Modelling Economic Variables

Similar documents
Economics 307: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory A Brief Mathematical Primer

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

Lecture notes: 101/105 (revised 9/27/00) Lecture 3: national Income: Production, Distribution and Allocation (chapter 3)

A PRODUCER OPTIMUM. Lecture 7 Producer Behavior

9/10/2017. National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes (in the long-run) Introduction. The Neoclassical model

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH DERIVING THE AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES MODEL

Exercise 1 Output Determination, Aggregate Demand and Fiscal Policy

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

ANSWER: We can find consumption and saving by solving:

Percentage Change and Elasticity

Math 1314 Week 6 Session Notes

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Outline for ECON 701's Second Midterm (Spring 2005)

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Chapter 11 Online Appendix:

KOÇ UNIVERSITY ECON 202 Macroeconomics Fall Problem Set VI C = (Y T) I = 380 G = 400 T = 0.20Y Y = C + I + G.

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

Foundations of Economics for International Business Supplementary Exercises 2

Assignment 1: Hand in only Answer. Last Name. First Name. Chapter

Exercise 2 Short Run Output and Interest Rate Determination in an IS-LM Model

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2

The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

Learning Objectives. 1. Describe how the government budget surplus is related to national income.

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Chapter 3. National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

ECON Chapter 4: Firm Behavior

Macroeconomics - Licence 1 Economie Gestion

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

PhD Qualifier Examination

Quantitative Techniques (Finance) 203. Derivatives for Functions with Multiple Variables

Two Equivalent Conditions

Example 11: A country s gross domestic product (in millions of dollars) is modeled by the function

ECON Micro Foundations

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Winter 2009 Solutions to Problem Set 2.

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

Intermediate Macroeconomics-ECO 3203

Lecture 3: National Income: Where it comes from and where it goes

AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT. Chapter 20

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

ECON Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory

WEALTH, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION and LIVING STANDARDS

Intro to Economic analysis

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

If a model were to predict that prices and money are inversely related, that prediction would be evidence against that model.

Assignment 5 Advanced Microeconomics

Introduction. Countries engage in international trade for two basic reasons:

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, UNIVERSITY OF VICTORIA

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

Econ 522: Intermediate Macroeconomics, Spring 2018 Chapter 3 Practice Problem Set - Solutions

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

OVERVIEW. 1. This chapter presents a graphical approach to the determination of income. Two different graphical approaches are provided.

9. CHAPTER: Aggregate Demand I

Solution Problem Set 2

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Introductory Mathematics for Economics MSc s: Course Outline. Huw David Dixon. Cardiff Business School. September 2008.

Assignment 1 Solutions. October 6, 2017

Equalities. Equalities

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output. The Core of Macroeconomic Theory. Aggregate Output and Aggregate Income (Y)

Solutions to Homework 3

The Theory of the Firm

Exam 2 Review. 2. If Y = AK 0.5 L 0.5 and A, K, and L are all 100, the marginal product of capital is: A) 50. B) 100. C) 200. D) 1000.

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Econ 522: Intermediate Macroeconomics, Fall 2017 Chapter 3 Classical Model Practice Problems

Chapter 4 Inflation and Interest Rates in the Consumption-Savings Model

Modules 6 and 7: Markets, Prices, Supply, and Demand practice problems. Practice problems and illustrative test questions for the final exam

Linear Modeling Business 5 Supply and Demand

SYLLABUS AND SAMPLE QUESTIONS FOR MSQE (Program Code: MQEK and MQED) Syllabus for PEA (Mathematics), 2013

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

ECON 2123 Problem Set 2

EC 205 Macroeconomics I Fall Problem Session 2 Solutions. Q1. Use the neoclassical theory of distribution to predict the impact on the real wage

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Midterm 2 - Economics 101 (Fall 2009) You will have 45 minutes to complete this exam. There are 5 pages and 63 points. Version A.

You will be given five minutes at the end of the examination to complete the front of any answer books used. May/June 2016 EC /6 A 001

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

BEFORE YOU BEGIN Looking at the Chapter

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

Class 2: The determinants of National Income. Long Run

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Macroeconomics. Based on the textbook by Karlin and Soskice: Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial System

Advanced Macroeconomics 8. Growth Accounting

ECO 2013: Macroeconomics Valencia Community College

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Sticky Wages and Prices: Aggregate Expenditure and the Multiplier. 5Topic

Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics. Chapter 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

PART II CLASSICAL THEORY. Chapter 3: National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes 1/64

Transcription:

ucsc supplementary notes ams/econ 11a Modelling Economic Variables c 2010 Yonatan Katznelson 1. Mathematical models The two central topics of AMS/Econ 11A are differential calculus on the one hand, and its applications to business and economics on the other. Economists use mathematics to model the behavior of a wide variety of economic variables and their interactions. These models can be very simple, describing nothing more than a linear or quadratic relationship between two variables, and they can be complex, involving many variables and intricate functional relationships. Economists use purely mathematical tools like calculus and linear algebra to analyze these models and better understand the hypothetical relationships between the economic variables. Most mathematical models of economic behavior boil down to an equation or, more generally, a system of equations. Broadly speaking, these equations describe three distinct types of relationships. Identities which serve as definitions. For example, the equation π = r c, identifies profit (π) as the difference between revenue (r) and cost (c). This is the definition of profit. Functional equations which describe how one variable depends on others. For example the equation Q = AK α L 1 α describes how a firm s output (Q) depends on capital and labor input (K and L, respectively). Equilibrium equations. These are equations, or systems of equations, that describe structural equilibria in various economic systems. An equilibrium point is literally a point of balance and in economics, equilibrium refers to a state wherein all of the various market forces are in balance and the system as a whole is stable, or unmoving. The best known equilibrium equation in economics is Q s = Q d, i.e., quantity supplied = quantity demanded (where the variable Q will always signify quantity, in some form or another). The solution of this equation is the point of market equilibrium, which is the point where a market stabilizes and determines the price of a good and the quantity of that good that is trading hands. In the sections that follow I will survey some of the basic economic variables that we will encounter in the course, and some of the relations between them. 1

2 2. Price and Quantity The variables p and q (lower case or upper case) will always signify the price and quantity variables. These are perhaps the two most basic variables in economics, and they appear in many of the examples in this course. Price is always measured in some form of currency, e.g., dollars, $1000 s, etc. Quantity can be measured in many ways, e.g., single units, 100s of units, gallons, etc. 2.1 Supply and Demand A demand equation, (or demand function), describes the relationship between the price of a product, p, and the quantity demanded of this product, q. A demand equation is always characterized by the fact that both p and q represent positive quantities, and that p is a decreasing function of q and vice versa. This means that the graph of a demand equation is downward sloping. Example 1. The equation p + 0.05q = 100, is a valid demand equation, as long as both p and q are positive. If we rearrange the equation by moving the q-term to the right hand side we obtain an equivalent equation that has the advantage of expressing p as a function of q: (2.1) p = 100 0.05q. Example 2. A supply equation (or function) describes the relationship between the price of a commodity and the amount that a producer of the commodity is willing to supply. Once again the variables should both be positive, but in this case, the higher the price, the more the producers will want to supply, and so we expect p and q to increase together. For example the function (2.2) p = 100 + q is a valid supply equation. Example 3. Using the demand and supply equations of the previous two examples, we can find the point of market equilibrium by setting the two prices (or the two quantities) equal to each other. That is when the market is in equilibrium, the price will be such that the quantity supplied and the quantity demanded at that price are the same, (2.3) 100 + q = 100 0.05q. or To find the equilibrium quantity, we square both sides of the equation, obtaining 100 + q = (100 0.05q) 2 = 10000 10q + 0.0025q 2, 0.0025q 2 11q + 9900 = 0. This is a quadratic equation which we solve using the quadratic formula giving two possible values for q: q 0 1261.92 and q 1 3138.08. Of these two solutions to the quadratic equation See SN 2 if the quadratic formula seems mysterious.

above, only q 0 is a solution of the original equation, (2.3). Thus the equilibrium quantity is q 0 and the corresponding equilibrium price is p 0 = 100 0.05q 0 36.904. 3. Revenue, Cost and Profit 3.1 Revenue The revenue is the total amount of money earned by a firm in a given unit of time. Revenue will always be denoted by the variable r. The revenue of a firm is given by the quantity of the product that they sell multiplied by the price per unit of that product. In other words r = p q, where p and q are the price and quantity variables described above. Since price is a function of quantity, or vice versa, we will often describe r as a function of q alone (or of p alone). Typically, the price of a product is determined from the demand equation for that product. Example 4. function: We can use the demand function defined in Example 1 to obtain a revenue (3.1) r = p q = (100 0.05q) q = 100q 0.05q 2. The revenue variable is typically measured in the same units as the price variable. 3.2 Cost A firm s total cost is represented by the variable c. Total cost can be split into fixed cost (FC) and variable cost (VC). The fixed cost is the amount of money spent by the firm independently of the quantity produced, even if nothing is produced, due to things like rent. Variable cost is the part of the total cost that depends directly on the quantity produced. Example 5. Suppose that a small firm has fixed monthly costs (rent, utilities, etc.) of $2000 and that its variable costs are $10 per unit, then the firm s total (monthly) cost is given by function (3.2) c = 10q + 2000. 3.3 Profit A firm s profit is the difference between its revenue and its cost. Profit is often denoted by the Greek letter π, (to distinguish it from price), so we have π = r c. Example 6. Suppose that the revenue function in Example 4 represents a firm s monthly revenue in dollars based on monthly sales of q units of its product, and suppose that the cost function in Example 5 represents its monthly costs. Then the firm s profit function is given by (3.3) π = r c = (100q 0.05q 2 ) (10q + 2000) = 0.05q 2 + 90q 2000. Squaring both sides of an equation can often lead to extraneous solutions, as in the example here. Notice that plugging q 1 into the demand equation above leads to a negative price, which contradicts the assumptions of the model. 3

4 4. Consumption, Savings and Income The relationship between income, consumption and savings is very important to economists. Income is often represented by the variable Y, (though the textbook uses I), consumption by the variable C and savings by S, (note that all of these variables are upper case). The relationship between these variables is often studied at the macroeconomic level, and they are typically measured in millions or billions of dollars a year. The fundamental relationship between consumption, savings and income is (4.1) Y = C + S, in other words, all of the income is either consumed or saved. Example 7. Suppose that the consumption function for a developing country is given by (4.2) C = 9Y 2 + Y 10Y + 3, where C and Y are both measured in millions of dollars a year. What is the savings function? Because of Equation (4.1) this question is easy to answer. Namely, S = Y C, so here 5. Input and output S = Y 9Y 2 + Y 10Y + 3 = Y 2 + 2Y 10Y + 3. Closely related to cost functions are output, or production functions. A production function of a firm, (or more generally, of an industry or an economy), is the function that describes the firm s output as it depends on the various inputs it uses in the production process. In the most basic models of production, output depends on two inputs, capital input and labor input, i.e., Q = F (K, L). Often, all three variables are measured in units of currency, so that the function is actually describing how the value of the output depends on values of the inputs. Example 8. A popular model of production is given by the Cobb-Douglas function, Q = AK α L β, where Q is output, and K and L are the capital and labor inputs, respectively. In this model it is assumed that the other three parameters, A, α and β are positive constants, with the further restriction that 0 < α < 1 and 0 < β < 1. Example 9. A firm s monthly output q is given by q = 75 m 5, Strictly speaking, in a classical Cobb-Douglas function, α + β = 1, which guarantees constant returns to scale, among other things.

where m is the number of the firm s (full-time) employees. A function like this, which depends only on labor input (m in this case) is sometimes used to model short term production. It is assumed that the capital input is fixed in the short term, and only the labor input varies. Example 10. given by Suppose that the demand equation for the firm from Example 9, above, is p = 2000 1 + 2 q, where p is the price per unit of the firm s product and q is the (monthly) demand for the firm s product. Find the firm s monthly revenue if it currently has m = 14 employees, assuming that it sells every unit it produces. Based on the production function in Example 9, if the firm has 14 full time employees, then its monthly output is q(14) = 75 9 = 225. Since the firm sells every unit it produces, the (current) price of the firm s product is p = 2000 1 + 225 = 2000 16 = 125, so the firm s monthly revenue is r = p q = 125 225 = 28125. 5