Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Similar documents
Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Ec2723, Asset Pricing I Class Notes, Fall Complete Markets, Incomplete Markets, and the Stochastic Discount Factor

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

One-Period Valuation Theory

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 7

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Topic 1: Basic Concepts in Finance. Slides

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Financial Decisions and Markets: A Course in Asset Pricing. John Y. Campbell. Princeton University Press Princeton and Oxford

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Introduction to Asset Pricing: Overview, Motivation, Structure

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

1 Dynamic programming

Slides III - Complete Markets

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Lecture 11. Fixing the C-CAPM

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

Applying the Basic Model

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

The Equity Premium. Blake LeBaron Reading: Cochrane(chap 21, 2017), Campbell(2017/2003) October Fin305f, LeBaron

Advanced Portfolio Theory

1 No-arbitrage pricing

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

The Consumption of Active Investors and Asset Prices

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Feb. 20th, Recursive, Stochastic Growth Model

Consumption-Based Model and Overview

Applied Macro Finance

Fin 501: Asset Pricing Fin 501:

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Is asset-pricing pure data-mining? If so, what happened to theory?

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

The Econometrics of Financial Returns

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Ch. 2. Asset Pricing Theory (721383S)

Optimizing Portfolios

Economics 8106 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 2

Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS SEPTEMBER 13, 2010 BASICS. Introduction

CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL JANUARY 19, 2018

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments.

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

B35150 Winter 2014 Quiz Solutions

LECTURE 06: SHARPE RATIO, BONDS, & THE EQUITY PREMIUM PUZZLE

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Asset Pricing and Portfolio. Choice Theory SECOND EDITION. Kerry E. Back

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Byamungu Mjella CONDITIONAL CHARACTERISTICS OF RISK-RETURN TRADE-OFF: A STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR FRAMEWORK

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Asset Pricing and the Equity Premium Puzzle: A Review Essay

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Predicting the Market

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Continuous time Asset Pricing

Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns. Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen

Quantitative Risk Management

Arbitrage, State Prices and Portfolio Theory Handbook of the Economics of Finance

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

Explaining basic asset pricing facts with models that are consistent with basic macroeconomic facts

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Mean-Variance Analysis

LECTURE 07: MULTI-PERIOD MODEL

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets

EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS

Transcription:

Basics of Asset Pricing Ali Nejadmalayeri January 2009

No-Arbitrage and Equilibrium Pricing in Complete Markets: Imagine a finite state space with s {1,..., S} where there exist n traded assets with a price vector p = {p 1,..., p n }. A portfolio w = {w 1,..., w n } is then an arbitrage portfolio if: pw 0 and Πw > 0, where Π is the Arrow-Debreu tableau of prices. The Arrow-Debreu price is the price of the Arrow-Debreu security (also known as state security, state-contingent claim, and pure security ): a security that pays off one unit of numeraire in one and only one future state of nature. Markets are called complete if payoff matrix for all assets has a rank S. In these markets, then market equivalent theorem holds. 1

Market Equivalent Theorem: Consider an economy with as many different securities as states (i.e., complete market). The equilibrium portfolio choice of each investor and the equilibrium security prices will be the same in that economy as in an otherwise identical economy, but where the original securities are replaced with a full set of state-securities. For instance, a risk-less asset s return is given as R = (1 Π) 1 = S i=1 π i, where 1 is a vector of ones and Π is the Arrow-Debreu tableau of prices. 2

The Fundamental Theorem of Finance: The following are equivalent: 1. No Arbitrage 2. The existence of a positive linear pricing rule that prices all assets 3. The existence of a (finite) optimal demand for some agent who prefers more to less Proof: Dybvig and Ross (1987). The upshot of their proof is that in complete markets with no arbitrage then there would exists a unique linear pricing rule, q, such that p = qπ. The linear pricing rule is then given by q = pπ 1. 3

Definition: Martingale or risk-neutral probabilities are a set of probabilities, π, such that for any asset with payoff vector z = {z 1,..., z S }, the value is given by: v(z) = 1 1 + R E [z] = S i=1 π i z i Definition: A state price density or pricing kernel is a vector, Φ = {φ 1,..., φ S }, such that for any asset with payoff vector z = {z 1,..., z S }, the value is given by: v(z) = E[Φz] = S i=1 π i φ i z i 4

Representation Theorem: The following are equivalent: 1. There exists a linear pricing rule. 2. The martingale property: the existence of risk neutral probabilities and an associated riskless rate. 3. There exists a positive state price density or pricing kernel. Proof: Ross (2004). Let s assume a positive pricing vector q 0. For any asset with payoff vector z = {z 1,..., z S }, the value is given by v(z) = qz. The value of riskless asset is defined as v(1) = q1 = S i=1 q i. 5

Results of Representation Theorem: First, we can show that risk-neutral probabilities and linear pricing vector are linked as following: π i = q i i=1 S q i > 0 This means that risk-neutral probabilities and an associated riskless rate define state price vector as: q i = 1 1 + R π i > 0 Second, we can show that the positive price density (i.e., discount factor) is given by: φ i = q i π i > 0 6

Consumption-based Asset Pricing Let s assume we wish to find an asset s value with a time t payoff x t+1. Assume that representative investor has a power utility, u(c t ) = c1 γ 1 γ The investor wishes to maximize her life-long utility, so she solves the following: subject to: max ξ u(c t ) + E t [ β u(ct+1 ) ] c t = e t ξ p t c t+1 = e t+1 + ξ x t+1 7

Stochastic Discount Factor and Marginal Rate of Substitution The first-order conditions (or Euler equation) from the investor s utility maximization problem yields: u (c t ) p t = E t [β u (c t+1 ) x t+1 ] The intuition being that the marginal forgone utility of purchasing a share of asset i at time t should equate to the expected marginal utility of payoffs of asset i at time t + 1. Substituting the constraints into the equation, we have the asset price defined as: p t = E t [ β u (c t+1 ) u (c t ) x t+1 ] 8

Stochastic Discount Factor and Marginal Rate of Substitution We know that with one-period ahead stochastic payoffs, x i,t+1, and stochastic pricing kernel, m t+1, for asset ith at time t, then the general pricing equation is given by: p t = E t [m t+1 x t+1 ] This implies that stochastic discount factor or pricing kernel is equal to intertemporal marginal rate of substitution, or: m t+1 = βu (c t+1 ) u (c t ) 9

Classic Issues: The Real Interest Rate Without uncertainty, that is when the asset has riskless payoff, then we have: p t = 1 R f x t+1 Note that the payoff x t+1 sells at a discount. The risky assets sells at even a bigger discount, because risk-adjusted discount rate, R i, is larger than risk-free rate, R f. p i t = 1 R i E t[x t+1 ] With inflation price level index Π, then we can decompose the inflation effect by: [( p t = E t β u ) ] (c t+1 ) Π t u x t+1 (c t ) Π t+1 10

Risk-free Rate, Risk Premium, and SDF Previous discussions also mean that the riskfree can be expressed as: R f = 1 E(m) With power utility and lognormal consumption growth, then risk-free rate is expressed by: r f t = δ + γ E t( ln c t+1 ) γ2 2 σ2 t ( ln c t+1 ) With price normalized to unity, the risk-free asset and risky asset i pricing equations are given by: 1 = R f E(m) 1 = E(mR i ) Thus the risk premium is, E(R i ) R f = cov [ u (c t+1, R i t+1 )] E [ u (c t+1 ) ] 11

Expected Return-Beta Representation From previous discussions, we know m = β (c t+1 /c t ) γ Thus the risky return is: E(R i ) = R f + ( cov(m, R i ) var(m) ) ( var(m) E(m) ) or, E(R i ) = R f + β i,m λ m This is the familiar single-factor pricing form where β i,m is the quantity of risk whereas λ m is the price of risk. 12

Equity Premium Puzzle: Surprisingly large equity return volatility (i.e., large equity Sharpe ratio) as compared to volatility of aggregate consumption Mehra and Prescott (1985) noted the extremely large risk aversion needed; coined the equity premium puzzle there are certain econometric issues: mean returns are hard to estimate because the length of calendar time not number of observation matters, i.e., annual better than monthly, monthly better than daily,... selection bias due to abnormally high growth period is the U.S. Catastrophic risks are priced 13

Predictability of Aggregate Stock Returns: predicted by lagged returns, DP, EP, BM, shares new equity, Treasury term spread, changes in short-rates, relative consumption to wealth/income [Fama and French (1988), Poterba and Summers (1988), Campbell and Shiller (1988),...] concerns: longer horizon more predictable, overlapping observation cause econometric issues, many determinants are persistent and highly correlated with returns state-of-art econometrics uses log-normal joint distributions for both SDF and returns E t [ R i t+1 R f t+1] +0.5 σ 2 i = cov ( m t+1, R i t+1 ) 14

Government Bonds Returns: Treasury yield curve is upward sloped but highly convex; yield spread at 3-month, 1- year, and 2-year are 33 bps, 77 bps, and 96 bps and then remain unchnaged Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) note that steep yield curve implies a high volatility of SDF (do a simple forward rate computation and show that this is true!) The change in Treasury term spread forecasts excess Treasury bond returns. This contradict pure expectation hypothesis that contends excess bond returns are constant. This predictive power of term spread is particularly large when ad where there is greater seasonality and cyclical variations. 15

Factor Models and SDF If all investors are single-period, mean-variance optimizers, then the market portfolio is meanvariance efficient, and there exists a beta (linear) pricing between all assets and the market portfolio. In more general sense, the SDF is then a linear combination of K factors: M t+1 = a t + K k=1 b k,t f k,t+1 The negative covariance of any excess return and the SDF is then: cov ( M t+1, R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = = K k=1 b k,t σ 2 k,t+1 σ i,k,t+1 σ 2 k,t+1 = K k=1 K k=1 b k,t σ i,k,t+1 λ k,t β i,k,t+1 16

Cross-Section of Stock Returns Early evidence [Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972) and Fama and MacBeth (1973)] supported Sharpe-Litner CAPM pricing model under borrowing/lending constraints Banz (1991) reported the size effect: small firms have higher excess return than large ones [Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1995)] Basu (1983) and others show that value stocks have higher excess returns as well [Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1995)] Jagadeesh and Titman (1993) show that there is momentum effect, past 12 month of high returns leads to better future return 17

Sources of Cross-Sectional Patterns spurious results due to data snooping; small firm effect reversed in 15 year after found unknown true market index; labor income and human capital is not reflected in the traditional indexes difference between conditional and unconditional asset pricing models; case of distress risk mistakes not rather mispriced risk; patterns are found then exploited; investors overemphasize past performance of firms 18

Prices, Returns, & Cash Flows: With assets that last more than one-period, the pricing equation is general discounted dividend model: p t = E t τ=t+1 D t+τ (1 + R) τ Campbell and Shiller (1988) extended the above to allow for log-linear dividends and time-varying discount rate: p t = k 1 ρ + E t τ=0 ρ τ ( ) d t+1+τ r t+1+τ Campbell s (1991) decomposition: r t+1 E t [ rt+1 ] = [ Et+1 E t ] + [ E t+1 E t ] τ=0 τ=0 ρ τ d t+1+τ ρ τ ρ τ r t+1+τ 19

Consumption & Portfolio Choice: Imagine investor, k, who lives off financial wealth and consumes all wealth tomorrow, then the payoff Xk,t+1 on an optimal portfolio will be equal to terminal consumption C k,t+1 and: M t+1 = θ t U k ( X k,t+1 ) X k,t+1 = U 1 k ( θ 1 t M t+1 ) Single period examples: 1. Markowitz (1952) assumes quadratic utility hence mean-variance analysis 2. CAPM is the case of M t+1 which is linear in the return on the market Multiperiod case: Samuelson (1969) shows a case where 1) investor has no labor income and 2) von Nuemann-Morgenstern utility then sufficient conditions for myopic portfolio choice are either I) log utility or II) both power utility and IID returns. 20

Equilibrium Models of Representative Agent: Lucas (1978) shows that equilibrium SDF can be obtained from exogenous consumption under some utility assumption. Three puzzles are found: Equity Risk Premium Puzzle innovations in consumption are too small to cause observed large equity premium Stock Market Volatility Puzzle variations of expected future consumption growth offsets variations of dividend growth and stock returns, leaving no room for observed large equity volatility Risk-free Rate Puzzle historical upward drift in consumption implies desire to borrow from future, leading to abnormally high real risk-free rates 21

Habit Formation Models: Sunderasan (1989) and Constantinides (1990) argue for a habit formation, a positive effect of today s consumption on tomorrow s marginal utility of consumption. Utility, U(C t, Y t ), can be power function of ratio C t /Y t, or power function of difference, C t Y t. Habit can be internal depends on agent s own consumption or external depends on aggregate consumption (i.e., catching up with the Jones ). Speed with which habit reacts to individual or aggregate consumption (depends on one lag vs. gradual change) 22

External Habit Formation Models: Since an increase in previous consumption increases habit, the agent wants to increase today s consumption by borrowing from future making interest rates instable and too high. Campbell and Cochrane (1999) propose a model of external habit where interest rates are stable and stocks can have high volatility. In their construct, the log of surplus S t (C t Y t )/C t can have a AR(1) process for s t log(s t ): s t+1 = (1 ϕ) s + ϕ s t + λ(s t ) ɛ c,t+1 In this setting, the SDF is given as: m t+1 = δ ( ) γ ( ) γ St+1 Ct+1 S t C t 23

Heterogenous Agents Models: Two types of agents: 1) constrained who only consume their labor income and 2) unconstrained. Evidence suggest that consumption of stockholders is more volatile. Heaton and Lucas (1999) and Vissing-Jørgensen (1997) build general equilibrium models with a fraction of population in stock market. Constantinides and Due (1996) model says: Individuals k have different consumption levels c t. The cross sectional distribution is lognormal and changes from t to t + 1 are uncorrelated. All investor have the same power utility. In this setup, then there is valid SDF, m t+1, from intertemporal marginal rate of substitution and an invalid SDF, m RA t+1, from marginal utility of cross sectional average consumption. Then: m RA t+1 m t+1 = γ(1 γ) 2 var ( r t+1) ct+1 24

Behavioral Models: Limits to Arbitrage Limited ability to absorb demands of noise traders, this could easily due to risk when utility-maximizing agents have to buy more risky assets from noise traders. Prospect Theory Based on experimental works of Kahneman and Tversky (1979) which showed people 1) judge outcomes based on an initial reference point, and 2) have a kinked utility function; concave on gains and convex on losses. Irrational Expectation In absence of arbitrage, there exists a unique state price vector which is product of subjective state probabilities and ratio of marginal utilities. Are subjective prob. equal to objective ones? 25