Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Similar documents
1 Two Period Production Economy

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 5

The Maturity Structure of Debt, Monetary Policy and Expectations Stabilization

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Problem Set # Public Economics

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Problem Set 3. Consider a closed economy inhabited by an in ntely lived representative agent who maximizes lifetime utility given by. t ln c t.

Exercises on chapter 4

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

G + V = w wl + a r(assets) + c C + f (firms earnings) where w represents the tax rate on wages. and f represents the tax rate on rms earnings

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

1 Unemployment Insurance

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

ECON Micro Foundations

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

6. Deficits and inflation: seignorage as a source of public sector revenue

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

Micro-foundations: Consumption. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Macro Consumption Problems 33-43

Keynesian Multipliers with Home Production

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Advanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions

Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model. Narayana Kocherlakota

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

Advanced International Macroeconomics Session 5

Cash in Advance Models

Fiscal Policy, Welfare, and the Zero Lower Bound

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

Discussion of Chiu, Meh and Wright

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Principles of Optimal Taxation

Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Consumption-Savings Decisions and Credit Markets

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Fiscal Policy. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #4 (version 1.3)

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Keynesian Business Cycles & Policy

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Problem set 1 - Solutions

The Facts of Economic Growth and the Introdution to the Solow Model

Interest rates expressed in terms of the national currency (basket of goods ) are called nominal (real) interest rates Their relation is given as

Money in an RBC framework

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

QUEEN S UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ARTS AND SCIENCE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Firm Heterogeneity and the Long-Run E ects of Dividend Tax Reform

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Session 6: Fiscal Policy

Exchange Rate Crises and Fiscal Solvency

Solutions to Problem Set 1

The Representative Household Model

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Macroeconomics and finance

Topic 2: Consumption

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Simple e ciency-wage model

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Fall 2009

Macro Consumption Problems 12-24

Transcription:

Roberto Perotti November 20, 2013 Version 02 Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics 1 The intertemporal government budget constraint Consider the usual two period model, with constant real interest rate is constant. Assume the government starts in period 1 with some initial net debt inherited from the past, B 0 : Then the government budget constraint in period 1 is: Similarly in period 2 it is B 1 = ()B 0 + G 1 T 1 (1) B 2 = ()B 1 + G 2 T 2 (2) As usual, it must be B 2 = 0: The government cannot end with positive net debt, because this would mean that some creditor would not get repaid. But it is not optimal for the government to end with negative net debt (i.e., positive net assets). Therefore setting B 2 = 0 in (2) and replacing B 1 in (1) gives the government intertemporal budget constraint: B 0 () = T 1 G 1 + T 2 G 2 (3) T i G i is the primary surplus in period i: The primary surplus is taxes less government spending (excluding interest payments). Hence the intertemporal government budget constraint says that: initial net debt (including interest) = present value of primary surpluses. 1

2 Ricardian Equivalence Let disposable income in teh two periods be Consumption of the individual in the two periods is y 1 = y T 1 (4) y 2 = y T 2 (5) c 1 = y s T 1 (6) c 2 = y + s() T 2 (7) Where s is savings and y is constant labor income: We assume for simplicity that G 1 = G 2 = G; i.e. government spending is the same in the two periods. We also assume that the initial debt is 0: B 0 = 0 The utility function is U = u(c 1 ) + 1 1 + u(c 2) (8) Assume for simplicity that r = : Note that in this model government spending does not enter the utility function of the individual directly. Hence, it a ects consumption and utility of the individual only through taxation: higher government spending means higher taxation and lower disposable income of the individual. This is the wealth e ect of government spending. For simplicity, we assuyme that the individual has no initial nancial wealth. We consider two cases. Case I We denote the outcome of this case with a " ". The government sets T1 = T2 = G: Hence, in each period the budget is balanced, and there is no debt: B1 = B2 = 0: From the Euler equation u 0 (c 1 ) = 1 + u0 (c 2 ) (9) Since r = ; this implies c 1 = c 2; and therefore s = 0: Note that government savings is also 0: s G = T 1 G 1 = 0: Therefore, national savings too is 0: s T OT = s + s G = 0: The consumption of the individual in the two periods is c 1 = y s T 1 (10) = y G (11) 2

c 2 = y + s () T 2 (12) = y G (13) Case II Now assume that the government implements a tax cut. Instead of T1 = G; in period 1 the government taxes T1 = G T; where T > 0: From the government budget constraint B1 = G T1 (14) = T (15) Hence, the government runs a de cit in period 1 and issues debt to nance the tax cut. From (2) in period 2 it must be T2 = ()B1 + G (16) = ()T + G (17) = T 2 + ()T (18) i.e., relative to Case I, the government must issue debt T in period 1, and taxes in period 2 must increase by T () to repay that debt. Now consider the optimal behavior of the individual. She sees taxes decreasing in period 1 by T: However, she knows that taxes will increase in period 2 by ()T: Hence, her human wealth (the present value of disposbale incomes) does not change, because and W = y 1 + y 2 = y T 1 + y T 2 (19) (20) 1 + y 2 W = y = y T1 + y T 2 = y T 1 + T + y T 2 ()T (21) (22) (23) = y T1 + y T 2 (24) = W (25) 3

Since her wealth does not change, her optimal consumption also should not change. In fact, the individual consumer could continue consuming the optimal quantities c 1 = c 2: How? She simply saves the tax cuts. Hence, her savings increase by T : Now consider government savings s = s + T (26) = T (27) s G = T 1 G (28) = T 1 T G (29) = T (30) = s G T (31) Government savings falls by T; but we have seen that private savings increases by T; relative to Case I. Hence, total savings is unchanged s T OT = s + s G (32) = s + T + s G T (33) = s + s G (34) = s T OT (35) Hence, national savings does not change. Simply, private savings increase to o set the decline in government savings. What is her disposable income? y 1 = y s T 1 (36) = y T (T 1 T ) (37) = y G (38) = y 1 (39) y2 = y + s () T2 (40) = y + T () (T2 + T ()) (41) = y G (42) = y 2 (43) And the disposable income is also unchanged relative to Case I. Because nothing real changes, the interest rate does not change either. A tax cut has no real e ect, because it does not change the present value of government 4

spending and therefore it does not change the present value of taxation. It merely reallocates taxes from period 1 to period 2. But the individual can undo this by increasing savings, and can continue doing optimal consumption smoothing like before. The reason is the following: if the government cuts taxes today by 1 dollar without changing spending at any time, the de cit increases by 1 dollar, but taxes will have to increase by 1+r dollars next period. Knowing this, the consumer saves all the initial tax cut; next period, she will earn exactly 1+r on this extra savings, which she will be able to use to repay the taxes, without altering her consumption path. Thus, private savings increase by exactly as much as government savings decreases: national savings is not a ected; hence the capital stock does not change => consumption, the interest rate etc. do not change. A frequently heard interpretation of Ricardian Equivalent is that "de cits do not matter". This interpretation can be wrong: de cits do not matter if they are caused by a change in the path of taxation, holding constant the present value of government spending. But if the de cit increases because government spending increases, and the present value of government spending also changes, then de cits do matter. There are several reasons why Ricardian Equivalence can fail: 1) Finite lives. Individuals do not save the whole tax cut because they expect that it will be future generations that will have to repay today s debt. Hence, national savings falls. 2) Myopia. Individuals do not internalize today that in the future they will have to repay the debt. Hence, national savings falls. 3) Liquidity constraints. Liquidity constrained individuals consume the whole tax cut, because that s exactly what they would have liked to do in the rst place. 4) Distortionary taxation: timing matters 3 Tax smoothing Taxes so far were lump-sum, i.e. non-distortionary. Distortionary taxation complicates things considerably, because it can have all sorts of e ects: intra-temporal and inter-temporal substitution e ects. We consider the simplest possible example. Assume that the utility function is U(c 1 ; c 2 ) = log c 1 + 1 1 + log c 2 (44) Income is xed, and there is a tax on consumption with rate t : Hence: c 1 = (y s)(1 1 ) (45) 5

c 2 = (y + s())(1 2 ) (46) The consumer takes 1 and 2 as given. We can rewrite the utility function as U(c 1 ; c 2 ) = log(y s)+log(1 1 )+ 1 1 + log(y+s(1+r))+ 1 1 + log(1 2) (47) The rst order condition for the consumer is and assuming as usual = r y 1 s = 1 1 + y + s() (48) y s = y + s() (49) i.e. Therefore, optimal consumption is s = 0 (50) c 1 = y(1 1 ); c 2 = y(1 2 ) (51) Hence, if the 1 < 2 ; c 1 > c 2 : the consumer prefers to shift consumption when it is taxes less. Given this, how should a social planner set the two tax rates in order to maximize the consumer s welfare? The social planner takes as given (51), and therefore her jobs is to max U = log c 1 ; 2 1( 1 ) + 1 1 + log c 2( 2 ) (52) s.t. c 1 = y(1 1 ); c 2 = y(1 2 ) (53) and the intertemporal government budget constraint Hence, this is equivalent to solving s.t. (54). The rst order condition is 1 y + 2y = G 1 + G 2 (54) max H = log(1 1 ) + 1 1 ; 2 1 + log(1 2) (55) 1 = 1 (56) 1 1 1 + 1 2 6

i.e. 1 = 2 (57) That is, the optimal tax policy is to do tax smoothing: if taxes are distortionary, it is optimal to smooth distortions over time, i.e. in this case to smooth the tax rate perfectly. The reason is clear: (55) is increasing and concave in (1-1 ) and (1 2 ); i.e. declining and convex in 1 and 2 : Hence, to minimize distortions one should smooth the tax rate. This means that, if G 1 is high and G 2 is low, it is optimal to run a de cit in period 1 and a surplus in period 2, and viceversa if G 1 is low and G 2 is high. This is the tax smoothing motive for the de cit, which is very di erent from the Keynesian countercyclical argument for the de cit. 4 The e ects of government spending 4.1 The neoclassical model We now consider the e ects of a change in government spending in a model with optimizing agents. To see the main e ect, it is enough to consider a static model. We need however to assume that leisure enters the utility function, and the real wage is not constant. The production function is where L is labor supply. The real wage is Assume that the utility function is Y = L ; < 1 (58) w = L 1 (59) u(c; 1 L) = log C + (1 ) log(1 L) (60) where 1 L is leisure. Hence the individual maximizes this utility s.t. Direct substitution gives the f.o.c. C = wl T (61) = L T (62) C = 1 1 L (63) 7

i.e. L T = 1 1 L The government budget constraint is, trivially, (64) G = T (65) Hence, to nd the e ects of an increase in G on labor supply and consumption, we need to nd the e ects of a change in T on L from (64). Rewrite (64) as Totally di erentiating the lhs we must have i.e. (1 L) (1 )(L T ) = 0 (66) dl 2 (1 )L 1 dl + (1 )dt = 0 (67) [ + 2 (1 )L 1 ]dl = (1 )dt (68) Therefore dl dt > 0 (69) and, from (63), dc dt < 0 (70) What is happening? An increase in G increases T via the government budget constraint. This reduces the wealth of the individual, and therefore reduces the purchase of the two "goods" in her utility function, consumption and leisure. As leisure falls, the labor supply curve shifts out, and the real wage declines. This is due to the negative wealth e ect of government spending via the increase in taxes. Note that output increases, because L increases, but welfare declines, because consumption and leisure decline. 4.2 Keynesian and neo-keyensian models We cannot enter into the speci cs of neo-keynesian models. But the e ects of government spending in these models are in some respects the opposite of that in neoclassical model: consumption and the real wage increase. This is due to the fact that not only the labor supply shifts out because of the wealth e ect, as in the neoclassical model, but also the labor demand curve shifts out as aggregate demand increases, so the real wage can increase. As the real wage increases, labor income increases, and if there are liquidity constrained individuals their consumption now increases. 8

5 The dynamics of debt and de cits Let s go back to the government debt accumulation equation, rewritten as B t+1 B t = G t T t + rb t (71a) Assume that there is no in ation, so that nominal and real variables are the same. Start from (71a) and divide both sides by Y t : Let a tilde indicate a variable as a share of GDP: for instance, e b t = B t =Y t. B t+1 Y t e bt = eg t et t + r e b t (72) B t+1 Y t+1 Y t+1 Y t e bt = eg t et t + r e b t (73) e bt+1 (1 + ) e bt = eg t et t + r e b t (74) where is the rate of growth of GDP. Now subtract e b t from both sides e bt+1 (1 + ) e bt (1 + ) = eg t et t + r e b t e b t (75) e bt+1 e bt = = es t 1 + + r 1 + e b t (76) ed t 1 + + r 1 + e b t (77) where d e t (es t ) is the primary de cit (surplus) as share of GDP. We say that scal policy is sustainable if the debt/gdp ratio converges to some constant, assuming that the primary de cit or surplus is constant. Rewrite (76) as e es t bt+1 = 1 + + 1 + e b t (78) The coe cient of e b t is less than 1 if > r; in this case, debt converges to a constant for any constant negative primary surplus es (if es is positive, net debt converges to a negative number). Consider the more interesting case of r > : Then given a constant surplus es; debt explodes if the primary surplus is smaller than e b 0 (r ); where e b 0 is the initial level of debt, and it implodes in the opposite case. Thus, given a positive initial level of debt, it gives us the primary surplus needed to keep it stable. That is we need a primary sruplus such that es = e b 0 (r ) (79) 9

Note that the total surplus must be negative, i.e. one has a total de cit es r e b 0 = e b 0 (80) Note that, given e b 0, to guarantee sustainability one needs a higher primary surplus es, the higher is r; and the lower is : For instance, to guarantee that a country does not exceed the Maastricht Treaty limit of 60 percent for the debt-to- GDP ratio e b 0 = :60; if r = :03 and = :02; one needs a primary surplus of at least.006, while the total de cit can be.012 of GDP (=.006 -.03*.60). Note the distinction between the notions of solvency and sustainability. Solvency: when the PDV of current and future primary surpluses is enough to repay the initial debt. Sustinability: when the debt/gdp ratio converges to some constant, assuming that the primary de cit or surplus is constant. 10