Did Banking Reforms of the Early 1990s Fail? Lessons from Comparing Two Banking Crises

Similar documents
A Comparison of Small Bank Failures and FDIC Losses in the and Banking Crises

A Comparison of Small Bank Failures and FDIC Losses in the and Banking Crises

Economic Brief. Basel III and the Continuing Evolution of Bank Capital Regulation

Financial Stability: The Role of Real Estate Values

Following a decade of neglect, the Bush administration and Congress moved

Frequently Asked Questions and Answers NCUA s Risk-Based Capital Revised Proposed Rule January 2015

Answers to Questions: Chapter 5

A Citizen s Guide to the 2008 Financial Report of the U.S. Government

Will Greater Disclosure and Transparency Prevent the Next Banking Crisis? by Eric Rosengren* Abstract

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

LIBRARY. CP New York Financial Writers JUN T k 2r- JÒlÌoojlW, Remarks by. L. William Seidman Chairman Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

Should We Worry about Trade Imbalances?

I. Learning Objectives II. The Functions of Money III. The Components of the Money Supply

Potential Causes and Implications of the Rise in Long-Term Unemployment 1

Remarks given at IADI conference on Designing an Optimal Deposit Insurance System

Economic Brief. Welfare Analysis of Debit Card Interchange Fee Regulation

Group 14 Dallas Hall, Chuck Dobson, Guy Tahye, Tunde Olabiyi

THE ROLE OF DEBT IN FARMLAND OWNERSHIP

CURRENT WEAKNESS OF DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND RECOMMENDED REFORMS. Heather Bickenheuser May 5, 2003

BANK OF UGANDA. Key Note Address by. Louis Kasekende (PhD) Deputy Governor, Bank of Uganda

FDICIA's Prompt Corrective Action Provisions

Joe Peek and Eric S. Rosengren

Fund Balance Adequacy. This chapter examines the adequacy of the trust fund balance for Minnesota s

Economic Brief. When Did the Recession End?

Chapter 11. Economic Analysis of Banking Regulation

COMMENTARY NUMBER 462 June Trade Balance, Consumer Credit. August 9, Bernanke Bemoans GDP Not Reflecting Common Experience

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

The zombie businesses phenomenon: An update

Ally Financial Inc. Basel III Public Disclosures. As of and for the three months ended December 31, 2017

Chapter Fourteen. Chapter 10 Regulating the Financial System 5/6/2018. Financial Crisis

Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress

Six recommendations for maintaining financial stability

Basel Pillar 3 Disclosures

e-brief Not Here? Housing Market Policy and the Risk of a Housing Bust

Revised Draft 12/05/03 FDIC LOSSES IN BANK FAILURES: HAS FDICIA MADE A DIFFERENCE?

16. Because of the large amount of equity on a typical commercial bank balance sheet, credit risk is not a significant risk to bank managers.

Educational Attainment and Economic Outcomes

MADAGASCAR ECONOMIC UPDATE: A Transition but Challenges are coming soon

REFORMING PCA. Addendum to Submitted Statements of. Mary Cunningham. and. William Raker. to the. National Credit Union Administration s

Capital Regulation at Community Banks: Lessons from 400 Failures

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Don t Raise the Federal Debt Ceiling, Torpedo the U.S. Housing Market

The Great Recession How Bad Is It and What Can We Do?

Federal Reserve System/IMF/World Bank. Seminar for Senior Bank Supervisors October 19 30, David S. Hoelscher

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Compensation and Risk Incentives in Banking and Finance Jian Cai, Kent Cherny, and Todd Milbourn

The wave of bank and savings and loan failures in the 1980s and

HC 676 SesSIon december HM Treasury. Maintaining the financial stability of UK banks: update on the support schemes

Chapter 18. Financial Regulation. Chapter Preview

Taxing Risk* Narayana Kocherlakota. President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Economic Club of Minnesota. Minneapolis, Minnesota.

Summary. The importance of accessing formal credit markets

TABLE OF CONTENTS. President's Letter to Shareholders Selected Consolidated Financial and Other Data... 2

10.2 Recent Shocks to the Macroeconomy Introduction. Housing Prices. Chapter 10 The Great Recession: A First Look

Record Household Debt, Student Loan Delinquencies Spike

Chapter 02 Financial Services: Depository Institutions

Waiting for Basel? Next steps for Canada's bank capital regime

Agricultural Credit: Institutions and Issues

Office of Material Loss Reviews Report No. MLR Material Loss Review of Great Basin Bank of Nevada, Elko, Nevada

A Steadier Course for Monetary Policy. John B. Taylor. Economics Working Paper 13107

Capital Speedboat Session 2. Charting your way through troubling waters FARIN & Associates Inc. Agenda

ECONOMY: DESPITE SLOW APRIL, FUNDAMENTALS ARE IMPROVING

The Benefits of World Capital Flows

Banking Crises Throughout the World

The Changing Banking Structure: What Expansion Strategies are Community Banks Adopting?

which was indicated to be roughly 1.5+ standard deviations from the national average. 3 Id.

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Sound residential mortgage underwriting in a changing environment

The enduring case for high-yield bonds

PCA Checkup. Prepared for: XYZ Credit Union First Quarter By: CUNA's Economics & Statistics Department

Small business credit still a problem:

HIGHER CAPITAL IS NOT A SUBSTITUTE FOR STRESS TESTS. Nellie Liang, The Brookings Institution

Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation

Banking reform in Britain

Agricultural Credit: Institutions and Issues

Economic Brief. Does Money Still Matter for Monetary Policy?

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Unemployment after the Recession: A New Natural Rate? Murat Tasci and Saeed Zaman

Spanish position on strengthening the EMU

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Americans Cut Their Debt Yuliya Demyanyk and Matthew Koepke

Prepared Testimony of Vikram S. Pandit Chief Executive Officer, Citigroup Inc. Before the Congressional Oversight Panel

Comments on the UK FSA The Turner Review and its Discussion Paper 09/2 (DP09/2)

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Three Myths about Peer-to-Peer Loans. Yuliya Demyanyk, Elena Loutskina, and Daniel Kolliner

Building a just and environmentally sound economy. Marco Vangelisti Essential Knowledge for Transition

Bank of Ocean City. Financial Statements. December 31, 2016

BERMUDA MONETARY AUTHORITY GUIDELINES ON STRESS TESTING FOR THE BERMUDA BANKING SECTOR

The Growing Number of Bank Failures and the D&O Insurance Marketplace

Bank Analytical Report

Unit 6 Measuring and Monitoring Economics (Ch 12 and 13)

SHARE INSURANCE FUND ANALYSIS & FORECAST

Homeowner Affordability and Stability Plan Fact Sheet

Gauging Current Conditions:

Testimony before the Joint Economic Committee at the Hearing on Monetary Policy Going Forward: Why a Sound Dollar Boosts Growth and Employment

C A Y M A N I S L A N D S MONETARY AUTHORITY

Bank of Ocean City. Financial Statements. December 31, 2017

NEW YORK STATE BAR ASSOCIATION TAX SECTION REPORT ON FDIC-ASSISTED TAXABLE ACQUISITIONS

Revised Draft 1/21/04 FDIC LOSSES IN BANK FAILURES: HAS FDICIA MADE A DIFFERENCE?

The lender of last resort: liquidity provision versus the possibility of bail-out

Chapter E: The US versus EU resolution regime

Basel III Standardized Approach Disclosures. For the quarter ended June 30, 2018

Agricultural Credit: Institutions and Issues

FRBSF Economic Letter

Transcription:

Economic Brief June 2015, EB15-06 Did Banking Reforms of the Early 1990s Fail? Lessons from Comparing Two Banking Crises By Eliana Balla, Helen Fessenden, Edward Simpson Prescott, and John R. Walter New Richmond Fed research on community and midsize banks evaluates the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) and Basel I by comparing failures in the 1986 92 period to those in 2007 13. Banks greatly increased commercial real estate lending between the two banking crises, but higher capital mitigated this risk. Failure rates in the recent crisis were mainly driven by the severity of the economic shocks. However, higher capital did not help contain FDIC losses, which were much larger in the recent crisis. One possible explanation is limitations in the accounting triggers used by FDICIA s prompt corrective action requirement. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, nearly 1,000 banks failed, as did hundreds of thrifts. In response to this crisis, policymakers implemented a series of reforms designed to improve the safety and soundness of the banking system. Two of the most significant were the increased capital requirements that came out of the 1988 Basel Accord and changes to the handling of troubled banks under the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) of 1991. The two most important reforms in FDICIA were a requirement that the FDIC resolve a failing bank through the least-costly means possible and a mandate that a bank s regulator intervene if the bank s regulatory capital falls below designated thresholds. The motivation behind this pre-emptive provision, known as prompt corrective action (PCA), was to move beyond the widespread practice in the 1980s of forbear- ance that is, allowing troubled institutions to stay open in hopes their financial position would recover. When a struggling bank was granted forbearance, the delay often meant that the eventual costs to the FDIC following its failure would rise. The 1989 federal bailout of the thrift industry ultimately cost taxpayers more than $120 billion. The authors of FDICIA sought to avoid a repeat of this scenario. This Economic Brief discusses new research by three of its authors (Balla, Prescott, and Walter), who compared the causes of bank failures and FDIC losses in periods before and after the reforms. A Tale of Two Downturns While U.S. economic performance was strong in the late 1980s, interrupted by only a mild recession in 1990 91, there were severe downturns in several regions of the country. The collapse EB15-06 - Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Page 1

of oil prices in the mid-1980s hurt states like Texas, while New England experienced a collapse of real estate prices around 1990. These regional downturns were a significant factor in the troubles faced by commercial banks during this period. From 1986 through 1992, nearly 1,000 commercial banks failed. In contrast, the 2007 08 financial crisis was part of a national downturn that was much more severe. Nevertheless, the fraction of commercial banks that failed was similar to that of the earlier period. From 2007 through 2013, when there were roughly half the number of banks of the earlier period, 403 commercial banks failed. (See Figure 1.) Balla, Prescott, and Walter compared these two periods by estimating models of bank failure and FDIC losses for each banking crisis, focusing on established (as opposed to newly chartered) community and midsize banks. 1 Their goal was to assess whether the regulatory reforms of the early 1990s made a difference to bank failure rates and FDIC losses. For community and midsize banks, they found that on many dimensions the two crises were quite alike. The same bank characteristics that predicted failure in the previous crisis predicted failure in the later one. Banks were less likely to fail if they were funded substantially by core deposits, had more capital, held more in securities, or were large institutions. Not surprisingly, banks headquartered in states that had bigger drops in housing prices and bigger increases in unemployment failed more often, as did those with more nonperforming loans. Furthermore, banks that did more commercial real estate (CRE) lending and construction and land development (CLD) lending, in particular, were also more likely to fail. Despite these similarities, there were several significant differences between the two periods. One of the most striking was the increased concentration of CRE and CLD lending by community and midsize banks. For the banks in the researchers sample, CRE lending rose from 6 percent to 21 percent of banks loans in the years between the two crises, while CLD lending jumped from 4 percent to 22 percent. What is noteworthy and less well known is that while the volume of CRE lending increased markedly over the intervening years, banks also were building up their defenses against insolvency. For the banks in this sample, average capital ratios rose from 8.5 percent in the 1980s to 11 percent two decades later. The researchers found that these higher capital levels partially offset the risk posed by the rise in real estate lending. Not only did real estate concentrations change between the two periods, but the degree and scope of the economic shocks drops in housing prices and Figure 1: Number of Commercial Bank Failures by Year 300 250 200 150 100 50 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 Source: FDIC Historical Statistics on Banking, Failures and Assistance Transactions Database Page 2

increases in unemployment levels at the state level differed as well. In particular, the economic shocks were much larger in the later period than they were in the earlier period, when they were more regional in nature. To isolate the role of the economic shocks, the researchers performed a counterfactual analysis in which they took banks with the mix of characteristics in one period and subjected them to the economic shocks of the other period. They found that banks with the characteristics of those in late 1985 for example, types of lending, size of assets, and capital ratios would have failed at a much higher rate if they had experienced the more severe state-level economic shocks of 2007 13. Conversely, banks with the characteristics of those in late 2006 would have failed at a much lower rate under the shocks from 1986 92, which were less harsh. The actual failure rate in the first period, 5.6 percent, would have jumped to 11.6 percent if the economic effects of 2007 13 were applied. Meanwhile, the actual failure rate in the more recent downturn, 4.6 percent, would have dropped to 1.4 percent under the conditions of 1986 92. The analysis suggests that community and midsize banks were better prepared for the recent crisis than they were for the previous one. It also suggests that despite the increased concentration in real estate lending by community and midsize banks, the large numbers of failures were mainly due to bad luck in the form of a very deep national recession. Indeed, if they had experienced economic shocks like those of the late 1980s, the crisis would have been relatively mild for them. Higher capital holdings, primarily the result of PCA and Basel I, helped reduce the chance of failure as banks faced the massive shocks of 2007 13 and countered the increased chance of failure from increased lending in riskier sectors such as CRE and CLD. By this measure, the reforms in the earlier period improved the regulation of community and midsize banks. Where PCA Fell Short While the researchers analysis of bank failures implies that PCA and the other reforms may have helped reduce failure probabilities, it also suggests that PCA fell short as a tool for reducing FDIC losses on failed banks. The FDIC s loss ratio was about 24 percent of a failed bank s assets in 2007 13 compared with only 14 percent in 1986 92, once these ratios are weighted for bank size. 2 (The loss ratio is the FDIC s losses on a failed bank divided by the assets of that bank.) The researchers did not identify a particular set of bank characteristics that fully explain the large increase in FDIC losses. However, their analysis suggests two complementary factors were at work. First, while capital levels were higher leading into the recent crisis, helping reduce failure probabilities, this extra capital provided only a small buffer for losses in those cases when a bank failed. Second, market values of bank assets can differ from their book values, sometimes dramatically. In the recent crisis, which saw a sudden drop in real estate prices and a corresponding fall in loan collateral values, asset book values may have significantly lagged market values. The difference between book and market values is particularly relevant for the operation of the PCA provision of FDICIA. Before the Act, regulators had some leeway in deciding when to place a bank into FDIC receivership. As noted above, this flexibility led to widespread forbearance. FDICIA, by contrast, required regulators to restrict a bank s activities (such as bonus or dividend payments) if its book capital fell below certain levels. A bank is considered well capitalized and faces no restrictions if its risk-based capital ratio is 10 percent or more; its Tier 1 risk-based capital ratio is 6 percent or more; and its leverage ratio is 5 percent or more. If these ratios drop below specific targets, regulators enforce restrictions and designate the bank as undercapitalized, significantly undercapitalized, or critically undercapitalized. In the last case, the trigger is a ratio of equity-to-total assets of 2 percent or less, and the bank generally must go into receivership or conservatorship within 90 days. The FDIC then handles the disposition, which usually means transferring the bank s liabilities and selling some or most of its assets to another bank, usually with FDIC assistance. 3 In such cases, the cost borne by the FDIC largely depends on how much it must pay to the acquirer Page 3

to take over the failed bank as well as the FDIC s receivership costs. 4 The price the acquirer is willing to accept, in turn, is based on factors such as the quality of assets, the value of the failed bank s charter, its core deposits, and any loss-sharing agreement reached with the FDIC. Notably, in the more recent crisis, most of the banks that went into receivership still had positive equity capital, but the losses to the FDIC were nevertheless enormous by historical standards. This suggests that failed banks market values were far less than their book values. In the 2007 13 period, the average capital ratio of failed banks in the quarter before failure was positive, about 1.5 percent. Since that is close to the 2 percent cutoff, the PCA requirement was carried out as intended. However, as noted above, the resulting losses were far greater as a percentage of assets than they were during 1986 92, when the capital level of a typical failing bank was negative 2 percent. In other words, the extra equity capital required by PCA capital triggers did not provide much of an extra buffer to absorb losses. (See Figure 2.) Another Possible Indicator Possibly related to the difference in book and market value of assets is an item on banks balance sheets called interest accrued but not yet received. The researchers found that in both periods, the ratio of this variable to bank assets strongly predicts both the chance of failure and the scale of losses. 5 Interest accrued but not yet received is an asset on the balance sheet that measures interest income that the bank has recognized on an accrual basis even though it has not yet received cash payments. This variable can measure benign situations for example, an agricultural loan in which income is accrued throughout the growing season but no cash payment arrives until harvest time. However, the account also can measure loans that are delinquent but have not yet been put on nonaccrual status. Typically, a bank has some discretion with how it categorizes delinquent or potentially delinquent loans. There could be situations where it is clear that the loan will not repay, but the bank does not treat it that way. In these cases, this accounting variable may serve as a red flag that additional losses on loans are forthcoming even though book value measurements do not reflect them yet. Conclusion For community and midsize banks, the two banking crises look surprisingly similar despite differences in the severity of economic shocks and divergent policy responses. The same mix of factors predicted bank insolvencies as well as FDIC losses: capital levels, size, security holdings, CRE and CLD lending, Figure 2: Average Capital Ratios of Failed Banks in the 16 Quarters Prior to Failure 12 10 8 6 4 2007-13 1986-92 2 0-2 -4 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Source: Consolidated Reports of Condition and Income (Call Reports) Page 4

nonperforming loans, core deposits, and key economic and housing indicators. The main distinction between the two episodes was the severity of economic shocks, which was the most important factor in determining the chance of bank failure. Although the increased concentration in commercial real estate lending since the 1980s also contributed to additional risk, this was mitigated by banks higher capital levels, which were due primarily to the financial reforms of the early 1990s. The researchers analysis suggests that the poor performance of the community and midsize banks in the recent crisis was due more to the misfortune of a historically deep recession than to their high real estate lending concentrations. While PCA and other reforms may have helped reduce failure probabilities, they did not seem to help reduce FDIC losses on failed banks. FDICIA s PCA provisions often did lead to closure before a bank had negative capital, but they did not prevent sizeable losses in those cases when accounting values that is, those related to the intervention trigger significantly lagged market values. Eliana Balla is a lead financial economist in the Supervision, Regulation and Credit Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Helen Fessenden is an economics writer, Edward Simpson Prescott is a senior economist and vice president, and John R. Walter is a senior economist and research advisor in the Bank s Research Department. Endnotes 1 See Eliana Balla, Edward Simpson Prescott, and John R. Walter, Did the Financial Reforms of the Early 1990s Fail? A Comparison of Bank Failures and FDIC Losses in the 1986-92 and 2007 13 Periods, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 15-05, May 2015. 2 This adjustment takes into account the loss absorption capacity provided from book equity, if there is any, at the time of failure. If the ratios are equally weighted that is, not adjusted for the size of the bank they are 22 percent for 1986 92 and 30 percent for 2007 13. See Balla, Prescott, Walter, Table 1. 3 See John R. Walter, Closing Troubled Banks: How the Process Works, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, Winter 2004, vol. 90, no. 1, pp. 51 68. 4 If a failed bank finds no buyer and the FDIC has to pay off insured depositors, the FDIC has to absorb those losses instead. During the more recent crisis, the federal government increased FDIC insurance coverage from $100,000 to $250,000. 5 Some of the literature on FDIC losses has identified the importance of this variable, but its connection to bank failure has not been previously identified. See John F. Bovenzi, and Arthur J. Murton, Resolution Costs of Bank Failures, FDIC Banking Review, September 1988, vol. 1, pp. 1-13. This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the italicized statement below. Views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND Richmond Baltimore Charlotte Page 5