Debts and Deficits How much is Labour to blame?

Similar documents
Budget 2011: A case of tunnel vision

WHEN REBALANCING GOES BAD

Number 2: The UK Spending Deficit What is it and must it be eliminated now?

THE CHANCELLOR S CHOICES

Deficit Reduction Averaging A Plan B for fiscal tightening

Deficit Reduction and the Role of Taxes

End of year fiscal report. November 2008

Advanced Subsidiary Unit 2: Managing the Economy

SAVING, INVESTMENT, AND THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM

23/03/2012. Government Budgets

In January 2017 UK Public sector net debt is 1,682.8 billion equivalent to 85.3% of GDP

Irish Economy and Growth Legal Framework for Growth and Jobs High Level Workshop, Sofia

Spending Review Overview

Chapter 16: Financing Government Section 2

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

Øystein Olsen: The economic outlook

Economic Policy in the Crisis. Lars Calmfors Jönköping International Business School, 2 November 2009

The fiscal response to the currency crisis and the challenges ahead - Korea s experience

Fiscal Policy with a Fiscal Rule

Consumer Debt and Money Report Q making business sense

A wealth tax for Ireland

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 8. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II

Investing in Clean Energy

OCR Economics A-level

What next after the general election?

Designing fiscal targets for the UK

AQA Economics A-level

PUBLIC FINANCE IN THE EU: FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT

Advanced Subsidiary Unit 2: Managing the Economy. Wednesday 18 January 2012 Morning Time: 1 hour 30 minutes

RESEARCH NOTE 27 BUDGET 2008 REPORT

Irish Employment Trends, Competitiveness or Structural Shifts?

Irish Economic Environment. Contact Details. Office Hours: by appointment KB3-46

Basel III market and regulatory compromise

Schroders Investing in Property During and After a Recession

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Denmark. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

Tax cuts that broke the budget

Progress. Economic Performance Under Presidents. Bill Clinton and George W. Bush

Lecture 7. Unemployment and Fiscal Policy

A-level ECONOMICS Unit 4 The National and International Economy

U.S. Fiscal Policy in the 1990s

Practical Problems with Discretionary Fiscal Policy

CHARTS MAY 7, 2013 WASHINGTON, D.C.

forever blowing bubbles?

Rebuilding of the European and US Economy and Japan. Richard C. Koo Chief Economist Nomura Research Institute Tokyo January 2012

The Swedish Fiscal Framework and the Fiscal Policy Council. Lars Calmfors Workshop on Fiscal Rules and Institutions OECD, 22 March, 2010

The Coalition s Record on Housing: Policy, Spending and Outcomes

Capping Welfare. One bill two caps. Matthew Oakley. June 2013

Fiscal Policy. Changes in federal taxes and purchases

OCR Economics AS-level

Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden

Economics Sixth Edition

! March 1929-Pres. Herbert Hoover. ! Credit

The end of deficit reduction? Thomas Pope

1 What does sustainability gap show?

Chapter 10: Money and Banking Section 2

Karnit Flug: Macroeconomic policy and the performance of the Israeli economy

The grass is greener to the East

Not just a crash diet: Improving public finances through structural reform

Stephanie Kelton: National Debt Washington s Wall Against Progress

OCR Economics A-level

Imbalances in the Euro Area

Each month, the Office for National

AQA Economics A-level

The Fiscal Cliff Lessons from the 1930s

15 th. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson. First page. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson

CIE Economics AS-level

Does the Riksbank have to make a profit?

chapter: Solution Fiscal Policy

Debt Facts and Figures - Compiled 4 th May 2006

Danske Bank March 1 ST 2016 Economic Update,

A European Unemployment Insurance Scheme? An Interview with Sebastian Dullien

SAVING, INVESTMENT, AND THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM

Petrodollars, the Savings Bust, and the U.S. Current Account Deficit

Convergence Programme for the United Kingdom: submitted in line with the Stability and Growth Pact

Introduction to the UK Economy

YouGov / The Sun Survey Results

How to avoid a double-dip recession in the eurozone

5+1 charts on how Hungary can catch up with France

1 Executive summary. Overview

4 Does trade hold the key to the UK services productivity puzzle? 1

growth but still remains at approximately 1.5% of potential GDP.

TRADE UNION MEMBERSHIP Statistical Bulletin

MINISTRY OF EDUCATION AND SCIENCE OF UKRAINE NATIONAL TECHNICAL UNIVERSITY KHARKIV POLYTECHNIC INSTITUTE

FINANCIAL TRANSACTION TAX: COUNCILLOR S GUIDE EVERYTHING YOU NEED

Lecture 14 and 15: Budget Deficits, Surpluses, and the Public Debt Reference Chapter 10 LEARNING OBJECTIVES

The U.S. Economy: An Optimistic Outlook, But With Some Important Risks

Chapter 10: Money and Banking Section 1

Fiscal Policy - the basics:

AP Gov Chapter 17 Outline

Tax Reform: Informing the debate

UK membership of the single currency

Economic aspects of Scottish independence: public spending and revenue

BCC UK Economic Forecast Q4 2015

Outlook for Scotland s Public Finances and the Opportunities of Independence. May 2014

Wednesday 22 May 2013 Afternoon

Institute for Public Policy Research LIFTING THE CAP THE FISCAL AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF LIFTING THE NHS PAY CAP. Joe Dromey and Alfie Stirling

Recaping the effects of both Fiscal policy and Monetary policy in the long run

BALANCING THE FEDERAL BUDGET: ECONOMIC RATIONALE AND ISSUES

The Macro-economy and the Global Financial Crisis

Transcription:

briefing Debts and Deficits How much is Labour to blame? Tony Dolphin January 2011 ippr 2011 Institute for Public Policy Research Challenging ideas Changing policy

About ippr The Institute for Public Policy Research (ippr) is the UK s leading progressive think tank, producing cutting-edge research and innovative policy ideas for a just, democratic and sustainable world. Since 1988, we have been at the forefront of progressive debate and policymaking in the UK. Through our independent research and analysis we define new agendas for change and provide practical solutions to challenges across the full range of public policy issues. With offices in both London and Newcastle, we ensure our outlook is as broad-based as possible, while our international work extends our partnerships and influence beyond the UK, giving us a truly world-class reputation for high-quality research. ippr, 4th Floor, 13 14 Buckingham Street, London WC2N 6DF +44 (0)20 7470 6100 info@ippr.org www.ippr.org Registered charity no. 800065 This paper was first published in January 2011. 2011 The contents and opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors only. About the author Tony Dolphin is Senior Economist and Associate Director for Economic Policy at ippr.

ippr Debts and Deficits: How much is Labour to blame? Summary Analysis of the historical data on debts and deficits shows the UK s fiscal position in 2007 08, immediately ahead of the recent recession, was reasonably sound. On George Osborne s preferred deficit measure the cyclically-adjusted current budget there was a deficit of just 0.6 per cent of GDP (less than 10 billion) in 2007 08. On this same measure, the deficit between 1997 98 and 2007 08 averaged precisely zero in line with the target set by George Osborne for 2015 16. Figure 1 Labour s mistakes ahead of the financial crisis were to underestimate the risk of a recession and not to realise how much reliance it was placing on revenues from sources associated with rampant lending. The vast bulk of the current deficit arose in the recession as a result of the loss of a significant portion of these revenues, discretionary measures taken by the Labour government to reduce the length and depth of the recession, and the loss of tax revenues and increases in welfare spending normally associated with economic downturns. Context The Coalition government has sought to blame its Labour predecessor for Britain s current fiscal position by referring persistently to Labour s debts and Labour s deficit and accusing it of not fixing the roof while the sun was shining. More recently, there have also been accusations that the deficit was, at least in part, due to excessive spending by the last Labour government even before the recession of 2008 and 2009. The Labour opposition refuses to accept the blame. Reports of a recent shadow cabinet meeting suggest its strategy is to insist the deficit was not caused by overspending or fiscal carelessness. It will continue to argue that deficits have increased in all developed economies as a result of the financial collapse and recession, and that the government s finances were in a healthy position before the crisis began. However, Labour will take responsibility for inadequate regulation of the banks and allowing the economy to become unbalanced. Data and key points This briefing looks at the numbers on debt, deficits and spending (relative to GDP) over time in the UK and comparing the UK with other developed economies in an attempt to establish which side is right.

2 ippr Debts and Deficits: How much is Labour to blame? The data are sourced as follows: Fiscal year data for the UK up to 2008 09: from the June 2010 Budget, Tables C15 and C16 Fiscal year data for the UK from 2009 10 onwards: from the Office for Budget Responsibility s Economic and fiscal outlook, November 2010, Tables 1.2, 4.2, 4.14 and 4.23 Calendar year data for central government spending: from the ONS public sector finances time series database Data on developed countries: from the OECD Economic Outlook 88 (December 2010) statistical annex. Time series charts highlight 1996 97 (or 1996) as the position inherited by Labour when it took office in 1997 and 2007 08 (or 2007) as the pre-crisis position. The key points that emerge from the charts are: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. There were two distinct periods for fiscal policy under Labour. Debts, deficits and spending were cut quite aggressively relative to GDP during the first four or five years that Labour was in power. Subsequently, deficits widened and debt increased, though in 2007 08 they were smaller than in 1996 97. Current spending relative to GDP in 2007 08 was little different from 1996 97 but investment spending, and thus total managed spending, was higher. Spending on interest and social benefits fell; other current spending, particularly on health, education and policing, increased. Other countries also reduced their debts and deficits between 1996 and 2007, and the UK moved up the ranking of developed countries in terms of debt and spending, and down the ranking in terms of its financial balance. The recession led to a significant drop in revenues (by 2.0 per cent of GDP) and increase in spending (by 6.6 per cent of GDP). These were partly discretionary (such as the temporary cut in the standard rate of VAT and higher investment spending) and partly the result of automatic stabilisers (the effect of lower economic activity on tax revenues and benefit spending). The effect of the recession on the UK s public finances appears to have been relatively large, due to the economy s reliance on financial services for growth and government revenues ahead of the banking crisis. The cyclically-adjusted current budget balance which George Osborne has set himself the target of reducing to zero over rolling five-year periods was in deficit by 0.6 per cent of GDP in 2007 08. (The actual balance was in deficit by 0.3 per cent). Over the 11 years of Labour government prior to the recession, the average balance on this measure was zero. The position in 2007 08 can, therefore, be summarised as follows: Government receipts were higher than in 1996 97 (relative to GDP). Current government spending was at the same level as in 1996 97 and a little less than government receipts, so the deficit on the current budget was smaller. Given the position in the economic cycle, it is arguable that spending should have been a little less than receipts. 2 Investment spending was significantly higher than in 1996 97 and had been increasing for seven years. The run on Northern Rock was, of course, in 2007 so the crisis could be said to have started during 2007 08. However, the recession began in the second quarter of 2008. 2 In money terms, spending would have to have been 9 billion lower or receipts 9 billion higher (or some mix of the two) to achieve cyclically-adjusted current balance.

3 ippr Debts and Deficits: How much is Labour to blame? As a result, public sector net borrowing averaged 2.7 per cent of GDP between 2002 03 and 2007 08 and public sector net debt was increasing. Public sector net debt remained below 40 per cent of GDP and below its level in 1996 97. Conclusion On the basis of these numbers, Labour s fiscal profligacy just ahead of the recession would seem to have been on a very limited scale. Current spending might have been about 10 billion lower (or revenues 10 billion higher). And, while it was reasonable to borrow to finance a high level of investment spending at the time, within a few years either this spending would have had to have been reduced or receipts would have had to have been increased to fund it. Labour did, however, make two mistakes. First, the rhetoric around no more boom and bust left it unprepared to acknowledge that, after 15 uninterrupted years of economic growth, it might be sensible to have some margin of error in its plans for the possibility of an economic downturn. 3 Second, and for similar reasons, it appears to have been blind to the reliance it was placing on revenues from sources associated with rampant lending, such the City and the housing market. Again, greater awareness might have suggested more caution. But the charges that the Coalition are tackling Labour s debt and Labour s deficits, or that Labour let spending run out of control before the recession, do not stack up. Deficits increased and debt soared during the recession, not before it. Ascribe blame for the recession and there are plenty of candidates to choose from, including governments, central banks, Chinese savings, financial regulators, banks, credit-rating agencies, sub-prime mortgage lenders and greedy householders and you have also ascribed blame for the vast bulk of Britain s fiscal problems. Although in March 2007, when the last pre-crisis budget was announced, the independent economists monitored by the Treasury were forecasting 2.6% growth in 2007 and 2.3% in 2008.

4 ippr Debts and Deficits: How much is Labour to blame? Appendix: Charts Figure 2 Debt ratio fell from 43% in 1996 97 to 30% in 2001 02 It then rose to 36.5% in 2007 08 Average ratio 38.7% under Thatcher/Major governments; 34.5% under pre-crisis Labour and 36.7% for the whole Blair/Brown period. Figure 3 UK had relatively low public debt in 1996 ranked 19th out of 25 developed economies. Figure 4 UK still had relatively low public debt in 2007 ranked 17th out of 25 developed economies OECD forecasts suggest UK will have 9th highest debt ratio by the end of 2011.

5 ippr Debts and Deficits: How much is Labour to blame? Figure 5 The current budget showed a deficit of 0.3% of GDP in 2007 08, compared to 2.7% in 1996 97 There were surpluses between 1998 99 and 2001 02 The average balance under Thatcher/Major was 2.0%, under precrisis Labour +0.1%, and under Blair/Brown as a whole 0.8%. Figure 6 The cyclically-adjusted current budget showed a deficit of 0.6% of GDP in 2007 08, compared to 2.2% in 1996 97 There were surpluses between 1998 99 and 2001 02 The average balance under Thatcher/Major was 1.0%, under precrisis Labour 0.0% and under Blair/Brown as a whole 0.7%. Figure 7 Public sector net borrowing was 2.4% of GDP in 2007 08, compared to 3.4% in 1996 97 Borrowing was negative between 1998 99 and 2000 01 Borrowing averaged 3.3% under Thatcher/Major, 1.2% under pre-crisis Labour, and 2.4% under Blair/Brown as a whole.

6 ippr Debts and Deficits: How much is Labour to blame? Figure 8 UK had a relatively large financial deficit in 1996 ranked 23rd out of 31 developed economies on its financial balance (note Norway, which has a very large surplus, is excluded from the chart). Figure 9 UK also had a relatively large financial deficit in 2007 ranked 28th out of 31 developed economies on its financial balance OECD forecasts suggest UK will rank 29th in 2011 (only the US and Ireland are larger). Figure 10 Current spending was 37.8% of GDP in 2007 08, compared to 37.6% in 1996 97 Current receipts were 38.6% of GDP in 2007 08, compared to 36.4% in 1996 97 Spending averaged 39.2% under Thatcher/Major, 36.4% under pre-crisis Labour, and 37.2% under Blair/Brown as a whole.

7 ippr Debts and Deficits: How much is Labour to blame? Figure 11 Total spending was 41.1% of GDP in 2007 08, compared to 39.9% in 1996 97 Spending averaged 43.5% under Thatcher/Major, 39.0% under pre-crisis Labour, and 40.0% under Blair/Brown as a whole. Figure 12 Public sector gross investment fell from 2.3% of GDP in 1996 97 to 1.8% in 2000 01 before increasing to 3.2% in 2007 08 Net investment was 0.7% in 1996 97, 0.5% in 2000 01 and 2.0% in 2007 08. Figure 13 UK had relatively low level of public spending in 1996 ranked 21st out of 31 developed economies. Figure 14 UK had higher level of public spending in 2007 ranked 12th out of 31 developed economies OECD forecasts suggest UK will have 8th highest spending ratio in 2011.

8 ippr Debts and Deficits: How much is Labour to blame? Figure 15 Spending on interest payments fell from 3.5% of GDP in 1996 to a post-war low of 1.9% in 2002 2004 before edging up to 2.2% in 2007. Figure 16 Spending on social benefits fell from 11.4% of GDP in 1996 to 9.9% in 2007. Figure 17 Other spending (ie excluding interest and social benefits fell from 21.3% of GDP in 1996 to 19.9% in 1998 It then increased to 23.7% in 2007 as more money was spent in areas such as health, education and policing.