Trade Volume and Economic Growth

Similar documents
A Two-sector Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting and Endogenous Technical Change

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply * 1

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

From Solow to Romer: Teaching Endogenous Technological Change in Undergraduate Economics

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Chapter 10: International Trade and the Developing Countries

Nonlinear Tax Structures and Endogenous Growth

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

1 The Solow Growth Model

Trade effects based on general equilibrium

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade

BETA CONVERGENCE IN THE EXPORT VOLUMES IN EU COUNTRIES

Testing the predictions of the Solow model:

GRA 6639 Topics in Macroeconomics

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

Kwok Tong Soo Lancaster University. Abstract

1 Continuous Time Optimization

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Gains from Trade 1-3

National Debt and Economic Growth with Externalities and Congestions

1 No capital mobility

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Athens Laboratory of Economic Policy Studies Department of Economics Athens University of Economics and Business

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth

Growth with Time Zone Differences

Dynamic Macroeconomics

1 Two Period Production Economy

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting)

Funded Pension Scheme, Endogenous Time Preference and Capital Accumulation

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

3. Trade and Development

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

DEVELOPMENT OF FINANCIAL SECTOR AN EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM SAARC COUNTRIES

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Substitution in Markusen s Classic Trade and Factor Movement Complementarity Models* Maurice Schiff World Bank and IZA

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Stanford Economics 266: International Trade Lecture 8: Factor Proportions Theory (I)

A theoretical examination of tax evasion among the self-employed

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Limited Market Participation, Financial Intermediaries, And Endogenous Growth

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Short and Long-Run Effects of Trade on Growth and Welfare

Paths of Development for Early- and Late-Bloomers in a Dynamic Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Government Spending on Infrastructure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Finite Horizons

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Income Inequality and Economic Growth: A Simple Theoretical Synthesis *

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Trade and Development

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Optimization of a Real Estate Portfolio with Contingent Portfolio Programming

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 5: The Ricardo-Viner and Heckscher-Ohlin Models (Theory I)

Chapter URL:

Fakultät III Univ.-Prof. Dr. Jan Franke-Viebach

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Role of Foreign Direct Investment in Knowledge Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence from Korean Firms Patent and Patent Citations

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Innovations in Macroeconomics

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

On the Political Substitutability between Tariffs and Subsidies a

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Eric W. Bond, Kathleen Trask, and Ping Wang

TECHNICAL TRADING AT THE CURRENCY MARKET INCREASES THE OVERSHOOTING EFFECT* MIKAEL BASK

Transcription:

Trade Volume and Economic Growth Shun-Fa Lee * Department of Industrial Economics, Tamkang University February 014 Abstract Do open economies earn better economic performance than closed economies? The most basic measure of openness is the simple trade volume, which is exports plus imports divided by GDP. A large number of empirical studies found a positive relationship, but few theoretical studies used this definition in endogenous growth models. We develop a two-country (Home and Foreign) by two-good (consumption good and investment good) by one factor (capital) endogenous growth model with international knowledge spillover to study the relationship between trade volume and economic growth. We find that trade volume are positively related to economic growth rate when a variation from the production coefficients in both countries. Keywords: two-country endogenous growth model, trade shares, economic growth JEL Classification: F43, O41. * Corresponding address: Shun-Fa Lee, Department of Industrial Economics, Tamkang University, 151 Ying-chuan Road, Tamsui, New Taipei City 5137, Taiwan. Phone: (886-) 615656 ext. 999; Fax: (886-) 609731; Email: alphalee@mail.tku.edu.tw.

1 1. Introduction Is trade openness good for economic performance? Although there are many empirical studies which provide an affirmative answer to this question, the relationship is still called in question. For instance, Rodriguez and Rodrik (001) and Winters (004) consider the results for trade liberalization from existing empirical studies are fragile. The results are crucially dependent on the variables selection for trade openness and independent variables in the regressions. Moreover, Yanikkaya (003) and DeJong and Ripoll (006) indicate that if we use trade restriction to represent trade openness, it is easy to get a reverse result in developing countries. Lee et al. (004) also find that openness has a small, positive, but not particularly robust effect on growth. They have to rely, however, on the nontestable assumption that the structural shocks in the system of simultaneous equations are uncorrelated. This causality criticism is echoed by Billmeier and Nannicini (009) and they find that the result is uncertain if we use trade restriction to measure openness. So far, the relationship between trade openness and growth is a highly debated topic in the growth and development literature, at least from the perspective of trade restriction. However, if we use trade volume to measure openness, all empirical studies support the positive relationship, such as Frankel and Romer (1999), Irwin and Terviö (00), Yanikkaya (003), Alcala and Ciccone (004), Noguer and Siscart (005) and Chang et al. (009). In theoretical literatures, most of them focus on trade restriction and have a controversial result. For example, in R&D-based endogenous growth models, they find that trade restriction lowers the world economic growth rate but a reverse result under some conditions, such as Romer (1990), Grossman and Helpman (1990), Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991a), Dinopoulosa and Segerstrom (1999), Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (008) and Gustafsson and Segerstrom (010). Similarly, in capital-accumulating endogenous growth models, Naito (006b) find that the relationship between tariff and growth is correlated with the factor intensity of production technology in a small-open economy. Lee (011) also finds that this relationship depends on the absolute advantage in the

production of investment goods in a two-country endogenous growth model. Most empirical studies use the ratio of exports plus imports to GDP to measure trade volume. However, there are few papers to discuss the relationship between trade volume and economic growth in theoretical literatures. For example, Osang and Pereira (1997) introduce a composite consumption good, as in Bovenberg (1989), into a human capital accumulating growth model to analyze this issue. They find that the relationship is decided by the agent s attitude toward saving. Moreover, Doi et al. (007) also find that the relationship is related to factor intensity in a human capital accumulating endogenous growth model with psychic cost and externality. These results are inconsistent with the empirical studies. This is just the main motivation of our paper. Our paper uses trade volume to represent the trade openness to examine the relationship between openness and economic growth. We introduce production externality which includes international knowledge spillover into a two-country capital-accumulation endogenous growth model. The international knowledge spillover is verified by Coe and Helpman (1995) and this set-up is also cited by Ghosh and Mourmouras (00) and Lee (011) to solve the knife-edge problem in a two-country endogenous growth model. In this model, there are two countries (Home and Foreign) and two goods in each country: a pure consumption good and a pure investment good. The two goods are respectively produced by two sectors with capital as the only private input. The capital may be thought of as a composite of various types of physical and human capital as outlined in Rebelo (1991). We find that trade volume are positively related to long-run economic growth rate when a variation from the production coefficients in both countries. This result is consistent with empirical studies. The intuition can be explained by a higher Home s productivity for the investment goods. The higher Home s productivity for the investment goods means that Home has more comparative advantage in the investment goods, and hence exports more investment goods and imports more consumption goods. It follows a higher volume of trade. On the other hand, a higher this productivity also furthers marginal product of capital and the corresponding economic growth rate. Therefore, trade volume and economic growth rate

3 are positive correlated. The structure of the paper is as follows. Section sets up the basic model. Section 3 analyzes the long-run equilibrium. In Section 4 we examine the relationship between trade volume and growth. Finally, some concluding remarks are made in Section 5.. The Model There are two countries (Home and Foreign) and two goods in each country: consumption good and a pure private investment good. a pure The two goods are respectively produced by two sectors with capital as the only private input. The capital may be thought of as a composite of various types of physical and human capital as outlined in Rebelo (1991). International knowledge spillovers are introduced in this economy, which furthers each country s productivity. The markets are competitive. Firms produce goods and make rental payments for capital input and distribute their profits to the households that own capital and firms. The households use the income to purchase the two goods. We also assume that the numbers of the households and firms are normalized to one, and thus each variable defined below expresses its aggregated value as well. Following tradition of Oniki and Uzawa, we assume that while the two goods are tradable, capital stock is not internationally mobile..1. Firms in the two countries There are two sectors to produce each good with capital, K i, as the only private input in each country. There is a positive production externality in each production technology, such as the setting of Romer (1986). Different from Romer (1986), the production externality also originates from the activities of foreign country through international trade. That is, we assume that the new knowledge also instantaneously spills over across different countries. 1 Thus, the externality may be represented by total capital in both countries. For simplicity, abstracting from domestic knowledge spillover, the Home s productive externality is just represented by the Foreign s total capital stock, * K, which is in line with 1 Although there is a lot of international technology diffusion whose marginal cost of use is not zero, we only focus on the public-good type for simplicity. The required proportion for this kind of international knowledge spillover may be arbitrarily small, and then this set-up is quite reasonable.

4 Lee (010). Thus, the production function of good i in the Home country is: 1 * i i i, Y A K K i1,, (1) * where i1 (resp. ) corresponds to the consumption (resp. investment) good, K is the * * Foreign s total capital which stands for the productive externality, and K K in the equilibrium. Parameter A i is the productivity coefficient in sector i, and measures the productivity of international knowledge spillover which is identical between the two sectors. The full employment conditions are: K K 1 K, () where K is the total capital stock. Let p be the international price of consumption good in terms of the investment good. Given p and the rental rate of capital, r, if the Home country produces both goods simultaneously, then the first-order conditions for the representative competitive firm in each sector are respectively: Y (1 ), 1 p r (3a) K1 Y (1 ), r (3b) K where r is also the interest rate if we assume that there is no depreciation of capital. Suppose Foreign has a similar production structure. Thus, the production function of good i in the Foreign country is: * * *1 i i i, Y A K K i1,, (4) Similarly the first-order conditions for the Foreign s representative firm are: 1 1 Y (1 ) p r, (5a) K Y (1 ) r. (5b) K. Households in the two countries

5 Home s representative household earns factor income with k(0) units of capital endowed initially and profit from the two firms. The household s budget constraint is thus: rk pc I, (6) where 1 [py 1 rk 1 ]+(Y rk ) is the profit from the two firms, C is consumption, and I is investment. The law of motion for capital accumulation is: K I. (7) For simplicity, no depreciation in capital is assumed. Given r, p, and K(0), the representative agent s problem is to choose c, I, and k to maximize the following discounted lifetime utility: t U u( C) e dt, (8) 0 subject to (6) and (7). Parameter >0 is the rate of time preference. For simplicity, following Ventura (1997), we assume the felicity has logarithmic form: u( C) ln C. To solve the household s optimization problem, we set up the current-value Hamiltonian: H ln C [ rk pc], where is the co-state variable of capital. The necessary conditions for optimality are then: 1 C p, (9a) r, (9b) with the transversality conditions limt ke t 0. While condition (9a) represents marginal benefit is equal to marginal cost for consumption condition, (9b) presents Euler equations for capital. The behavior of Foreign s household is the same. Thus, the first-order condition for the household is parallel to (9a) and (9b) with asterisked variables. Moreover, for simplicity, we assume the rate of time preferences between these two countries are the same as follows.

6 =*. Thus, the necessary conditions for the Foreign s household are: 1 * C * p, (10a) * * * r *, (10b) with the transversality conditions * * t Ke t lim 0. 3. Two-country World Market Equilibrium For free trade, the world commodity market-clearing condition for the consumption goods is: C C Y Y (11) 1 1. Once (11) is satisfied, the world market for the investment goods is automatically cleared. We are now ready to analyze the equilibrium. The equilibrium is a path {Y 1, Y, Y 1 *, Y *, C, C*, K, K*, K 1, K, K 1 *, K *, I, I*, r, r*, p, λ, λ*} and is determined by (1)-(6), (9)-(11). 3.1. Transformation of the economic system In order to analyze the equilibrium, it is necessary to transform the equilibrium conditions with perpetual growth into a system with stationary variables. Denote zk*/k, xpc/k, x*pc*/k*, vk 1 /K, and v*k 1 */K*. In what follows we briefly explain the transformation. First, multiplying (11) by p/k and utilizing (3a)-(5b), the world market-clearing condition may be rewritten as: z 1 x x* z A v A v* z. 1 v (1 v*) z Next, (3a)-(3b) and (5a)-(5b) can be solved to yield the relationship between v and v*. (1) * v A1A v * 1v A A 1 v * 1. This implies that the Home s fraction of capital allocated to the consumption sector and the Foreign s fraction are positively related. We find that v>v* when Home has a (13)

7 comparative advantage in the pure consumption good A 1 /A >A 1 */A * and v<v* when Home has a comparative advantage in the pure investment good A 1 /A <A 1 */A *. Differentiating (9a) and using (3b) and (9b) lead to the following growth rate of consumption. C z p (1 ) A. C 1 v p Based on (6) and using (3a)-(3b), we get the growth rate of capital: K A K z x. 1 v The growth rate of x can be derived by (14a) and (14b) as follows.. x p C K xa z x p C K 1 v Moreover, the counterpart in the foreign country is: x * 1 x* A. x * (1 v*) z Finally, with the help of (14b), the growth rate of z is: (14a) (14b) (15) (16) z K * K 1 z A A x x*. z K * K (1 v*) z 1v The dynamics of the system can therefore be described by (1)-(13) and (15)-(17), which determine the equilibrium paths of five variables: x, x*, z, v, and v*. Other variables are solved by other equations. (17) 3.. Long-Run Equilibrium We now analyze the equilibrium in a steady state. A steady state is a perfect foresight equilibrium with a BGP under which x, x*, z, v, and v* are constant. Denote z, x, x*, v, and v * as the values in a BGP. Based on (15) and (16), we then obtain: xa z, 1 v (18a)

8 1 x* A. (1 v*) z (18b) Utilizing (18a) and (18b), Equation (17) implies that the rates of economic growth between these two countries are identical. z A 1 (1 ) A (1 ). 1 v (1 v*) z (19) This equation indicates x x*. Moreover, this equation is also the main difference from the existing literature. After v and v * are determined, the growth rates between countries may be different. both Home s and Foreign s growth rates. Thanks to international knowledge spillover, z appears in Now, the two growth rates may converge to be identical through the adjustment of z - that is, (19) can determine the value of z. The past literature, such as Bond, Trask and Wang (003) and Doi, Nishimura and Shimomura (007), always assume no international difference in production technology and preference, such that this equation is met automatically. Substituting (18a), (18b) and (19) into (1), the world market-clearing condition can be rewritten by: A z (1 z) 1v [ v z( v * )] Therefore, the three endogenous variables, z, v,and v *, are determined by (13), (19), and (0). Now we assess the existence of z, v,and v *, Based on (13), we find that v* v *( v). (0) Moreover, given v,, (19) can determine a unique z z v It is easy to find A 1 * (1 v) ( ) [ ] A. (1 v*) that the left-hand side (LHS) of (0) is increasing in v and LHS as v 1 and LHS A z as v 0. Consequently, v can be determined uniquely by (0) 0 as depicted in Figure 1. [Insert Figure 1 here] This figure indicates there is an unique solution for v. Given v, (13) and (19) can determined z and v *. In sum, we get the following proposition.

9 Proposition 1 Suppose the only difference between Home and Foreign is the productivity coefficient in the firms technology. The long-run equilibrium is uniquely determined with incomplete specialization in each country. 4. Trade Volume and Growth This section examines the long-run relationship between trade volume and economic growth rate. We follow the empirical literatures to define the trade volume as the ratio of exports plus imports to GDP. Now we examine the trade volume. Substituting (3a) and (3b) into (6), we find that Home s resource constraint becomes: p( C Y ) Y I 1 If Home imports consumption goods and export investment goods, then this equation implies that Home s import volume equals export volume. With the help of (11), Home s total trade volume is p( C Y ) Y I p( C Y ) p[( C Y ) ( C Y )]. * * 1 1 1 1 Thus, utilizing (3a)-(3b), (5a)-(5b) and (19), the ratio of exports plus imports to GDP is: ( ) ( * ). py1 Y A z A z p( C Y1) Y I 1v 1v T v z v Moreover, the long-run economic growth rate can be derived by (14a) as follows. (1) z g (1 ) A. 1 v For simplicity, we assume A 1 /A =A 1 */A * at the beginning. () Note that under * * A 1 /A =A 1 */A *, (13) induces v v*, and (19) and (0) indicates C Y and C Y 1 1 which means this economy is like an autarkic economy. Under A 1 /A =A 1 */A *, (19) and (0) implies both values of the two square brackets in (1) are zero and hence this ratio is also equal to zero. In addition, with (19) and (0), the economic growth rate in () can be rewritten as

10 1 g 1. v Now we examine the relationship between T and g. These two endogenous variables are unchanged as long as the exogenous variables are constant. Thus, we need to assume some variations of the exogenous variables to investigate the relationship between these two endogenous variables. (3) In this section, we assume the variation in exogenous variables only originates from the production coefficients of the two countries, such as A 1, A, A 1 *, and A *. Without loss of generality, we change the value of A and hold the other parameter values constant. In what follows, we briefly show the derivation. First, we examine the effect of A on T. We assume A increases a little bite such that A 1 /A <A 1 */A *. good. Equation (11) also implies: It means that Home has comparative advantage in the pure investment 1v 1 v ( v ) z ( v * ) 0. A z A z The values of the two brackets are the same except v and v *. Under A 1 /A <A 1 */A *, (13) also implies v v* and then the value of the first brackets is greater than second brackets. It follows that the value of first brackets is positive and the value of second brackets is negative. In other words, Home imports the pure consumption good and exports the pure investment good. Thus, the ratio of exports plus imports to GDP in (1) becomes greater than zero. The effect of A on T is positive, i.e. dt/da >0. Second, we examine the effect of A on g. Under A 1 /A =A 1 */A *, (19) and (0) imply ( A A ) (1 v) ( v ). * 1/ This expression also indicates dv (1 v)( v ) 0. da A [ ( v ) (1 v)] Thus, it is easy to find that the effect of A on g is positive by (3) as follows. dg da dv da (1 )( v ) 0. As a result, the relationship between trade volume and economic growth rate is

11 positive as follows. dt dg dt / da dg / da 0. That is, if we only vary one of the values of A 1, A, A 1 *, and A *, we find that there is a positive relationship between trade volume and economic growth rate under A 1 /A =A 1 */A * or small enough difference of these two values of the relative productivities. get the following proposition. In sum, we Proposition Assume the only variation in the economy is from the production coefficients in both countries and the difference of relative productivities is small enough. Trade volume and economic growth rate are positive correlated. The intuition can be explained as follows. A higher A means that Home has more comparative advantage in the investment good, and hence exports more investment goods and imports more consumption goods. It follows a higher volume of trade. On the other hand, a higher A also furthers marginal product of capital and so does the economic growth rate. Therefore, trade volume and economic growth rate are positive correlated in this case. 5. Concluding Remarks We have presented a basic two-country endogenous growth model, which is regarded as an integration of a two-country economy and endogenous growth. We find that trade volume are positively related to economic growth rate when a variation from the production coefficients in both countries. This result is consistent with empirical studies. Since the model is a basic one, there are many directions to extend this model to discuss trade and growth issues. One direction is to extend this model to include two factors, such as physical capital and labor or physical capital and human capital. This may re-examine the hypothesis of the Heckscher-Ohlin model. Moreover, international knowledge is a public good in this model, but in the real world most of these are a private good. If the firms absorbing international knowledge should pay the cost, then we can

extend this model to a R&D structure such as Romer (1990). 1

13 Reference Alcala, F. and A. Ciccone, 004, Trade and Productivity, Quarterly Journal of Economics 119, 613 46. Baldwin, Richard E. and Frédéric Robert-Nicoud, 008. Trade and Growth with Heterogeneous Firms, Journal of International Economics 74, 1 34. Billmeier, A. and T. Nannicini, 009. Trade openness and growth: Pursuing empirical glasnost, IMF Staff Papers 56, 447-475. Bond, E. W., K. Trask and P. Wang. 003. Factor accumulation and trade: dynamic comparative advantage with endogenous physical and human capital, International Economic Review 44, 1041-1060. Borensztein, E., de Gregorio J. and Lee. J. 1998. How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth? Journal of International Economics, 45, pp. 115-35. Bovenberg, L., 1989. The Effects of Capital Income Taxation on International Competitiveness and Trade Flows, American Economic Review 79, 1045 64. Chang, Roberto, Linda Kaltani and Norman V. Loayza, 009. Openness can be good for growth: The role of policy complementarities. Journal of Development Economics 90, 33 49. DeJong, D.N., and M. Ripoll, 006, Tariffs and Growth: An Empirical Exploration of Contingent Relationships, Review of Economics and Statistics 88, 65 40. Dinopoulos, E. and P. Segerstrom, 1999. The dynamic effects of contingent tariffs. Journal of International Economics 47, 191. Doi, J., K. Nishimura and K. Shimomura. 007. A two-country dynamic model of international trade and endogenous growth: Multiple balanced growth paths and stability, Journal of Mathematical Economics 43, 390-419. Farmer, Roger E.A. and A. Lahiri. 005. A two-country model of endogenous growth, Review of Economic Dynamics 8, 68-88. Frankel, J.A., and D. Romer, 1999, Does Trade Cause Growth? American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 3, pp. 379 99. Ghosh, S. and I. A. Mourmouras, 00. On public investment, long-run growth, and the

14 real exchange rate, Oxford Economic Papers 54, 7-90. Coe, D.T., and E. Helpman. 1995. International R&D spillovers, European Economic Review 39: 859-887. Grossman, G. M. and E. Helpman 1990, Comparative advantage and long-run growth, American Economic Review, 80, 796-815. Gustafsson, Peter and Paul Segerstrom, 010. Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth. Review of International Economics 18, 07 8. Irwin, D.A. and Marko Tervio. 00 Does Trade Raise Income? Evidence from the Twentieth Century. Journal of International Economics 58, 1 18. Lee, H.Y., L.A. Ricci, and R. Rigobon, 004, Once Again, Is Openness Good for Growth? Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 75, No., pp. 451 7. Lee, Shun-Fa, 011, Tariff, growth, and welfare, Review of International Economics, 19, 60 76. Lucas, R., 1988. On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics, 3 4. Naito, T., 006a. Tariff and tax reform: dynamic implications. Journal of International Economics 68, 504-517. Naito, T., 006b. Growth, revenue, and welfare effects of tariff and tax reform: win-win-win strategies, Journal of Public Economics 90, 163-180. Nishimura, K., Venditti, A., 00. Intersectoral externalities and indeterminacy. Journal of Economic Theory 105, 140 157. Noguer, Marta and Marc Siscart, 005. Trade Raises Income: A Precise and Robust Result. Journal of International Economics 65, 447-460 Osang, Thomas and Alfredo Pereira, 1997. Savings, Volume of Trade, and Growth. Review of International Economics 5, 310 33. Rivera-Batiz, L. A. and P. M. Romer, 1991a, International trade with endogenous technological change, European Economic Review, 35, 971-1004. Rivera-Batiz, L.A. and P.M. Romer, 1991b. Economic integration and endogenous growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 531 555. Rodriguez, F. and Rodrik, D. 001, Trade Policy and Economic Growth: a Skeptic's Guide

15 to the Cross-National Evidence, Macroeconomic Annual 000. 61-34, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press for NBER. Romer, Paul M. 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth, Journal of Political Economy 94, 100-1037. Romer, P., 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98, 71 10. Sen, Partha, 001. Tariffs and welfare in an imperfectly competitive overlapping-generations model. Review of Development Economics 5, 7-38. Ventura, J. 1997. Growth and interdependence, Quarterly Journal of Economics 11, 57-84 Winters, L. A. 004, Trade Liberalization and Economic Performance: an Overview, Economic Journal, 114, F4-F1. Yanikkaya, H., 003. Trade openness and economic growth: a cross-country empirical investigation, Journal of Development Economics 7, 57-89.

16 Figure 1: long-run equilibrium LH S Az 0 v 1 v