Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates. Evidence from Forecast Data

Similar documents
LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Vector Autoregressions. September 7, 2016

On the new Keynesian model

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy?

Taxes and the Fed: Theory and Evidence from Equities

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

MODELING THE INFLUENCE OF FISCAL POLICY ON INFLATION

Dean Croushore 1 Simon van Norden 2 AEA Fiscal Policy: Ex Ante and Ex Post. Dean Croushore, Simon van Norden. Introduction.

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Estimating the Impact of Changes in the Federal Funds Target Rate on Market Interest Rates from the 1980s to the Present Day

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

Macroeconometrics - handout 5

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Appendix to Fiscal Forecasts at the FOMC: Evidence from the Greenbooks

Monetary Policy under Behavioral Expectations: Theory and Experiment

Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy?

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Interest Rate Smoothing and Calvo-Type Interest Rate Rules: A Comment on Levine, McAdam, and Pearlman (2007)

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

SEM U. Chicago

Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom? Martin Uribe and Vivian Yue (JIE, 2006)

University of California Berkeley

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

9. ISLM model. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations CHAPTER 9. slide 0

A NEW MEASURE OF MONETARY SHOCKS: DERIVATION AND IMPLICATIONS. Christina D. Romer David H. Romer. Working Paper 9866

Monetary Policy and Stock Market Boom-Bust Cycles by L. Christiano, C. Ilut, R. Motto, and M. Rostagno

Are inflation expectations differently formed when countries are part of a Monetary Union?

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Lecture 5a: ARCH Models

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

Online Appendix to Grouped Coefficients to Reduce Bias in Heterogeneous Dynamic Panel Models with Small T

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

The Effect of Monetary Policy on Credit Spreads

Using the New Keynesian Phillips Curve to Understand Inflation Since. the Great Recession

LECTURE 11 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. November 2, 2016

What determines government spending multipliers?

Trinity College and Darwin College. University of Cambridge. Taking the Art out of Smart Beta. Ed Fishwick, Cherry Muijsson and Steve Satchell

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training

There is considerable interest in determining whether monetary policy

One for Some or One for All? Taylor Rules and the Inter-Regional Unemployment Dispersion Puzzle

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Does a Big Bazooka Matter? Central Bank Balance-Sheet Policies and Exchange Rates

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

CORPORATE ANNOUNCEMENTS OF EARNINGS AND STOCK PRICE BEHAVIOR: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

HIGH FREQUENCY IDENTIFICATION OF MONETARY NON-NEUTRALITY: THE INFORMATION EFFECT

The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer LECTURE 9

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

The Finance-Growth Nexus and Public-Private Ownership of. Banks: Evidence for Brazil since 1870

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Do Forecasters Know the Slope of the Phillips Curve?

Discretionary Accrual Models and the Accounting Process

Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate?

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Foreca. Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

The Rational Part of Momentum

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

The relation between bank losses & loan supply an analysis using panel data

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Inflation Expectations and Behavior: Do Survey Respondents Act on their Beliefs? October Wilbert van der Klaauw

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

Pension fund investment: Impact of the liability structure on equity allocation

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

FEDERAL RESERVE PRIVATE INFORMATION AND THE BEHAVIOR OF ~TEREST RATES. Christina D. Romer David H, Romer. NBER Working Paper 5692

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Predicting the Equity Premium with Implied Volatility Spreads

MPhil F510 Topics in International Finance Petra M. Geraats Lent Course Overview

Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation

Emergency Liquidity Facilities, Signalling and Funding Costs 1

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

THE CHANGING PROBABILITY OF A MONETARY POLICY RESPONSE TO INFLATION AND EMPLOYMENT ANNOUNCEMENTS

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

PRIVATE SECTOR INFLUENCES ON MONETARY POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES

Transcription:

Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates Evidence from Forecast Data

Asymmetric Information Hypothesis (AIH) Asserts that the federal reserve possesses private information about the current and future outlook of the economy which is not available to market participants. AIH holds relevance for 1. Assessments of monetary policy effectiveness 2. Explaining the counterintuitive response of long-term interest rates to monetary policy decisions

How Interest Rates Behave (in theory) Monetary Contraction Short-term rates rise Banks raise rates leading to decline in consumption Inflation decreases (lower long-term rates) Aggregate demand falls

How Interest Rates Behave (empirically) (Cook and Hahn, 1989) show that increase in the Fed Funds rate signifying monetary contraction causes statistically significant increase in 3-month to 20-yr bonds rates of 55 to10 basis points. This empirical result of long-term bond rate behavior is counterintuitive to theoretical expectations. (Romer and Romer, 2000) test the assertion that the Fed s asymmetric information (AIH) explains this unexpected increase in rates.

Romer s Theoretical Framework Assuming the Fed possesses asymmetric information unavailable to market participants, such information influences long-term rates according to the following mechanism: FF rate increases Signal to market participants Market responds by raising inflation expectations

Central Bank Forecast Data Any Fed private information would be reflected in inflation forecasts found in the Greenbooks published by the FRB of Philadelphia. Greenbooks released to the public at a 5-year lag. They contain projections for 15 macro variables. Inflation projections modeled by 3 variables Available 1965:11 1991:11 GNP Deflator = Nominal GNP Real GNP X 100

Central Bank Forecast Data The GNP Deflator monthly series captured in the Greenbooks typically represent forecasts with horizons of five or six quarters. Greenbook forecasts are produced only on the occasion of FOMC meetings, which typically occur during the first half of the month. There is variability in the timing of FOMC meetings both during the year and within the given month in which a meeting occurs. GNP Deflator is expressed as Q/Q growth in price index for GNP, chain weight (annualized percentage points)

Commercial Forecast Data Romer collects inflation forecasts from three commercial forecasting sources available 1968:11 1991:11 Due to proprietary considerations, only SPF data was obtainable for replicating (Romer and Romer, 2000). SPF, administered by FRB of Philadelphia quarterly near the end of the quarter s second month, contains projections of 32 macro variables. Again, we use the GNP Deflator to measure inflation.

Actual GNP Deflator Actual GNP Deflator quarterly series is acquired from June, September, December, and March issues of the Survey of Current Business over the period 1964:4 1991:4 An important thing to note is the revisionary nature of the GNP Deflator data. As more information becomes available, the Survey publishes revisions of initial forecast estimates. (Romer and Romer, 2000) use the second revision since it relies on mostly complete data and is roughly contemporaneous with the forecasts being analyzed.

1. Testing for Forecast Rationality A necessary first step before determining the existence of asymmetric information is establishment of the rationality of commercial forecasts. i.e., Market participants will only use commercial forecasts as inputs to their decisionmaking if the forecasts are not grossly inaccurate. OLS regression of the following model (using HAC estimators) π ht = α + β π ht + ε ht

Rationality of the Fed s Forecast at Horizon h *Romers estimates in red

Replication Comparison Rounding to one basis point reveals slight disparity in the replication results for the β coefficients only for the contemporaneous month (h = 0) and at the first horizon (inflation 1 quarter after the forecast made in month t) This disparity is likely due to data formatting challenges that have resulted in unequal sample observations being used for estimation. The standard errors vary slightly for all horizons. This is likely due to the same disturbance affecting the β s as well as Romers use of a combination of Hansen-Hodrick and Newey-West standard errors versus and my use of HAC estimation.

Rationality of the SPF Forecast at Horizon h *Romers estimates in red

Replication Comparison for SPF Forecast Rounding to one basis point reveals slight disparity in the replication results for the β coefficients only for the 3 rd and 4 th horizons. This disparity is likely due to data formatting challenges that have resulted in unequal sample observations being used for estimation. The standard errors vary slightly for horizons 1-4. In general the variance between Romers and my standard errors increase at longer horizons. This is likely due to the same disturbance affecting the β s as well as Romers use of a combination of Hansen-Hodrick and Newey-West standard errors versus and my use of HAC estimation.

1. Test for Forecast Rationality - Evaluation (Romer and Romer, 2000) infer that virtually all forecasts across horizons contain useful information in predicting actual inflation. β coefficients are positive, generally between 0.5 and 1, and significant at conventional levels. My findings support the Romer conclusion across the same sample.

2. Does the Fed Have Additional Information? We are interested to know if commercial forecasters would benefit from knowing the Fed s forecast. If so, then the inference of the Fed s possessing private information is substantiated. i.e., Is β F statistically different from zero? π ht = α + β C π C ht F + β F π ht (1) π ht = α + β C π C ht + β F π F ht + ε ht (2) After running (1) separately for all h horizons, we then run it for average inflation over all horizons (2). The second regression indicates the systematic relationship free of any quarter-to-quarter noise.

*Romers estimates in red

Actual v. Forecasted Growth in GNP Deflator 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 APCGNPD_4 AASAD4 AGRFD4

2. Test for Fed Private Information - Evaluation The replicated coefficient estimates and standard errors frequently match exactly and never differ by any significant amount across all horizons separately and for the 4-quarter average inflation regression. My results are in agreement with the Romers that the Fed s forecasts present overwhelmingly significant indication that it has information unavailable to the public. Evidence of this is given by t-statistics on β F significant at conventional levels, leading us to reject the null hypothesis of no asymmetric information.

Sources of Asymmetric Information Inside information about monetary policy Fed forecasts have predictive capability at relatively long horizons; thus it may be possible staff members have inside information about the FOMC s commitment to a particular policy. Advance access to official data Unlikely since the Fed chair only receives data on key economic variables only the night before release to the public. Lead time should only give an advantage in the short run; however the Fed s forecast has predictive power at long horizons. Greater allocation of resources for forecasting at the Fed Fed devotes more inputs toward forecasting than any commercial entity, resulting in superior value of its forecasts.

Robustness Check Forecast Timing Basic specification for regressions (1) and (2) put the Fed forecast at a possible timing disadvantage because the Fed generally makes its forecasts early in the month, whereas the SPF forecasts are generated during the latter part of the month. To ensure the preceding results are not attributable to timing disadvantages, we run (1) and (2) with a 1-month lag in the Fed forecast, thereby putting it at a deliberate disadvantage relative to the commercial forecast.

Robustness Check Results for μ(0-4) π ht = α + β C π C ht F + β F π ht 1 + ε ht *Romers estimates in red

3. Implication for the Behavior or Interest Rates The Fed s asymmetric information impacts interest rates if it is somehow signaled to the market. Theory leads us to look for such signaling in the monetary policy actions of the Fed. (Romer and Romer 2000) use the change in the Fed Funds-rate target as an indicator of monetary action for the period 1974:8 1979:8, 1984:2-1991:11. (Excludes the Volcker disinflationary period during the 1980s)

Market Signaling To determine whether market participants can garner insight into the Fed s private information through monetary decisions, we run the following regression. π F ht = ψ + θm t + φ π C ht + ω ht (A) θ indicates the extent to which the Fed s forecast of inflation is above the expected value given only the commercial forecast Timing of the forecasts and monetary actions present a challenge. Correcting for timing in the SPF data gives the following regression. π F ht C = ψ + θm t + φ π ht 1 + ω ht (B)

*Romers estimates in red

Market Signaling Evaluation From the results using the average inflation forecast up to four quarters, we see that an increase of 1% in the fed funds rate results in a 0.32 percentage point upward gap in the Fed s inflation forecast compared to what one would expect given only the commercial SPF forecast. The indication is that Federal Reserve actions appear to be significant signals of its private information (result is significant at α = 0.10). Comparing my results with Romers, there is exact matching in the coefficient estimates and negligible disparity in the standard errors.

Market Response to Information Signals To ascertain whether the market acts on the perceived signal from the Fed s monetary action, we run the following regression specifically tailored for SPF forecasts, accounting for idiosyncratic timing in the SPF data, monetary action dates, and Fed forecasts. C π ht+3 C = η + λm t+1 + κ π h+1,t F + ρ( π ht+4 F π h+1,t+1 ) + υ ht+3 Coefficient of Interest Accounts for new information received between consecutive SPF C forecasts that may influence π ht+3

*Romers estimates in red

Signal Responsiveness - Evaluation In all cases my replication results match Romers results on the coefficient estimates. Minor variability exists in the standard errors. Interestingly, while (Romer and Romer, 2000) report some statistically significant coefficients on λ as evidence that market participants revise their inflation expectations upward in response to contractionary monetary policy action, the p-values in my results are larger than α at conventional levels. This leads me to conclude that in the case of SPF, Federal Reserve monetary action does correlate to upward revision in commercial forecasts but is insignificant at conventional levels.

AIH as Explanation for Monetary Action Effects on the Term Structure of Interest Rates How much of commercial forecasters response to monetary actions is attributable to the asymmetric information revealed by the monetary actions themselves? Competing theories: 1. Sluggish Inflation contractionary action induces long-lasting increase in real rates and correspondingly gradual decline in inflation. 2. Asymmetric information about real rate equilibrium - contractionary action implies current/future real rates are higher than previously believed, causing increase in nominal rates. 3. Overreaction long-term rates overreact to short-term rates as a violation of the rational expectations theory.

Short-term Interest Rates Monetary action has a pronounced impact on expected inflation at short horizons A 100-basis point increase in the target rate results in a 0.11 percentage point increase in expected inflation during the life of the 3-month Treasury bill rate, a 0.10 percentage point increase for the 6- month bill,and a 0.14 percentage point increase for 12-month bills. Most of the response, though, is due to changes in real rates.

Impact of Asymmetric Information at Long Horizons (2, 3, and 4 years) Forecast data provides at most 7 quarter horizons. We are interested in testing the impact of asymmetric information at 8, 12, and 16- quarter horizons using medium-term forecasts (h = 4). π ht = α + β C π C 4t F + β F π 4t

*Romers estimates in red h = 8 h = 12 h = 16 In accordance with Romers findings, my coefficient estimates on the Fed forecast are positive and > 0.5, suggesting predictive capability of fed forecasts of inflation at long horizons. At 12 th + horizons the variance between my results and Romers increases. This may be due to inaccuracies in data transformation for actual inflation at long horizons or nuances in model specification I am unaware of. My results indicate that for SPF at minimum 2-yr horizon, the fed medium term forecast is significant at conventional levels.

Extension of (Romer and Romer, 2000) The data for the Romer paper ends at 1991:11. I test for consistency of the preceding results under a longer time series extending to 2009:4 Below is the average inflation over 4 quarters regressed on 4-quarter averaged Fed and SPF inflation forecasts, also accounting for differences pre and post 1992 when GNP Deflator was replaced by the GDP Deflator. π 4t = α + β C π C 4t + β F π F 4t +δ 1 GDP Def + δ 2 π C 4t GDP Def + δ 3 π F 4t GDP Def + ε ht

Does Fed Asymmetric Information Persist up to 2009? Evidence indicates that Romer s assertion of Fed private information is supported at conventional levels using more recent data from 1992 2009. Furthermore, I find evidence that from 1992 onwards, when the FRB of Philadelphia switched from GND to GDP Deflator tracking, there is now an inverse relationship between actual inflation and Fed forecasts.

Actual v. Forecasted Growth in GNP/GDP Deflator 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 APCGNPD_4 AGRFD4