The Problem With Deficit-Neutral Tax Reform By Chuck Marr, Chye-Ching Huang, and Nathaniel Frentz

Similar documents
July 31, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

The Legacy of the 2001 and 2003 Bush Tax Cuts

WHAT WOULD IT SAY ABOUT CONGRESS S PRIORITIES TO WAIVE PAYGO FOR THE AMT PATCH? By Aviva Aron-Dine

March 12, 2009 KEY FINDINGS

Senate Tax Bill Has Same Basic Flaws as House Bill

Vast Majority of Americans Would Likely Lose From Senate GOP s $1.5 Trillion in Tax Cuts, Once They re Paid For

Ryan Plan Gets 69 Percent of Its Budget Cuts From Programs for People With Low or Moderate Incomes By Richard Kogan and Joel Friedman

A Fair Way to Limit Tax Deductions

October 31, Policy Priorities, October 28, 2011,

And Jobs Act, November 14, 2017, %20chairman's%20modified%20mark.pdf.

PROPOSED SENATE TAX CUTS FOR SMALL BUSINESSES AND FARMERS NOT A TOP PRIORITY, GIVEN BUDGET OUTLOOK AND OTHER PRESSURES.

THE PRESIDENT S BUDGET: A PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS

Revised January 6, 2006

REPUBLICAN PROPOSAL TO PAY FOR PAYROLL TAX EXTENSION WOULD INCREASE ALREADY SEVERE CUTS IN DISCRETIONARY PROGRAMS by James R.

What The New CBO Report Shows Budget And Economic Outlook Has Not Improved by James Horney and Richard Kogan

NEW TAX CUTS PRIMARILY BENEFITING MILLIONAIRES SLATED TO TAKE EFFECT IN JANUARY

July 17, Summary

Senate Republicans Take Big First Step Towards $1.5 Trillion Deficit-Increasing Tax Cut

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

CBO s Official Baseline Projections Substantially Understate the Deficits That Will Occur if Current Policies Are Extended

Special Report. Using Dynamic Analysis Makes Tax Reform 30 Percent Less Challenging. Key Findings. August 2013 No. 210

Chart Book: Deficit Reduction, the Economy, And the Budget Negotiations By Sharon Parrott, Richard Kogan, Krista Ruffini, and William Chen

New House Republican Tax Proposal Fails Fiscal Responsibility Test, While Favoring the Wealthiest

House GOP Budget Cuts Programs Aiding Low- and Moderate-Income People by $2.9 Trillion Over Decade

CONGRESS HAS CUT DISCRETIONARY FUNDING BY $1.5 TRILLION OVER TEN YEARS First Stage of Deficit Reduction Is In Law

ALLOWING HIGH-INCOME TAX CUTS TO EXPIRE ON SCHEDULE WOULD BE SOUND ECONOMIC AND FISCAL POLICY By Chuck Marr

Tax Expenditures: How Cutting Spending Through the Tax Code Can Lower the Deficit, Improve Efficiency, and Boost Fairness in the US Tax Code

SHOULD THE BUDGET RULES BE CHANGED SO THAT LARGE-SCALE BORROWING TO FUND INDIVIDUAL ACCOUNTS IS LEFT OUT OF THE BUDGET? 1

MORE THAN HALF OF BLACK AND HISPANIC FAMILIES WOULD NOT BENEFIT FROM BUSH TAX PLAN. by Isaac Shapiro, Allen Dupree and James Sly

Taxes Primer September 27, 2013

The key differences between the Cooper-LaTourette plan and the Simpson-Bowles commission plan are:

Revised November 21, 2008

Revised May 10, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

Senate Proposal for Balanced Budget Amendment Would Require Extreme Budget Cuts By Richard Kogan and Cecile Murray 1

Ten Facts You Should Know About the Federal Estate Tax By Chye-Ching Huang and Chloe Cho 1

continue to average 0.2 percent of GDP from 2018 through 2028, CBO projects.

Taxing Capital Income Once * Leonard E. Burman

CBPP S UPDATED LONG-TERM FISCAL DEFICIT AND DEBT PROJECTIONS

shortfalls in perpetuity. 3 The 2003 Trustees report, for example, pushes the insolvency date back by assuming that older

Revised December 7, 2006

NEW ESTATE TAX RULES SHOULD EXPIRE AFTER 2012 Shrinking the Tax Beyond the 2009 Level Is Unaffordable and Unnecessary By Gillian Brunet

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

TESTIMONY OF ROBERT GREENSTEIN Executive Director, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities Before the House Budget Committee July 25, 2007

75-YEAR PAY-AS-YOU-GO PROPOSAL COULD ADVERSELY AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY, MEDICARE, SSI, VETERANS DISABILITY, AND OTHER PROGRAMS

PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS OF THE FAMILY FAIRNESS AND OPPORTUNITY TAX REFORM ACT

PROPOSAL FOR NEW HSA TAX DEDUCTION FOUND LIKELY TO INCREASE THE RANKS OF THE UNINSURED. by Edwin Park and Robert Greenstein

WOULD RAISING IRA CONTRIBUTION LIMITS BOLSTER RETIREMENT SECURITY FOR LOWER AND MIDDLE-INCOME FAMILIES? by Peter Orszag and Jonathan Orszag 1

REPEALING THE ALTERNATIVE MINIMUM TAX WITHOUT OFFSETTING THE COST WOULD ADD $1.2 TRILLION TO THE FEDERAL DEBT OVER THE NEXT DECADE

WINNERS AND LOSERS AFTER PAYING FOR THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

Medicare in Ryan s 2014 Budget By Paul N. Van de Water

ECONOMIC EVIDENCE FOR EXTENDING CAPITAL GAINS AND DIVIDEND TAX CUTS IS WEAK By Joel Friedman and Aviva Aron-Dine

WHAT THE NEW TRUSTEES REPORT SHOWS ABOUT SOCIAL SECURITY By Jason Furman and Robert Greenstein

SENATE FINANCE COMMITTEE PLAN INCLUDES SOUND STIMULUS PROPOSALS. by Joel Friedman, Robert Greenstein, and Richard Kogan

TODAY S UNSUSTAINABLE BUDGET POLICY: A RECOUNT

HOUSE LEGISLATION WOULD CAUSE 350,000 PEOPLE TO FORGO HEALTH COVERAGE AND COULD JEOPARDIZE HEALTH REFORM By Judith Solomon and Robert Greenstein

Senator Kerry s Tax Proposals. Leonard E. Burman and Jeffrey Rohaly 1 Revised July 23, 2004

House Health Bill: Tax Cuts for Wealthy, Insurers, and Drug Companies Paid for by Low- and Middle-Income Families

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

Fiscal Challenges for State and Federal Governments

Preliminary Details and Analysis of the Senate s 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

ARE TAXES TOO CONCENTRATED AT THE TOP? Rapidly Rising Incomes at the Top Lie Behind Increase in Share of Taxes Paid By High-Income Taxpayers

Republican Leaders Tax Plan Would Deliver Large Tax Cuts to the Wealthiest Americans Even if It Doesn t Cut the Top Rate

Unpaid for Tax Cuts: the Gulf Between Promises and Reality

THE ESTATE TAX: MYTHS AND REALITIES

SMALLER DEFICIT ESTIMATE NO SURPRISE New OMB Estimates Do Not Support Claims About Tax Cuts By James Horney

Updated May 11, of Economic Research, August First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

November 30, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

Written Testimony of Scott A. Hodge, President, Tax Foundation

HOW THE TAX REFORM OF 1986 SUPERCHARGED THE AMERICAN ECONOMY

A FRAMEWORK FOR DEFICIT REDUCTION: PRINCIPLES AND CAUTIONS by Robert Greenstein

Tax Foundation Figures Do Not Represent Typical Households Tax Burdens

WILL THE ADMINISTRATION S TAX CUTS GENERATE SUBSTANTIAL ECONOMIC GROWTH? by Richard Kogan

Long-Term Budget Outlook Has Improved Considerably Since 2010 But Remains Challenging

What the 2018 Trustees Report Shows About Social Security

Corporate Tax Cuts Skew to Shareholders and CEOs, Not Workers as Administration Claims

WebMemo22. New CBO Budget Baseline Shows that Soaring Spending Not Falling Revenues Risks Drowning America in Debt

An Overview of Recent Tax Reform Proposals

Tax Foundation s Average Far More Than What Most Americans Pay in Federal Taxes FIGURE 1: April 2, 2012

Ending the Capital Gains Tax Preference would Improve Fairness, Raise Revenue and Simplify the Tax Code

New Analysis Finds GOP Tax Plan would Give Richest One Percent of CT Residents $125,380 More Per Year on Average than Obama s Approach

Long-Term Budget Outlook Has Improved Significantly Since 2010 But Remains Challenging

An Analysis of the 2004 House Tax Cuts. Leonard E. Burman 1 The Urban Institute and The Tax Policy Center. June 2004

The Debate over Expiring Tax Cuts: What about the Deficit? Adam Looney

The Beacon Hill Institute

Universal Savings Account Proposal in New Republican Tax Bill Is Ill-Conceived

The Debate over Expiring Tax Cuts: What about the Deficit? Adam Looney*

January 6, Honorable John Boehner Speaker of the House U.S. House of Representatives Washington, DC Dear Mr. Speaker:

WHAT THE 2007 TRUSTEES REPORT SHOWS ABOUT SOCIAL SECURITY By Chad Stone and Robert Greenstein

Preliminary Details and Analysis of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

working paper President Obama s First Budget By Veronique de Rugy No March 2009

Does the Budget Surplus Justify Large-Scale Tax Cuts?: Updates and Extensions

tax break Sunsets in the Tax Code by William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag I. Introduction

Trump Budget Gets Two-Thirds of Its Cuts From Programs for Low- and Moderate-Income People

Our Tax System Revealed. Lee R. Nackman, Ph.D. October 24, 2018

FACT SHEET CBO BUDGET OUTLOOK FY

AN ANALYSIS OF TED CRUZ S TAX PLAN

PROGRAM CUTS UNDER A BALANCED BUDGET AMENDMENT: HOW SEVERE MIGHT THEY BE? By Richard Kogan

EVALUATING BROAD-BASED APPROACHES FOR LIMITING TAX EXPENDITURES

Impact of the Fiscal Cliff on New York State

OBSERVATION. TD Economics U.S. DEFICITS & DEBT: PAST, PRESENT & FUTURE

Transcription:

820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org July 10, 2013 The Problem With Deficit-Neutral Tax Reform By Chuck Marr, Chye-Ching Huang, and Nathaniel Frentz Given the nation s long-term fiscal pressures, increases in revenues need to make a significant contribution to deficit reduction, alongside reductions in spending for mandatory programs. Deficit-neutral tax reform would, as a result, be highly problematic. Tax reform generally refers to a process through which policymakers would scale back the vast collection of tax deductions, credits, and other preferences, known collectively as tax expenditures. (For example, Senate Finance Committee Chairman Max Baucus and ranking Republican Orrin Hatch are undertaking a process in which Finance Committee members will examine and be asked to defend each tax expenditure that they want to retain in the code. 1 ) If tax reform were revenue neutral, it would use up the politically achievable savings from tax expenditures to lower rates without producing any deficit reduction, and it would effectively take revenue off the table for deficit reduction for years to come. It likely would take major mandatory programs off the table as well, because many policymakers would justifiably resist changes in those programs which could significantly affect millions of people with relatively modest incomes if they were not accompanied by revenue increases from reforming inefficient tax expenditures that disproportionately benefit the most affluent households. Aggravating these risks, some prominent proponents of deficit-neutral tax reform have set, as a key tax-reform goal, a sharp cut in the top income tax rates. The House-passed budget resolution of this spring, for example, calls for setting a goal of cutting the top individual and corporate rates to 25 percent and offsetting that cost through unspecified tax-expenditure savings. The House rate-cut goals would dig a $5.7 trillion revenue hole over the next ten years, the Urban Institute-Brookings Institution Tax Policy Center (TPC) has estimated, with the tax benefits heavily skewed to people at the top. 2 The task of finding anything close to that amount in tax expenditure savings would be politically herculean, given the popularity of such major and expensive tax expenditures as the mortgage interest deduction, the charitable deduction, and many others. 1 Robert Greenstein, Revenue-Neutral Tax Reform: The Road to Nowhere on Deficit Reduction, Off the Charts Blog, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, April 30, 2013, http://www.offthechartsblog.org/revenue-neutral-tax-reformthe-road-to-nowhere-on-deficit-reduction/. 2 Chuck Marr, Chye-Ching Huang, and Nathaniel Frentz, The Ryan Budget s Tax Cuts: Nearly $6 Trillion in Cost and No Plausible Way to Pay for It, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, March 17, 2013, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=view&id=3926. 1

Consequently, policymakers would have strong incentive to use budget gimmicks and optimistic revenue forecasts (including the dubious tactic of dynamic scoring ) to reach the stated goal of deficit-neutral tax reform. Thus, a purportedly revenue-neutral tax reform bill might be revenue neutral only cosmetically (or might be revenue neutral only over the first ten years and lose revenue after that due to the use of timing-shift gimmicks). If so, tax reform could wind up raising less revenue than current law over the long term, making long-term deficits worse. Revenue-neutral tax reform also could lengthen the amount of time that policymakers leave the sequestration budget cuts in effect by making it harder to craft a balanced, long-term budget agreement to replace them. Sequestration, with its equal defense and nondefense cuts, was designed to bring bipartisan negotiators to the table in search of a broader agreement that would include both mandatory spending cuts and revenue increases. Revenue-neutral tax reform could doom that prospect as well. Figure 1 Specified Ryan Tax Cuts* Would Create Nearly $6 Trillion Revenue Hole Pursuing Deficit-Neutral Tax Reform Many recent tax reform proposals have several common elements: 1) calls to cut top tax rates on individuals and corporations, often to specific and historically low levels; 2) a goal of revenue neutrality; and 3) few if any specific proposals for how to achieve revenue neutrality that is, how to offset the cost of the rate cuts. The 2012 plan of presidential candidate Mitt Romney is a well-known example. The latest budget plan of House Budget Committee Chairman Paul Ryan, which the House adopted in its budget resolution this spring, is another. Under such plans, policymakers could dig a big (and regressive) federal revenue hole by cutting tax rates deeply but not shrinking tax expenditures dramatically enough to fully offset the cost, prompting them to adopt various gimmicks to mask the tax cuts costs. Policymakers might even resort to dynamic scoring the proposed process by which budget or tax technicians are supposed to assume that rate cuts generate large enough economic growth to drive up tax revenues, despite the lack of strong evidence for such results (and the difficulty of measuring any such effects). 3 *Does not reflect plan s unspecified changes in tax expenditures. Note: The estimate for repealing the revenueraising measures in the Affordable Care Act includes only the revenue effects that TPC was able to include in its model; Congressional Budget Office estimates indicate the full impact of repealing the revenue provisions would be roughly $1 trillion over 2014-2023. The estimate for the cost of the budget s proposed reductions in individual tax rates includes $48 billion in savings from not extending beyond 2017 the improvements to refundable tax credits enacted in 2009 and extended in 2010 and at the start of this year. Sources: Tax Policy Center (TPC) and Joint Committee on Taxation estimates Policymakers also might enact tax reform that s revenue neutral in the first ten years but adds to deficits in the long run. 4 3 Paul N. Van de Water, Budget Plans Should Not Rely on Dynamic Scoring, Estimates Are Uncertain and Subject to Manipulation, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, June 21, 2012, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=view&id=3598. 2

Across-the-Board Rate Cuts Would be Costly and Regressive The fiscal year 2014 House budget resolution calls for cutting the top individual and corporate tax rates to as low as 25 percent, eliminating the individual Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT), and repealing the revenue-raising measures in health reform. Those tax cuts would cost $5.7 trillion in lost federal revenue over the next decade, according to TPC estimates (see Figure 1). To put the $5.7 trillion figure in perspective, keep in mind that, at the outset of discussions in 2010 over a grand bargain to put the budget on a sustainable course, policymakers widely discussed a target of $4 trillion in deficit reduction over ten years. 5 The cost of the House proposal is no surprise; tax rate cuts are very expensive. TPC Figure 2 Across-the-Board Rate Cut* Would Provide Biggest Gains at the Top *Policy reflects 20 percent reductions to individual income tax and AMT rates, relative to the policy in effect in 2012. Income tax rates reflected are 8, 12, 20, 23, 27, and 28 percent, and the AMT rates are 21 and 23 percent. Note that this baseline reflects the policies that were in place before the American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 created a new 39.6 percent bracket on taxable income above $400,000 for single filers and $450,000 for married couples filing jointly. (TPC has not yet updated this analysis to reflect 2013 tax rates.) Measured against today s law, the tax cut would be larger for the top brackets. Source: Urban Brookings Tax Policy Center, Table T11-0394 analysis suggests that just a two percentage point rate cut would cost about $1.5 trillion over ten years, 6 a level that (as discussed in the next section of this paper) could easily exceed the level of taxexpenditure savings lawmakers can actually pass. For example, the Administration s proposal to limit the value of various tax expenditures to 28 cents on the dollar, which has encountered stiff opposition from an array of constituencies and lawmakers, would raise about $500 billion or about one-third of the cost of a two-percentage-point rate cut. 7 4 Chye-Ching Huang, New Study from Treasury Analysts Highlights Risk of Corporate Tax Reform Trap, Off The Charts Blog, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, May 7, 2013, http://www.offthechartsblog.org/new-study-fromtreasury-analysts-highlights-risk-of-corporate-tax-reform-trap/. 5 Note that the tax cuts in the Ryan budget would cost $5.7 trillion over the years 2014-2023 against a baseline that includes the American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (ATRA). The original Simpson-Bowles proposal released in December 2010 described $3.9 trillion in deficit reduction over 2013-2020 against a baseline that assumed that the tax cuts President Bush and Congress enacted in 2001 and 2003 would expire for incomes over $250,000 for couples ($200,000 for singles); see Richard Kogan, What Was Actually in Bowles-Simpson And How Can We Compare it With Other Plans? Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, October 2, 2012, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=view&id=3844. 6 Tax Policy Center Table T13-0056. Note that this cost would be higher if paid for with base-broadening. 7 Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimated Budget Effects Of The Revenue Provisions Contained In The President s Fiscal Year Budget Proposal, May 10, 2013, https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=4520; and 3

At first blush, across-the-board rate cuts may seem fair. Everybody gets the same percentage reduction in rates, so everybody should benefit equally. In fact, however, such rate cuts actually benefit the highest-income households much more. To understand how, consider a simple tax system with two tax rates: 20 percent and 40 percent. Suppose both tax rates are cut by half, to 10 percent and 20 percent, respectively. Taxpayers would keep 90 cents rather than 80 cents of each dollar taxed at the bottom rate, generating a 12.5 percent increase in after-tax income. But for each dollar taxed at the top rate, high-income households would keep 80 cents, rather than 60 cents, generating a 33 percent increase in after-tax income. Although both tax rates fall by the same percentage, this would create a regressive tax cut that benefits people in the top bracket the most, not only in dollars but in the percentage increase in after-tax income (which many analysts regard as the best measure of whether a tax policy change is progressive or regressive). Figure 2 illustrates the regressivity of a 20 percent across-the-board rate cut. Had policymakers cut rates by 20 percent from the levels in place before January s American Taxpayer Relief Act (ATRA), they would have boosted aftertax incomes by 4.4 percent for people making over $1 million, compared to 1.7 percent for people making between $50,000 and $75,000. A 20 percent across-the-board rate cut would be similarly regressive today. Figure 3 Ryan s Specified Individual Tax Cuts Would Cut Taxes Deeply at the Top* The fiscal year 2014 House budget resolution goes further; it calls for replacing the current seven tax brackets with two: 10 percent and 25 percent. That, too, would disproportionately *Does not reflect plan s unspecified changes in tax expenditures. Note: While making its new tax cuts permanent, the plan allows the 2009 refundable credit improvements to expire after 2017. Source: Tax Policy Center Tables T13-0110, T12-0040, and http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/uploadedpdf/1001628-base-broadening-tax- Reform.pdf benefit the most well-to-do. After-tax incomes would rise by an estimated 15.4 percent for people making over $1 million a year, compared to 1.4 percent for people making between $50,000 and $75,000, according to TPC analysis. (For more on potentially regressive tax changes, see Box 1.) Policymakers could, of course, try to retain the tax code s progressivity by cutting different tax rates by different percentages, although that wouldn t solve the cost problem. Tax Policy Center Table T13-0056. Note that the President s proposal to limit tax expenditures would raise $493 billion over 2014-2023 assuming current tax rates, but would raise less the more the rates are reduced. 4

Box 1: Tax Reform Can Make the Tax Code Either More or Less Progressive As this paper explains, across-the-board cuts in tax rates are regressive. If policymakers want to include such rate cuts in a tax reform plan while maintaining the progressivity of the tax code, they will have to design their reforms in tax expenditures and cuts to tax rates very carefully. Maintaining progressivity would be especially hard if policymakers followed the lead of lawmakers like House Budget Committee Chairman Paul Ryan and declined to scale back the tax expenditures from which high-income taxpayers benefit the most the preferential tax rates for capital gains and dividends and step-up in basis at death. The benefits of the other major tax expenditures are actually somewhat progressive, as Figure 4 shows. a Figure 4 Curbing Tax Expenditures Would Affect All Income Groups *Preferential treatment of capital gains includes lower rates and forgiveness of capital gains upon death Note: baseline is pre-atra current law. ATRA is unlikely to have changed the overall regressivity of tax expenditures; the reinstatement of Pease may have somewhat reduced the total value of itemized deductions for some high-income filers, however the return of the top tax rates to Clinton-era levels for some taxpayers will increase the value of deductions and exemptions for high-income filers. Source: Urban Institute-Brookings Institution Tax Policy Center Crafting and enacting a plan to cut the remaining tax expenditures enough to finance across-the-board rate cuts without hitting low- and moderate-income taxpayers harder than people at the top would likely prove unachievable. b a Congressional Budget Office, The Distribution of Major Tax Expenditures in the Individual Income Tax System, May 29, 2013, http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43768, and Chuck Marr, Chairman Ryan s Misleading Chart, Off the Charts Blog, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, March 27, 2012, http://www.offthechartsblog.org/chairman-ryans-misleading-chart/. b Chuck Marr, Chye-Ching Huang, and Nathaniel Frentz, The Ryan Budget s Tax Cuts: Nearly $6 Trillion in Cost and No Plausible Way to Pay for It, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, March 17, 2013, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=view&id=3926, and Samuel Brown, William G. Gale, and Adam Looney, On the Distributional Effects of Base-Broadening Income Tax Reform, Tax Policy Center, August 1, 2012, http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/publications/url.cfm?id=1001628. 5

Cutting Tax Expenditures Is Hard Tax expenditures cost the government more than $1 trillion per year in lost revenue, and reforming and scaling them back can make the tax code more efficient. The code s vast array of deductions, credits, and other preferences reduces economic efficiency by favoring some forms of investment or economic activity over others. They often also give the largest subsidies to highincome families, even though such taxpayers generally least need a financial incentive to do whatever the tax break seeks to promote, such as saving for college or retirement. That makes such tax incentives inefficient and wasteful. 8 But curtailing tax expenditures, especially by enough to offset the costs of rate cuts, is much harder politically than many proponents suggest. The more than $1 trillion per year in lost revenue has created unrealistic expectations about the potential revenue that could be raised through tax expenditure reform, notes Professor John Buckley, former chief of staff for the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT). 9 A Congressional Research Service (CRS) report issued last year similarly concluded: 10 [T]here are impediments to base broadening by eliminating or reducing tax expenditures, because they are viewed as serving an important purpose, are important for distributional reasons, are technically difficult to change, or are broadly used by the public and quite popular. Given the barriers to eliminating or reducing most tax expenditures, it may prove difficult to gain more than $100 billion to $150 billion in additional tax revenues [in 2014] through base broadening. Base broadening in this range, CRS notes, would not allow for significant reductions in tax rates. Such revenues would offset the cost of only about a one or two percentage point reduction, CRS explained. The author of CRS report, Jane Gravelle, reinforced this point and highlighted the challenges for tax reform in recent congressional testimony: 11 First, it is difficult to identify base broadening provisions that realistically might be considered to allow significant rate reductions. Secondly, it is even more difficult to identify provisions that 8 Chuck Marr, Chye-Ching Huang, and Joel Friedman, Tax Expenditure Reform: An Essential Ingredient of Needed Deficit Reduction, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, February 27, 2013, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=view&id=3912; Chuck Marr and Brian Highsmith, Reforming Tax Expenditures Can Reduce Deficits While Making the Tax Code More Efficient and Equitable, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, April 15, 2011, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=3472; and Lily Batchelder, Fred Goldberg, and Peter Orszag, Efficiency and Tax Incentives: The Case for Refundable Tax Credits, Stanford Law Review, Volume 59, Issue 1, 2006, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=941582. 9 John L. Buckley, Tax Expenditure Reform: Some Common Misconceptions, Tax Notes, July 18, 2011. 10 Jane G. Gravelle and Thomas L. Hungerford, The Challenge of Individual Income Tax Reform: An Economic Analysis of Tax Base Broadening, Congressional Research Service, March 22, 2012, http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-srv/business/documents/crstaxreform.pdf. Because the American Taxpayer Relief Act prevented tax rates from fully returning to Clinton-era levels, as this analysis assumed, both the revenue estimates from base broadening and the resulting rate reduction would be somewhat smaller against the new current law baseline, given the same assumptions about the level of base broadening. 11 Jane G. Gravelle, Statement on Tax Reform and Residential Real Estate, The Ways and Means Committee United States House of Representatives, April 25, 2013. 6

would allow significant reductions of the top rate, while maintaining the current distribution of tax burdens. Indeed, President Obama s proposal to cap the value of the largest individual tax expenditures (including such popular deductions such as those for mortgage interest and charitable giving and the exclusion for employer-provided health insurance) at 28 percent would raise $493 billion over ten years. 12 Policymakers would need to cut tax expenditures by over ten times as much as the Obama proposal to pay for the House rate-cut proposals. Yet, the Obama proposal continues to face strong opposition on Capitol Hill. 13 Compounding the revenue problem is an often overlooked fact: the more that income tax rates fall, the less revenue that policymakers can raise by scaling back tax expenditures. Most tax expenditures reduce the amount of a taxpayer s income that s subject to income tax rates, so their cost depends on the taxpayer s marginal tax rate. For example, each additional $1 deduction reduces revenues by 15 cents if a taxpayer is in the 15 percent tax bracket but by almost 40 cents if the taxpayer is in the 39.6 percent bracket. When tax rates fall, the cost of these tax expenditures falls with them and, as a result, policies to scale them back raise less revenue. TPC analysis suggests that cutting rates by 20 percent and eliminating the AMT would reduce revenues available from base broadening by roughly 20 percent. 14 Pitfalls of Deficit-Neutral Tax Reform Let s suppose policymakers craft a tax reform bill that s truly deficit neutral such as by scaling back their desired rate cuts and making sufficient changes in tax expenditures to offset the cost. That would create a serious problem of its own by paralyzing efforts to reach a long-term deficit reduction agreement, possibly for a number of years. If policymakers enact deficit-neutral tax reform, they will have made the politically possible changes in tax expenditures while locking in lower tax rates. Because policymakers would have nowhere else to go on the tax expenditure front, revenue would likely be effectively off the table for the further deficit reduction that despite the fiscal improvement in recent years is still needed to put the nation on a sustainable long-term path. 15 The fiscal ramifications would extend beyond revenue. Politically speaking, any large long-term budget agreement will likely include both reductions in mandatory spending (for example, in Medicare) and additional revenue. Those who oppose mandatory spending cuts would almost certainly relent only if the proponents of such cuts agree to team them with tax increases. So, 12 Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimated Budget Effects Of The Revenue Provisions Contained In The President s Fiscal Year Budget Proposal, May 10, 2013, https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=4520. 13 Hart Research Associates polling for Americans for Tax Fairness, Americans for Tax Fairness Post Fiscal Cliff Poll, January, 2013, http://www.americansfortaxfairness.org/files/atf-post-fiscal-cliff-poll-v-media-final.ppt 14 Samuel Brown, William G. Gale, and Adam Looney, On the Distributional Effects of Base-Broadening Income Tax Reform, Tax Policy Center, August 1, 2012, http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/publications/url.cfm?id=1001628. 15 Richard Kogan, Kathy Ruffing and Paul N. Van de Water, Long-Term Budget Outlook Remains Challenging, But Recent Legislation Has Made It More Manageable, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, June 27, 2013, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=3983. 7

deficit-neutral tax reform would likely take such spending cuts off the table as well, leaving policymakers nowhere to turn for more mid-term and long-term deficit reduction. Box 2: Efficiency Gains from Tax Reform May Be Modest Proponents of broadening the tax base and lowering tax rates often tout the potential for such measures to boost economic growth. Policymakers can and should seek to reform tax expenditures in ways that make the tax code more efficient. The economic gains, however, would likely prove modest. Some studies have found significant efficiency gains from fundamental tax reform, but [m]ost economists asserting the economic benefits of tax reform are modeling their vision of an ideal tax system, notes John Buckley, former Joint Tax Committee chief of staff and former chief tax counsel for the House Ways and Means Committee. Most often, it is a vision that would have little political viability and unrealistically low rates because of the omission of items like transition relief. a Brookings Institution tax economist William Gale writes that there are particular reasons to be skeptical that revenue-neutral tax cuts will have much effect on growth. While lower tax rates provide a stronger incentive for employment and saving, base-broadening measures would increase the portion of Americans income that is subject to tax, and this would create incentives that would work in the other direction. At the end of the day, the net effects on labor supply and saving behavior would likely be small. b As a case in point, the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86) the last major effort to broaden the tax base and reduce rates appears to have produced little impact on economic growth. Summarizing the results of a conference sponsored by the University of Michigan, Henry Aaron, another Brookings tax expert, wrote, Most of the papers presented at this conference reinforce the casual observation that TRA86 has had little effect on the broad measures of real economic activity in which most economists are interested. c Moreover, the economy will likely grow faster over the long term if policymakers use the revenues they raise from tax reform primarily for deficit reduction rather than tax rate cuts. That s why the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) concluded in 2012 that letting President Bush s tax cuts expire and dedicating the revenues to deficit reduction would ultimately raise U.S. residents income more than otherwise, and that the boost to national saving would outweigh any loss of economic efficiency due to the higher taxes. d A tax reform package that achieved modest efficiency gains from base broadening but contributed little if anything to deficit reduction would likely do less for long-term economic growth than limiting tax expenditures and applying the savings in whole or substantial part to deficit reduction. a John L. Buckley, Written Testimony Of John L. Buckley, Visiting Professor Georgetown University Law Center Committee On Ways And Means, September 21, 2011, http://waysandmeans.house.gov/uploadedfiles/buckley_testimony921.pdf. For example, previous JCT studies of base-broadening, rate-lowering tax reform have omitted transition relief; see Thomas A Barthold, Letter to Senate Committee on Finance Chairman Max Baucus and Ranking Member Orrin G. Hatch, October 12, 2012, http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/ezra-klein/files/2012/10/bn_101212_192832.pdf. Similarly, an illustrative tax reform example from CBO does not explicitly account for transition relief; see Congressional Budget Office, Choices for Deficit Reduction, November 8, 2012, http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43692, p. 25. b Samuel Brown, William G. Gale, and Adam Looney, On the Distributional Effects of Base-Broadening Income Tax Reform, Tax Policy Center, August 1, 2012, http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/publications/url.cfm?id=1001628. c Henry J. Aaron, Lessons for Tax Reform, in Joel Slemrod (ed.), Do Taxes Matter? (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1990), p. 322. d Douglas W. Elmendorf, Director, Congressional Budget Office, The Economic Outlook and Fiscal Policy Choices, Testimony before the Senate Committee on the Budget, September 28, 2010, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/118xx/doc11874/09-28- EconomicOutlook_Testimony.pdf. 8

Lengthening the Life of Sequestration The President and Congress created sequestration in the 2011 Budget Committee Act. If the congressional supercommittee failed to craft a plan to reduce deficits by $1.5 trillion over the next decade (as it did), then sequestration would generate $1.2 trillion in budget savings through nine years of automatic annual budget cuts, with an equal mix from defense and non-defense programs. Policymakers assumed that, facing such a blunt process and such mindless cuts to both defense and non-defense programs, the President and Congress would come together on a long-term plan that would replace sequestration with a better designed, more balanced approach to deficit reduction. Defying those expectations, sequestration took effect this spring and will almost certainly remain in effect for the rest of the current fiscal year. Moving forward, the political path to ending it remains the same replacing it with a broad, balanced plan of both more revenues and savings in mandatory programs that help address the long-term budget challenge. Deficit-neutral tax reform that claims the politically achievable savings from scaling back tax expenditures and locks in lower tax rates makes that more balanced deal much harder for policymakers to craft. The harder it is from them to craft it, the longer that sequestration will likely remain in effect. Avoiding a Tax Reform Trap The primary goal of tax policy should be to raise additional revenue, in a progressive fashion, as part of a balanced approach to long-term fiscal health. The primary goal should not be to cut tax rates further. Tax expenditures should be a prime target for revenue raising. For one thing, they suffer from a key design flaw their value rises as household income rises, so they provide the biggest benefits to the people who least need a tax incentive to buy a home, save for retirement, send a child to college, or the like. For another, they make the tax code less efficient by favoring some activities over others. Thus, policymakers can secure tax-expenditure savings while, at the same time, boosting the efficiency of the tax code. Yet most large tax expenditures are popular and deeply embedded in the tax code. Policymakers must be realistic about the amount of savings they can generate and they should not apply them solely to cutting tax rates and, thus, creating new obstacles to deficit reduction. 16 Policymakers should follow a first-things-first sequencing. They should pursue tax-expenditure reform as part of a balanced long-term deficit plan that also includes spending reductions. And policymakers should apply a share of the proceeds to lower rates only if they have first met the revenue targets of such a balanced deficit plan. 16 See Chuck Marr, Chye-Ching Huang, and Joel Friedman, Tax Expenditure Reform: An Essential Ingredient of Needed Deficit Reduction, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, February 27, 2013, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=view&id=3912. 9