Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim)

Similar documents
Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development?

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development?

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development?

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks.

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Discussion of Chiu, Meh and Wright

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records

Capital Goods Trade and Economic Development

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

Household Labor Supply in a Heterogeneous-Agents Model with Tradable Home Labor

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

The Implications of a Greying Japan for Public Policy.

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development?

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Reproductive health, female empowerment and economic prosperity. Elizabeth Frankenberg Duncan Thomas

The Effects of Financial Inclusion on Children s Schooling, and Parental Aspirations and Expectations

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002

Examining the Household Responses to the Recession Wealth Shocks:

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. January For students electing

Collective Model with Children: Public Good and Household Production

Final Exam Solutions

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

Exercises in Growth Theory and Empirics

Public versus Private Investment in Human Capital: Endogenous Growth and Income Inequality

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

1 Dynamic programming

Financial Crises, Dollarization and Lending of Last Resort in Open Economies

Corporate Finance and Monetary Policy

Household Saving, Financial Constraints, and the Current Account Balance in China

RESOURCE POOLING WITHIN FAMILY NETWORKS: INSURANCE AND INVESTMENT

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Prof. J. Sachs May 26, 2016 FIRST DRAFT COMMENTS WELCOME PLEASE QUOTE ONLY WITH PERMISSION

Optimal Income Taxation of Married Couples: An Empirical Analysis of Joint and Individual Taxation

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Online Appendix. Long-term Changes in Married Couples Labor Supply and Taxes: Evidence from the US and Europe Since the 1980s

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

Revisiting the cost of children: theory and evidence from Ireland

Time, Uncertainty, and Incomplete Markets

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Problem set Fall 2012.

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

Labor Supply and Taxation in Europe

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect

Fertility, Human Capital, and Economic Growth over the Demographic Transition

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe

Reforming the Social Security Earnings Cap: The Role of Endogenous Human Capital

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

ECON6035 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Game Theory Fall 2003

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Gender Pay Gap Report

Schooling Investment and Development

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

Growth Theory: Review

Child Mortality Decline, Inequality and Economic Growth

Public Pension Reform in Japan

Intergenerational Transfers and Old-Age Security in Korea

Location, Productivity, and Trade

This test has 30 questions. ANSWER ALL QUESTIONS. All questions carry equal (4) marks.

Capital Income Tax Reform and the Japanese Economy (Very Preliminary and Incomplete)

Intergenerational transfers, tax policies and public debt

International Trade: Lecture 3

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Inside the Household

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

QUESTION 1 QUESTION 2

Transcription:

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim)

Evidence

Evidence :

Evidence :

Evidence :

Evidence : :

Evidence : :

Evidence : :

Evidence

Development Policy Based on this evidence, various development policies and programs target women. Prominent examples: Microcredit. Conditional cash transfer programs (PROGRESA).

Question Is targeting transfers to women a good idea?

The Conventional Interpretation Cooperative bargaining model offers one specific interpretation of the facts: 1. Women care more about children than men do. 2. Women s bargaining power is increasing in their wealth. Interpretation suggests that, indeed, empowering women should benefit children, and thus development. But is this interpretation correct?

Our Interpretation We show that facts can also be explained by non-cooperative bargaining model with household production. Model does not rely on preference differences between men and women. Instead, mechanism builds on specialization in time- and goods-intensive household tasks driven by gender wage gap.

Implications for Development No Longer Clear Cut Wealth transfer from man to woman lead to increase in female-provided and decrease in male-provided public goods. Overall effect on development depends on relative importance of those goods. Mandated transfers likely to be harmful when physical capital accumulation is key engine of growth.

Model: Preferences Husband and wife. Derive utility from private goods and continuum of public goods (such as children). Spouses have identical preferences: where g {m, f }. 1 U g = ln(c g )+ 0 ln(c i ) di, Contribute to public goods in form of goods and time.

Model: Household Production Public goods produced using household production functions involving inputs of time T and goods E. Public goods differ in relative importance of time versus goods: C g,i = T α(i) g,i E 1 α(i) g,i, C i = C f,i + C m,i, where g {m, f }, i [0, 1], α(i) increasing, α(0) = 0, α(1) = 1.

Model: Budget and Time Constraints Wages are gender specific. Assume w m > w f. Allocate income between personal consumption and public-goods contributions: 1 c g + E g,i di = w g (1 T g )+x g. 0 Allocate time between work and household production: 1 0 T g,i di = T g.

Model: First-Best Allocation Maximize weighted sum of utilities subject to joint budget constraint and time constraints. In interior equilibrium, only low-wage spouse provides public goods. Mandated transfers do not affect allocation.

Model: Equilibrium Non-cooperative decision making. Spouses play Nash equilibrium: Each spouse chooses own consumption, public-good contributions, and labor supply. Choices of other spouse taken as given. Focus on how mandated transfers affect outcome.

Characterizing the Equilibrium Each public good is provided by spouse with higher preferred provision. First-order conditions for spouse g: c g = 1 λ g, E g,i 1 α(i) λ g, T g,i α(i) w g λ g.

Characterizing the Equilibrium Ratio of female-to male preferred provision for public good i: C f,i = E 1 α(i) f,i C m,i E 1 α(i) m,i T α(i) f,i T α(i) m,i = ( wm w f ) α(i) λ m λ f. Expression strictly increasing in α(i). Equilibrium characterized by cutoff ī: Goods with i < ī provided by husband (goods intensive). Goods with i > ī provided by wife (time intensive). Cutoff satisfies Cf,i = C m,i.

Characterizing the Equilibrium Determination of public-good provision: 0.8 Female Provision 0.7 Consumption 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Goods Intensive Time Intensive

Characterizing the Equilibrium Determination of public-good provision: 0.8 Female Provision Male Provision 0.7 Consumption 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Goods Intensive Time Intensive

Characterizing the Equilibrium Determination of public-good provision: Consumption 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 Female Provision Male Provision Equilibrium Provision 0.3 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Goods Intensive Time Intensive

Mandated Transfers Consider mandated wealth transfer from husband to wife. Conditional on cutoff ī, husband will spend less on public goods, wife will spend more. Effect offset by shift in cutoff ī. However, only partial offset: Higher equilibrium spending by wife.

Mandated Transfers Baseline before transfer: 0.8 0.7 Consumption 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Goods Intensive Time Intensive

Mandated Transfers Counterfactual outcome for constant ī: 0.8 0.7 Consumption 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Goods Intensive Time Intensive

Mandated Transfers Outcome with new ī: 0.8 0.7 Consumption 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Goods Intensive Time Intensive

Mandated Transfers Transfer increases supply of public goods provided by recipient. True as long as relative willingness to pay for public goods is different at new compared to old cutoff. Effect would be even larger in model where spouses have absolute advantage at providing certain goods.

Mandated Transfers: Role of Relative Wages Pre- and post-transfer outcome for w f = 0.5: 0.8 0.7 Consumption 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Goods Intensive Time Intensive

Mandated Transfers: Role of Relative Wages Pre- and post-transfer outcome for w f = 0.9: 0.8 0.7 Consumption 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Goods Intensive Time Intensive

Mandated Transfers: Effect on Total Provision Can trace out how targeted transfers affect total provision of public goods: 1 ln(c i ) di. 0 Two effects: 1. Expenditure Share Channel: Provision increases with wealth of spouse who spends larger fraction of resources on public goods. 2. Efficiency Channel: Transfer from husband to wife shifts use of time towards efficient arrangement. When α(i) = i (symmetric case), efficiency channel dominates for interior solution. However, expenditure share channel can dominate when large range of public goods is goods-intensive.

Mandated Transfers: Effect on Total Provision Cutoff between male and female public good provision as a function of transfer from husband to wife: 1 0.9 w f =0.3 0.8 Provision Cutoff 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0.5 0 0.5 Transfer to Wife

Mandated Transfers: Effect on Total Provision Cutoff between male and female public good provision as a function of transfer from husband to wife: 1 0.9 0.8 w f =0.3 w f =0.5 Provision Cutoff 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0.5 0 0.5 Transfer to Wife

Mandated Transfers: Effect on Total Provision Total utility derived from public goods as a function of transfer from husband to wife: 0.2 0.25 w f =0.3 Public Good Utility 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55 0.5 0 0.5 Transfer to Wife

Mandated Transfers: Effect on Total Provision Total utility derived from public goods as a function of transfer from husband to wife: Public Good Utility 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 w f =0.3 w f =0.5 0.55 0.5 0 0.5 Transfer to Wife

Growth Implications of Mandated Transfers Growth model with successive generations. Each couple has one daughter and one son. Parents care about own consumption and children s full income: U(c g, y ) = ln(c g )+ln(y ). Output T produced using physical and human capital: Factor accumulation: Y = AK 1 θ H θ. Physical capital is left as a bequest to children (money intensive). Human capital is produced with a variety of inputs involving time (time intensive). Exogenous gender gap; female productivity is δ < 1 of male productivity.

Growth Implications of Mandated Transfers Constraints for parent s optimization problem: k =b = b f + b m, ln(h ) = 1 0 ln(c f,i + C m,i ) di, C g,i =Eg,i 1 i (T g,i h) i, 1 c g + b g + E g,i di = 1 [ ( w g h 1 0 2 y = r k + w h. 1 0 ) ] T g,i di + rk + τ g, b and h are split equally between daughter and son. Mandated transfers satisfy: τ f + τ m = 0.

Growth Implications of Mandated Transfers Preferences can alternatively be represented as: with: U(c g, k, h ) = log(c g )+β k log(k )+(1 β k ) log(h ), β k = (1 θ)φ θ +(1 θ)φ. Decision problem in growth model is special case of decision problem in general problem, with: α(i) = { 0 for 0 i βk, i β k 1 β k for β k < i 1, Key implication: Implicit weight on goods-intensive goods decreasing in human capital share θ.

Growth Implications of Mandated Transfers Assume mandated transfers are proportional to output per capita. Model has balanced growth path. Even during transition path, time allocation is fixed. Key result: Sign of effect of mandated transfer on output depends on human capital share θ: Y τ f { < 0 if θ small, > 0 if θ large.

Growth Implications of Mandated Transfers 1.5 Percent Change in Output 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 Transfer Lowers Growth Transfer Increases Growth 1.5 0.45 0.5 0.55 0.6 0.65 0.7 θ (Share of Human Capital)

Mandated Transfers: Summary Wealth transfer from husband to wife leads to higher provision of female-provided public goods. Comes (at least partially) at expense of lower public-good spending by husband...... whereas in preference-gap model higher public good spending comes at expense of husband s private consumption.

Mandated Transfers: Summary Welfare effect depends on how important male-provided public goods are. One such good: Household investment. Empirical findings consistent with higher male propensity to save and invest.

Conclusions Non-cooperative bargaining model can explain impact of mandated transfers on household expenditures. Impact of mandated transfers declines as men and women become more similar (lower gender gap). Mandated transfers are a bad idea at stage of development where growth is driven by physical capital accumulation.