER 776 November Durable Goods Orders, New-Home Sales December 23, 2015

Report to Governor s Blue Ribbon Commission on Tax Reform by Economic Consultants

CORPORATE TAX REVENUE BUOYANCY

Economic Brief. When Did the Recession End?

STATE CORPORATE INCOME TAXES GENERALLY

A Look at Voter-Approval Requirements for Local Taxes

Example 19.1 The Value Added Tax

Submission to the Federal Tax Discussion Paper. Prepared by the Urban Development Institute of Australia (UDIA)

GEORGIA S CORPORATE TAXES : SHOLD THE CORPORATE INCOME TAX BE REPEALED. Martin F. Grace

INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES

Human Capital and Labor Force Participation on the South Georgia Coast

June 19, I hope this information is helpful to you. The CBO staff contacts are Frank Sammartino and Terry Dinan. Sincerely,

REVENUE STRUCTURES OF STATES WITHOUT AN INCOME TAX*

COMMENTARY NUMBER 601 January Housing Starts, PPI February 19, Unstable Housing Starts Showed a Corrective Plunge in January

Public choice theory explains and interprets politics as the interaction among

AN ANALYSIS OF PROPOSED NEW ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT INITIATIVE. Kelly D. Edmiston David L. Sjoquist Jeanie Thomas

ADVANCE COMMENTARY NUMBER 930-A. December Labor, Private Surveying and M3, November Trade Deficit and Construction Spending January 5, 2018

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report)

Principles of a good tax system. Jason Mercier Director, Center for Government Reform Washington Policy Center Tri-Cities Office

Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review

Internet Appendix for. Fund Tradeoffs. ĽUBOŠ PÁSTOR, ROBERT F. STAMBAUGH, and LUCIAN A. TAYLOR

AP Microeconomics Chapter 16 Outline

Written Testimony of Scott A. Hodge, President, Tax Foundation

INTRODUCTION TAXES: EQUITY VS. EFFICIENCY WEALTH PERSONAL INCOME THE LORENZ CURVE THE SIZE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME

A Dynamic Analysis of President Obama s Tax Initiatives

The U.S. Current Account Balance and the Business Cycle

Repeal of the State and Local Tax Deduction

Payroll giving: providing a real-time benefit for charitable giving

Topic# 3: General Theory of Taxation. Romanian tax system General theory of taxation PROF. ANDREEA STOIAN, PHD LECTURE 5

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Labor s Declining Share of Income and Rising Inequality. Margaret Jacobson and Filippo Occhino

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies

POTENTIAL EFFECT OF ELIMINATING THE STATE CORPORATE INCOME TAX ON STATE ECONOMIC ACTIVITY

The Beacon Hill Institute

METHODOLOGY. Who Pays? A Distributional Analysis of the Tax Systems in All 50 States, 6th Edition

DECREASING NUMBER OF PUBLIC COMPANIES

ROTARIAN ECONOMIST BRIEF No Analysis and Commentary for Service Above Self

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

A Brief History of Tax Expenditures

TAX POLICY: RECENT TRENDS AND REFORMS IN OECD COUNTRIES FOREWORD

Total state and local business taxes

Gambling with policy

The Economic Effects of the Estate Tax

Thinking Through the Economic Consequences of Higher Taxes

We are IntechOpen, the world s leading publisher of Open Access books Built by scientists, for scientists. International authors and editors

Session three: Revenue Raising and Base Broadening 16 September 2009

Qualified Research Activities

POLICY BRIEF. Monetary Policy as a Jobs Guarantee. Joshua R. Hendrickson July 2018

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand

Chapter URL:

Feldstein Proposal Increases Federal Revenues but the Devil s in the Details

This publication is a slight revision of four news releases recently made available to Oregon newspapers.

Oil Industry Tax and Deficit Issues

Summary An issue in the development of the new health care reform plan is the effect on small business. One concern is the effect of a pay or play man

A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax

14-1: How Taxes Work NOTES

COMMENTARY NUMBER Household Income, August Housing Starts September 18, 2013

THE OECD S REPORT ON HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION JOANN M. WEINER * & HUGH J. AULT **

Modeling Tax Reform in Maine. Outline of Presentation

Assessing Public D&O Industry Performance

How Pension Funds Manage Investment Risks: A Global Survey

MICHIGAN RENAISSANCE ZONE ACT Act 376 of 1996

Employer-Sponsored Health Insurance in the Minnesota Long-Term Care Industry:

statistical appendix A Study of the Efficiency, Effectiveness, and Regional Equity of the IEDC

Emerging markets: Individual country or broad-market exposure?

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

Chapter 12 TAXES AND TAX POLICY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

A summary of economic events, data, and trends published by the Community Research Institute. Allen County Labor Force

GENERAL ASSEMBLY OF NORTH CAROLINA SECOND EXTRA SESSION 1996 CHAPTER 13 HOUSE BILL 18

Research Library. Treasury-Federal Reserve Study of the U. S. Government Securities Market

GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES FISCAL RESEARCH CENTER May 14, 1999

THE GEORGIA INDIVIDUAL TAX : CURRENT STRUCTURE AND IMPACT OF PROPOSED CHANGES. Barbara M. Edwards

Transcription:

BALL STATE UNIVERSITY CENTER FOR BUSINESS AND ECONOMIC RESEARCH POLICY BRIEF JUNE 2014 RESEARCH+OUTREACH Tax Simplicity & a Sound Tax System in Michael J. Hicks, PhD Director, Center for Business and Economic Research and Professor of Economics, Miller College of Business Dagney Faulk, PhD Director of Research, Center for Business and Economic Research Ball State University Prepared for the 2014 Tax Competitiveness and Simplification Conference, June 24, 2014 THE SIMPLICITY OF A TAX SYSTEM has long been viewed as an important, universal aspect of sound tax policy. However, other goals of tax policy do exist. These include the stability of revenues, which provide certainty to governments and taxpayers and neutrality, or a tax system that minimally distorts economic decisions. As may be evident, the goal of simplicity in a tax system may conflict with the stability and neutrality of a tax system. Balancing these competing goals should be part of a comprehensive review of a tax system and any effort towards achieving overall improvements in a tax system. Extreme simplicity in a tax system could be achieved by applying a single tax, with a single rate, on a single activity. Flat consumption or payroll taxes are common examples of this. However, the simplicity gains of such a system come at the expense of stability and neutrality. A single tax instrument will obviously lead to highly unstable tax revenues as structural or cyclical changes in economic activity alter the size of the tax base. s experience with gaming-related tax revenues, or national revenues from FICA taxes during the Great Recession, provide two examples of simple, but unstable, revenue sources. Tax revenues drawn from a single source, or fewer sources, are also less neutral than a tax system drawn from multiple tax instruments or activities. This is true for two reasons. First, the effects of tax rates on behavior are not linear. A 10 percent marginal tax rate will likely distort behavior more than twice as heavily as a 5 percent marginal tax rate. (1) Because a single tax instrument will have a higher rate than a broader set of taxes when providing the same level of revenue, it will necessarily be more distortionary. (2) Second, fewer tax instruments apply to a more narrow tax base. For example, a tax on payroll applies only to earned income, not to accumulated wealth, consumption, or transfer payments. This, too, necessarily results in a more distortionary or less neutral tax system that collects the same level of revenues against a more narrow base incentives firms and households to alter their type of economic activity in response to higher relative tax rates. For example a single payroll tax would incentivize the shift to a more capitalintensive production process by businesses that will bear part of the burden. This will reduce the demand 2014. Center for Business and Economic Research, Ball State University. 1. See MacKie-Mason 1990 for a theoretical example. 2. There are also equity issues associated with broadening the tax base that are not addressed here. 1

for labor. Likewise, households who pay part of the tax will reduce their labor supply in response to lower real compensation. It is important to note that the actual incidence of the tax is not solely dependent upon the administrative incidence of the tax. For example, while the sales tax is collected on consumers, both consumers and producers pay part of the tax because the existence of a sales tax will influence pricing and consumption decisions. Achieving both tax stability and neutrality involves what is likely the most strongly held belief regarding a good tax system that it should enjoy low rates and a broad base. The low rate, broad base feature of a tax system enables it to tax the most activity, thus lowering any one particular rate. This make the tax system less sensitive to business cycles or structural changes in the economy, and it makes it less likely to distort the behaviors of businesses or households as they seek to avoid taxes. However, a low rate, broad base characteristic of a tax system conflicts with overall simplicity in a tax system. To accommodate this, economic research has tended to focus on the simplicity of individual tax instruments and their effect on compliance costs. The remainder of this policy brief explores these two issues in. We begin with some brief empirics on the simplicity of individual tax systems, with an eye on. Here we argue that there are gains to be made in compliance cost reductions, but leave specific recommendations to others. In the following section, we review the overall balance of tax instruments, with a focus on the current conditions and their implications for. Finally, we summarize and conclude with additional areas of research. Tax Simplicity in taxes income, consumption, and wealth. Income is primarily taxed through state personal income taxes levied on households and non-corporate businesses, although there are six local option taxes levied on income as well. Corporations are taxed through the corporate income tax. Consumption is taxed through a sales tax on goods and an excise tax on some fuels. Businesses pay a high share of these taxes, perhaps 44 percent of sales tax (Thaiprasert, Faulk, and Hicks 2013), while households from and elsewhere pay the remainder. Services and some goods are not taxed. Wealth is taxed through a local tax on property, both real and personal on households and businesses. Counties in assess these taxes with between five and 61 separate taxing districts (Faulk and Hicks 2011). The result is that a typical individual tax parcels may be subject to tax levies from between 6 and 12 different tax districts. Two important goals of tax simplicity are first to reduce uncertainty by taxpayers regarding their tax obligations and second to reduce compliance costs. Compliance costs can accrue to taxpayers in business and households and to government. The complexity of s local government property taxes offers an insight into the size and scope of compliance costs to government. Two important goals of tax simplicity are 1.) to reduce uncertainty by taxpayers regarding their tax obligations and 2.) to reduce compliance costs. Tax rates are constitutionally capped, and local governments set budgetary needs for up to 61 separate units of governments in a county. Because these governments overlap, the share of taxes paid by an individual parcel is not visible to local governments. The budgetary requests are forwarded to the Department of Local Government Finance, which then compiles individual parcel obligations from which the share of taxes to each overlapping taxing district is calculated. This atypically cumbersome system involves the creation of a separate state agency simply to process local taxes. In addition to imposing high administrative costs on state government, the system reduces the ability of local governments to manage their fiscal environments. Taxpayer compliance costs are also influenced by tax simplicity. Several studies have identified the role of tax complexity in increasing transactions costs for businesses, reducing certainty about tax liability and reducing investment. (3) One method of chronicling this effect is to link a measure of tax complexity to direct expenditures related to tax compliance. We do this in two ways. First, we provide a simple graphic between a measure of tax complexity created by the Progressive Policy Institute (Weinstein 2014) at the state level to the number of workers listed as tax preparers per 1,000 workers in each state, using the 2013 Occupational and Employment Classifications of the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Importantly, a low number in this index implies high tax complexity or low simplicity. Figure 1 ranks the tax complexity score for states with an income tax against the number of tax preparers per 1,000 workers in a state. It is clear from this data that there is a strong correlation between the tax complexity index ranking and the number of tax preparers per 1,000 employees. This suggests that higher tax complexity requires 3. See Edmiston, Mudd, and Valev 2003; and Warksett, Winer, and Hettich 1998. 2

Figure 1. PPI Tax Complexity Score and Tax Preparers per 1,000 Employees 1.0 Figure 3. Relative Tax Rates and Relative Tax Bases Base Income $223B 34.36% Base Consumption $160B 24.64% Tax Complexity Score 0.8 0.6 0.4 Income Tax $4.47B 34.05% Sales Tax $2.62B 20.00% Property Tax $6.03B 45.96% 0.2 Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics and Progressive Policy Institute. Figure 2. Log (Tax Instruction and Form Pages) and Tax Preparers per 1,000 Employees Log Instructions 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, state departments of revenue, and author calculations. Tax Preparers per 1,000 People 0.0 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 Tax Preparers per 1,000 People households and businesses to employ or contract with more specialized tax preparers, a very clear proxy for higher compliance costs in more complex tax systems. In a second approach, we compiled the number of instructional and tax form pages for each state s income tax form. For visual ease, we report the logarithm of the number of total instructional and tax form pages for each state, and plot them against the number of tax preparers per 1,000 employees in a state. See Figure 2. This graphic clearly indicates that there is a positive correlation between the number of instruction and tax form pages in each state s income tax and the number of tax preparers per 1,000 employees in a state. This is further evidence that tax complexity increases the cost of compliance by households and businesses. These visual comparisons of the relationship between complex taxes and higher compliance costs for businesses provide anecdotal Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Department of Local Government Finance, Department of Revenue, and author calculations. Base Wealth $266B 41.00% evidence of a problem that is potentially solvable through policy intervention. The higher quality scholarly work in this area of the type cited earlier suggests a review of tax simplification for compliance with individual tax instruments in is warranted. Does Have a Broad Tax Base? Examining s tax instruments across different taxes is outside the scope of this brief, but a preliminary snapshot of the tax base suggests some areas of improvement. In examining three large taxes sales, property, and income we can compare the total taxes against a proxy for the tax base in each case. See Figure 3. For sales tax, we find that while the state collects a 7 percent sales tax on goods, the taxable sales in the state is only 16 percent of personal income in 2010. This suggests that a significant base of sales taxes may not be subject to taxes. These include health care expenditures, food, and services. Including these estimates into the tax base yields an effective tax rate on all potentially sales taxable items of 1.6 percent. However, for most goods the tax rate is 7 percent, and for most services it is zero percent. Similar calculations against the income taxes collected, and total income and property taxes collected against total net assessed value (property minus exemptions) provide effective tax rates of 2.0 percent and 2.3 percent respectively. We also estimate the distribution of taxes across all instruments as a measure of the share of total tax revenues draw from separate economic activities. Using a tool known as the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, we provide a relative index of the concentration of the state s total tax revenues on different tax instruments. The HHI is the sum of the squared share (expressed from 0 to 100) of each major tax instrument. If all taxes are collected from a single tax instrument, the index would be 10,000. As total taxes are collected evenly against more tax instruments the index decline, and so offers a relative degree of collection of taxes against a base. The higher the number, the more 3

Figure 4. Tax Revenue HHI,* 1950-2013 Herfindahl-Hirschman Index 10,000 8,000 6,000 4,000 2,000 0 '50s '60s '70s '80s National Average '90s '00s * HHI: The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index is the sum of the squared share (expressed from 0 to 100) of each major tax instrument. If all taxes are collected from a single tax instrument, the index would be 10,000. Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census and author calculations. '10s narrow the tax base; the lower the number, the broader the tax base. Figure 4 illustrates this for and the average U.S. state from 1950 through 2013. Figure 4 clearly illustrates that s tax revenues have become more concentrated since 2001, meaning that the bulk of revenue is raised from fewer sources. In 1950, was the 12th most concentrated tax state. At its peak in 1961, was the second most concentrated state for tax revenues, behind only South Dakota. In 2001, when had the most broadly spread taxes relative to other states, it ranked 14th, and by 2013 it had moved to 8th place behind only states without an income tax. Economic research has not yet convincingly connected the broad base benefit of a tax system to overall economic performance, such as GDP or personal income growth. However, very high levels of tax collected on one instrument tend to offer a less neutral overall tax system. In s case, the narrow sales tax base is an obvious target for policy consideration. Indeed, a broad expansion of the sales tax base to include all non-business services would likely permit the sales tax rate to be reduced to between 4 percent and 5 percent without reducing overall tax revenues. Summary The goals of tax simplicity are well recognized and enjoy broad agreement among tax researchers of all stripes. However, improvements in s tax code should target individual compliance costs for existing tax instruments. A possible more urgent problem for is that the current tax base is far narrower, with tax revenues collected less broadly across differing tax instruments than is typical in other states. This argues for a broadening of the tax base as part of an overall review of the tax code, in concert with efforts to succeed at tax simplification. In this context, we have discussed both simplifications in individual instruments and broadening of the tax base (which is often referred to as reduced simplicity across instruments) as a potential policy goal. We believe a tax code that is easier to administer and comply with, and one that has a broader base and lower rates is a non-partisan improvement in our tax code. We are not so naïve to suppose there will be no interest group opposition to both steps, especially among those whose business models thrive on tax complexity and among businesses and occupations who provide services that are not subject to sales taxes. Still, we recommend the legislature seriously consider a broad suite of options in both areas. Finally, we have discussed these changes within the context of revenue neutrality. Unlike national tax schemes, which are levied against factors of production and households who are relatively immobile, and for whom the benefit of services is diffuse and not immediately clear, this policy brief is about state and local taxes. It should be clear that at the state and local level, overall marginal tax rates are lower, and thus less distortionary; services such as schools, infrastructure and public safety are more immediately observable; and businesses and households balance both tax rates and the quality of services when making location decisions. We frame this discussion within the context of revenue neutrality, because in our judgment, while the tax rates are favorable to both households and business relocation to, the quality of services plays a larger role in the prosperity of many regions. So, for, tax revenues effectively allocated to service quality improvements are a more immediate concern than reductions in the overall effective tax rate. For, tax revenues effectively allocated to service quality improvements are a more immediate concern than reductions in the overall effective tax rate. 4

References Edmiston, Kelly, Shannon Mudd, and Neven Valev. 2003. Tax structures and FDI: The deterrent effects of complexity and uncertainty. Fiscal Studies 24,(3): 341-359. Faulk, Dagney Gail, and Michael J. Hicks. 2011. Local government consolidation in the United States. Cambria Press. MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K. 1990. Some nonlinear tax effects on asset values and investment decisions under uncertainty. Journal of Public Economics 42(3): 301-327. Thaiprasert, Nalitra, Dagney Faulk, and Michael J. Hicks. 2013. A Regional Computable General Equilibrium Analysis of Property Tax Rate Caps and a Sales Tax Rate Increase in. Public Finance Review 41(4): 446-472. Warskett, George, Stanley L. Winer, and Walter Hettich. 1998. The complexity of tax structure in competitive political systems. International Tax and Public Finance 5(2): 123-151. Weinstein, Jr. Paul. 2014. The State Tax Complexity Index: A new Tool for Tax Reform and Simplification. Progressive Policy Institute, Policy Memo, April 2014. BALL STATE UNIVERSITY CENTER FOR BUSINESS AND ECONOMIC RESEARCH About the Center for Business and Economic Research Ball State University s Center for Business and Economic Research conducts timely economic policy research, analysis, and forecasting for a public audience. CBER research includes public finance, regional economics, manufacturing, transportation, and energy sector studies. We produce the CBER Data Center, a site featuring a suite of data tools, and the Business Bulletin, a weekly newsletter with commentary and dozens of regularly updated economic indicators. Center for Business and Economic Research Ball State University (WB 149) 2000 W. University Ave. Muncie, IN 47306-0360 Phone: 765-285-5926 Email: cber@bsu.edu 5 www.bsu.edu/cber