Perverse Incentives in Hedge Fund Fees. A/Prof Paul Lajbcygier David Ghijben

Similar documents
CAN AGENCY COSTS OF DEBT BE REDUCED WITHOUT EXPLICIT PROTECTIVE COVENANTS? THE CASE OF RESTRICTION ON THE SALE AND LEASE-BACK ARRANGEMENT

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

Dividend Policy and Investment Decisions of Korean Banks

Next Generation Fund of Funds Optimization

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

EQUITY RESEARCH AND PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT

CHAPTER 12: MARKET EFFICIENCY AND BEHAVIORAL FINANCE

Active versus passive the debate is over

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies

** Department of Accounting and Finance Faculty of Business and Economics PO Box 11E Monash University Victoria 3800 Australia

Bank Characteristics and Payout Policy

Discussion of Value Investing: The Use of Historical Financial Statement Information to Separate Winners from Losers

Analyst Disagreement and Aggregate Volatility Risk

Management Science Letters

How Does Earnings Management Affect Innovation Strategies of Firms?

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks.

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 2 Summer 1997 AN ANALYSIS OF VALUE LINE S ABILITY TO FORECAST LONG-RUN RETURNS

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Seeking ALPHA - (C) 2007 Kingdom Venture Partners by Sherman Muller, MBA

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

When Does Trend Following Kick In?

Confidence Bands for Investment Decisions

Top 5 Compensation Cost, Holdings & Future Stock Returns. By Stephen F. O Byrne and S. David Young

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

How to select outperforming Alternative UCITS funds?

BARUCH COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS & FINANCE Professor Chris Droussiotis LECTURE 6. Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT): The Keynesian Animal Spirits

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate?

Lecture 1 Introduction

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal*

TRADING VOLUME REACTIONS AND THE ADOPTION OF INTERNATIONAL ACCOUNTING STANDARD (IAS 1): PRESENTATION OF FINANCIAL STATEMENTS IN INDONESIA

Equity Sell Disciplines across the Style Box

Principles of Finance

Bank Rescues and Bailout Expectations: The Erosion of Market Discipline During the Financial Crisis

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

Does the Application of Smart Beta Strategies Enhance Portfolio Performance? Muhammad Wajid Raza Dawood Ashraf

Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic. Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry

Managed Futures as a Crisis Risk Offset Strategy

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

Dividend Policy Responses to Deregulation in the Electric Utility Industry

Mutual Funds through the Lens of Active Share

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Analysis of Non Financial Firms Listed in Karachi Stock Exchange in Pakistan

Performance, Persistence, and Pay: A New Perspective on CTAs

The debate on NBIM and performance measurement, or the factor wars of 2015

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Historical Performance and characteristic of Mutual Fund

Capital Asset Pricing Model - CAPM

EC248-Financial Innovations and Monetary Policy Assignment. Andrew Townsend

Does Disposition Drive Momentum?

Volume 29, Issue 3. A new look at the trickle-down effect in the united states economy

Investor Reaction to the Stock Gifts of Controlling Shareholders

Classification Shifting in the Income-Decreasing Discretionary Accrual Firms

Risk Hedging Frameworks: Governance Concerns and Equity Derivative Strategies

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Discussion of The Active vs. Passive Asset Management Debate by T. Roncalli

Complete Dividend Signal

Development Economics Lecture Notes 4

Management Science Letters

Archana Khetan 05/09/ MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix

Improving Returns-Based Style Analysis

EMPIRICAL STUDY ON STOCK'S CAPITAL RETURNS DISTRIBUTION AND FUTURE PERFORMANCE

Is Residual Income Really Uninformative About Stock Returns?

THE BEHAVIOUR OF GOVERNMENT OF CANADA REAL RETURN BOND RETURNS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Dynamics of Wealth and Consumption: New and Improved Measures for U.S. States

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

3 The leverage cycle in Luxembourg s banking sector 1

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Bank Capital, Profitability and Interest Rate Spreads MUJTABA ZIA * This draft version: March 01, 2017

Answer FOUR questions out of the following FIVE. Each question carries 25 Marks.

Applied Macro Finance

Appendix 6-B THE FIFO/LIFO CHOICE: EMPIRICAL STUDIES

Dynamic Capital Structure Choice

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Monetary Economics Portfolios Risk and Returns Diversification and Risk Factors Gerald P. Dwyer Fall 2015

ECMC49S Midterm. Instructor: Travis NG Date: Feb 27, 2007 Duration: From 3:05pm to 5:00pm Total Marks: 100

Ocean Hedge Fund. James Leech Matt Murphy Robbie Silvis

EC989 Behavioural Economics. Sketch solutions for Class 2

A Comparison of the Financing Benefit and Incentives of Non-traditional Options

OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS- ASSET ALLOCATIONS. BKM Ch 7

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

The Information Content of Earnings Announcements in Regulated and Deregulated Markets: The Case of the Airline Industry

The Financial Transactions Tax Versus the Financial Activities Tax

Wholesale funding runs

Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended Analysis

Risk Taking and Performance of Bond Mutual Funds

The Separate Valuation Relevance of Earnings, Book Value and their Components in Profit and Loss Making Firms: UK Evidence

Stock Market Expected Returns Page 2. Stock Market Returns Page 3. Investor Returns Page 13. Advisor Returns Page 15

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Transcription:

Perverse Incentives in Hedge Fund Fees A/Prof Paul Lajbcygier David Ghijben 1

Hedge Fund Fees: Payment for skill Fees for Hedge Fund Managers: 2% of notional AUM and 20% of profits above a high water mark. Compare this with other fund managers: mutual funds earn ~1%. Why the HUGE difference? Alternative managers are the Über fund managers. In principle, they SHOULD have great skill! This skill must be manifest in the manager s ability to generate: large, persistent returns for investors. Hence, the 20% incentive fee rewards such skill and aligns manager and investor interests. 2

But...No Skill? Due to the 20% incentive fee, absolute returns (above the high water mark) should be the key performance characteristic responsible for fund success and growth. The literature suggests, that performance is not persistent, or significant, over the long term(agarwal and Narayan 2000) (Harri and Brorsen 2004). It appears that the incentives embedded in the performance contract to ensure consistent, high, absolute performance do not work. Why not? It appears it is VERY hard to consistently beat the markets. 3

Are hedge fund fees deserved due to manager skill? Warren Buffet has commented that : hedge funds are distinguished not by [their manager s] abilities but by their ability to charge high fees. http://jvbruni.com/berkshire.htm Buffet reserves some of his most severe criticism for hedge fund management fees, saying It s a lopsided system whereby 2% of your principal is paid each year to the manager even if he accomplishes nothing or, for that matter, loses you a bundle. http://www.berkshirehathaway.com/letters/2006ltr.pdf. 4

But.. Hedge funds can generate huge revenues! (Source Graig W. French, JoIM conference) 5

So why the HUGE revenue? Despite theory which says that capacity constraints should limit fund growth... there are funds which desire & obtain HUGE AUM. So, why do funds desire AUM given the erosion of trading profits? Huge AUM have a multiplier effect on fees. The huge revenues occur because HUGE funds perform well occasionally and reap the 20% incentive fee. When not performing well... they also make huge revenue from management fees too. 6

Which one is correct? Max Monotonically Increasing REVENUE TO MANAGER REVENUE TO MANAGER Revenue to Manager Return to Investor AUM AUM 7

The conclusions Lucrative fees are charged by managed futures funds. Ideally, these fees should align the interests of managers and investors. However, the fee structure fails in this regard; we show that by growing their assets under management, managers increase their overall revenue via their management fees but, because of capacity constraints decrease their returns. Thus, the fee structure motivates perverse behavior: it fails to properly exploit manager skill for the benefit of investors. We suggest increasing contracting flexibility to resolve this conflict of interest. 8

Implications... It appears that large AUM managers circumvent the hedge fund compensation structure: perhaps, it is easier to exploit management fees and charge an investor economic rent than it is to apply management skill consistently and exploit the huge incentive fees and thus provide the investor with large, consistent returns. So what? Doesn t this only effect high net worth individuals. No, the perverse incentives lead to managers increasing risk to optimize the value of the option on the investor s capital. Systemic risk increased and that became everyone s problem! 9

Lucrative Fees in 2008, the year of the GFC! Brother can you spare a billion? Bad Average Performance 2008 worst annual performance on record. 2008 record number of hedge funds liquidated. High Payouts for a few However, for top 35 $11.6 bn, 2008 3 rd best year. Top four made more than $1bn each. Hedge funds have long been shielded from executive compensation debates. 10

The role of hedge funds in the GFC Krugman (2009) argues that it is the run on the shadow banking system, precipitated by the Lehman Brothers collapse in September 2008 that caused the crisis. We submit that the root cause of the crisis was not the shadow banking system per se, but rather the flawed incentive system under which it operated and which drove the protagonists to behave in such a way that led directly to the financial crisis, the worst since the great depression. 11

Why are perverse hedge fund incentives important? Paul Krugman Argues that Hedge Fund Perverse Incentives Caused the GFC Perverse incentives led to increased systemic risk. A hand full of people being paid enormous sums for the illusion of success drove this whole thing. If you can create the appearance of success for 2-3 years you can become immensely wealthy. Capital Decimation Partners. 12

Hypotheses H 1 : Total revenue increases with fund size, albeit at a decreasing rate H 2 : Total revenue increases with fund age, albeit at a decreasing rate H 3 : The rate of increase in incentive fees per dollar invested is lower for larger funds compared with smaller funds H 4 : Proportion of total revenue due to management fees increases with fund size 13

Data Barclays managed futures/cta data base. CTA (i.e. Managed future) systematic diversified style. Yearly individual fund fees are calculated for the most recent five-year window, from 1 January 2000 to 1 January 2005. Creating a common five-year window controls for time-varying exogenous factors that may affect strategic rate of return. Furthermore, since the majority of funds are new, most funds exist in this latest time period. Revenues are calculated for 12 month blocks of a funds returns. 14

AUM vs Quintile AUM Q5 AUM suggests capacity constraints will be important for Q5 funds only. Discrepancy in AUM motivates latter comparison of Q1-4 vs Q5 15

Hypothesis 1 Results Revenue ($) 16

Comment on H1 Results At first instance it may seem that these findings are to be expected, given that both management fees and incentive fees are calculated as functions of AUM. That is, AUM magnifies both fees. However, the relevant literature often posits that managers have a strong incentive to resist growth in fear of future performance reduction. Despite this future performance only affects incentive fees, not necessarily the total revenue of the fund. Ultimately all that a manager cares about is maximising her total revenue. 17

Comparison of Aggregate Incentive & Management Fees Results 18

Test of H3 H 3 : The rate of increase in incentive fees per dollar invested is lower for larger funds compared with smaller funds Incentive fee i = α + β ave_aum i + ε i 19

Hypothesis 3 Results TABLE 4 Piecewise Regression (Dollar Incentive fee), Upper Quintile Funds Partitioned Panel A: Proxy for establishment, average assets under management for a fund in a year (ave_aum) 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Aggregate Q1-Q4 Q5 Q1-Q4 Q5 Q1-Q4 Q5 Q1-Q4 Q5 Q1-Q4 Q5 Q1-Q4 Q5 intercept 62.799 (1.044) 1953.775* (1.940) 10.194 (0.134) -1533.928 (-1.147) -26.158 (-0.129) -449.724 (-0.125) 201.948 (1.297) -2168.872 (-0.560) 235.287 (1.193) 2474.514 (0.766) 97.053 (1.471) 4726.482*** (3.550) ave_aum 0.0323*** (7.852) 0.013** (2.309) 0.045*** (10.204) 0.0533*** (8.441) 0.078*** (7.694) 0.061*** (5.150) 0.037 (7.500) 0.045 (5.972) 0.013*** (4.030) 0.005 (1.426) 0.040*** (12.295) 0.015*** (5.444) t-stat -3.542*** - -1.442* - -2.224** -9.064*** no. of obs 202 50 198 49 210 53 211 52 169 42 989 247 R 2 (%) 23.56 10.00 34.70 60.25 22.16 34.20 21.21 41.64 8.86 48.39 17.15 10.79 Table 4, Panel A reports piecewise regression results of Eq (3) where the dependant variable is estimated dollar incentive fees calculated over a year. The independent variable is average assets under management for that year. Funds are classified into quintiles on the basis of ascending ave_aum of the fund. The t-stats in parentheses test whether Ho:β i = 0 versus H1β i 0. The t-statistic between Q1-4 funds and Q5 funds is a 1-sided test, testing Ho:β Q5 β Q1-4 Q5 versus H1:β Q5 < β Q1-4. *,**,*** indicate rejection of Ho at the 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels, respectively. 20

Comment of H3 Results In aggregate, each coefficient remains positive and statistically significantly different to zero, meaning that actual dollar incentive fees continue to increase with fund size, albeit at a decreased rate. This is consistent with a capacity argument... but the capital per dollar invested is used less effectively in larger funds, due to reduced incentive fees. This fact motivates fee reform: Managers are permitted to act in their own self interest before their investors! 21

H 4 : Proportion of total revenue due to management fees increases with fund size 1.2 1 Proportion of Total Revenue 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 'Small' Funds 'Large' Funds 28% of annual revenue in small funds is from management fees. 43% of annual revenue in large funds is from management fees. 22

Fee Reform: Remove Management Fees? If zero management fees for large funds became the norm, the only fee clients would pay is when they receive a cumulative return above the high water mark. Interestingly, this is reminiscent of Jones original hedge fund. Such a fee structure reduces the incentive to embrace growth in assets under management as a value generator for managers but does not entirely eliminate it, as coefficients are still positive in upper quintile funds (Table 4A). 23

Fee Reform: Change Incentive Fees? How should the trading profits be divided between manager and investor? Ultimately the answer to this question must hinge on an ethical consideration of what amount of profits are deserved (Arnold, 1987) by an entrepreneurial fund manager. Here we answer this question by focusing on how the fund manager can best serve the investor in terms of efficiency per dollar invested from the perspective of the investor (not in total revenue generated for the manager). 24

Incentive fee per $ invested (Beta) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Quintiles of Funds Ascending in Size The coefficient attached to ave_aum is largest for Q3 funds and statistically different to zero at the 5% level. This suggests the relation between ave_aum and incentive fees is steepest for Q3 funds. 25

Comments Prima facie the result suggests that money invested with a quintile 3 fund is utilised most efficiently and should demand the highest share of the profits, relatively speaking. In other words, clients may be willing to enter contracts that offer these managers more of the realised profits as an incentive to perform well when capacity constraints are not prohibitive. In contrast, for young/small managers, clients may be willing to offer a lower proportion of realised profits for want of a track record. Similarly, a reasonable argument for a client of an old/large fund is that, since these funds tend to set relatively lower variance strategies to ensure survival (Brown et al., 2001), their incentive fees should be more conservative than the 20% industry benchmark. 26

Conclusion These results have several important implications for future contracting arrangements between investor and manager within the managed futures industry. Principally, they identify different efficiencies in use of capital amongst managed futures. Institutional fund allocators, fund-of-fund managers, and high net worth individuals can utilize this work to further understand the issues that should rationally underpin fee structure negotiations within this industry. 27

You can t fool all the people all the time! The "Pyramid Economy on the Daily Show. $3.4bn in Earnings in April-June 2009. Pay out of $20bn in bonuses. $700,000 per employee. >14 times average household income. AFTER Government bailouts in 2007-2008. 28