Convex duality in optimal investment under illiquidity

Similar documents
Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Markets with convex transaction costs

Superhedging in illiquid markets

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Arbitrage and deflators in illiquid markets

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs

Asset valuation and optimal investment

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 11 Oct 2008

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

Risk Neutral Pricing. to government bonds (provided that the government is reliable).

Law of the Minimal Price

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Lower and upper bounds of martingale measure densities in continuous time markets

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Lower and upper bounds of martingale measure densities in continuous time markets

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

Utility maximization in the large markets

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

PRICING CONTINGENT CLAIMS: A COMPUTATIONAL COMPATIBLE APPROACH

Pathwise Finance: Arbitrage and Pricing-Hedging Duality

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

Conditional Certainty Equivalent

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Continuous time Asset Pricing

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

The super-replication theorem under proportional transaction costs revisited

The minimal entropy martingale measure

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

On the law of one price

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE CENTRE DE MATHÉMATIQUES APPLIQUÉES UMR CNRS PALAISEAU CEDEX (FRANCE). Tél: Fax:

LIST OF PUBLICATIONS

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

Derivative Pricing and Logarithmic Portfolio Optimization in Incomplete Markets

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

arxiv: v4 [q-fin.pr] 10 Aug 2009

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

Robust hedging with tradable options under price impact

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Characterization of the Optimum

Arbitrage and Asset Pricing

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

Umut Çetin and L. C. G. Rogers Modelling liquidity effects in discrete time

Performance Measurement with Nonnormal. the Generalized Sharpe Ratio and Other "Good-Deal" Measures

Yuri Kabanov, Constantinos Kardaras and Shiqi Song No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

Spot and forward dynamic utilities. and their associated pricing systems. Thaleia Zariphopoulou. UT, Austin

Arbitrage Theory. The research of this paper was partially supported by the NATO Grant CRG

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

European Contingent Claims

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management: ineffectiveness of VaR and ES constraints

An example of indifference prices under exponential preferences

Hedging under Arbitrage

Stochastic Dynamics of Financial Markets

ON THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING. Dedicated to the memory of G. Kallianpur

ON THE EXISTENCE OF SHADOW PRICES

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON ARBITRAGE BY CHANGING THE STOCK EXCHANGE

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Non-semimartingales in finance

An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

ON UTILITY-BASED PRICING OF CONTINGENT CLAIMS IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

Pricing and hedging in the presence of extraneous risks

Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

Transcription:

Convex duality in optimal investment under illiquidity Teemu Pennanen August 16, 2013 Abstract We study the problem of optimal investment by embedding it in the general conjugate duality framework of convex analysis. This allows for various extensions to classical models of liquid markets. In particular, we obtain a dual representation for the optimum value function in the presence of portfolio constraints and nonlinear trading costs that are encountered e.g. in modern limit order markets. The optimization problem is parameterized by a sequence of financial claims. Such a parameterization is essential in markets without a numeraire asset when pricing swap contracts and other financial products with multiple payout dates. In the special case of perfectly liquid markets or markets with proportional transaction costs, we recover well-known dual expressions in terms of martingale measures. Key words: Optimal investment, illiquidity, convex duality 1 Introduction Convex duality has long been an integral part of mathematical finance. Classical references include Harrison and Kreps [15], Harrison and Pliska [16], Kreps [25] and Dalang et al. [8] where the no-arbitrage principle behind the Black Scholes formula was related to the existence of certain dual variables; see Delbaen and Schachermayer [10] for a detailed discussion of the topic. In problems of optimal investment, convex duality has become an important tool in the analysis of optimal solutions; see e.g. Kramkov and Schachermayer [23], Delbaen et al. [9], Karatzas and Zitković [21] and Rogers [40] and their references. This paper studies convex duality in problems of optimal investment in illiquid financial markets where one may encounter frictions or restrictions when transferring wealth through time or between assets. Our model extends the classical linear model by allowing for portfolio constraints and nonlinear transaction costs that are encountered e.g. in limit order markets. In particular, we Department of Mathematics, King s College London, teemu.pennanen@kcl.ac.uk 1

do not assume, a priori, the existence of a numeraire that allows for free transfer of (both positive as well as negative amounts of) wealth through time. This is a significant departure from the classical model where a numeraire is assumed in order to express wealth processes in terms of stochastic integrals. Such models are at odds with real markets where much of trading consists of exchanging sequences of cash-flows. Such trades would be unnecessary if one could postpone payments to a single date by shorting the numeraire. While in classical models of perfectly liquid markets, convex analysis can often be reduced to an application of basic separation theorem, in the presence of nonlinear illiquidity effects, more sophisticated convex analysis is needed; see for example Cvitanić and Karatzas [6], Jouini and Kallal [18, 17], Guasoni [14], Schachermayer [43], Rokhlin [41], Bielecki, Cialenco and Rodriguez [4] as well as the books of Kabanov and Safarian [19] and Rogers [40]. The present paper builds on the market model introduced in Pennanen [30] where trading costs and portfolio constraints are described by general convex normal integrands and measurable closed convex sets, respectively. This discrete-time model provides a unifying framework for modeling transaction costs and portfolio constraints as well as nonlinear illiquidity effects. The classical superhedging principle was extended to this model in [33, 32]. The present paper makes similar extensions to the duality theory of optimal investment. More precisely, we derive a dual representation for the optimal value function of the optimal investment problem studied in [34] as a basis for valuation of financial contracts. The dual representation is obtained by applying the stochastic optimization duality framework developed in [31] as an instance of the conjugate duality framework of Rockafellar [38]. This allows for a unified treatment of many well known models of mathematical finance where dual correspondences have often been derived case by case. In particular, we illustrate how the dual variables in the general case are connected to martingale measures and shadow prices that have been extensively studied in models with a numeraire. 2 Optimal investment This section recalls the optimal investment problem from [34]. The problem is parameterized by financial liabilities characterized by a sequence of cash-flows the agent has to deliver over time. The dependence of the optimum value on the liabilities is important in valuation of swap contracts and other financial products that provide payments at multiple points in time. Section 3 derives dual expressions for the optimum value function. Consider a financial market where a finite set J of assets can be traded over finite discrete time t = 0,..., T. We will model uncertainty by a probability space (Ω, F, P ) and the information by a nondecreasing sequence (F t ) T of sub-sigma algebras of F. At time t one does not know which scenario ω Ω will realize but only to which element of F t it belongs to. The filtration property F t F t+1 means that information increases over time. 2

We describe trading strategies by (F t ) T -adapted sequences x = (x t ) T of R J -valued stochastic processes. The random vector x t describes the portfolio of assets held over (t, t + 1]. The adaptedness means that x t is F t -measurable, i.e. the portfolio chosen at time t only depends on information available at time t. The linear space of adapted trading strategies will be denoted by N. Unless F T has only a finite number of elements with positive probability, N is an infinite-dimensional space. We will assume that F 0 = Ω, so that x 0 is independent of ω. Implementing a portfolio process x N requires buying a portfolio x t := x t x t 1 of assets at time t. Negative purchases are interpreted as sales. Trading costs will be described by an (F t ) T -adapted sequence S = (S t ) T of convex normal integrands on R J F. This means that for each t, the setvalued mapping ω (x, α) R J R S t (x, ω) α is closed convex-valued and F t -measurable 1. The value of S t (x, ω) is interpreted as the cost of buying a portfolio x R J at time t in state ω. Accordingly, we assume that S t (0, ω) = 0. Implementing a trading strategy x N requires investing S t ( x t ) units of cash at time t. The measurability condition on S t implies that ω S t ( x t (ω), ω) is F t -measurable, i.e. the cost of a portfolio is known at the time of purchase. Indeed, the cost is the composition of the measurable functions ω ( x t (ω), ω) and S t ; see e.g. [39, Corollary 14.34]. The classical model of perfectly liquid markets corresponds to S t (x, ω) = s t (ω) x where s = (s t ) is an (F t ) T -adapted sequence of price vectors independent of the traded amounts. Markets with proportional transaction costs and/or bid-ask-spreads can be modeled with sublinear cost functions S t (x, ω) = sups x s [s t (ω), s + t (ω)], where the (F t ) T -adapted R J -valued processes s and s + give the bid- and ask-prices, respectively; see [18]. Convex trading costs arise naturally also in modern limit order markets, where the cost of a market order is nonlinear and convex in the traded amount. Parametric convex market models have been proposed e.g. in Çetin and Rogers [5] and Malo and Pennanen [26]. We model portfolio constraints by requiring that the portfolio x t chosen at time t has to belong to a closed convex set D t much as e.g. in [28, 41, 11]. We allow D t to be random but assume that it is F t -measurable. We assume that 0 D t almost surely, i.e. that the zero portfolio is feasible. The classical unconstrained model corresponds to D R J while short selling constraints, studied e.g. in Cvitanic and Karatzas [6] and Jouini and Kallal [17] can be described by D R J +. As observed there, short selling constraints can also be used to model different interest rates for lending and borrowing. Indeed, this can be done by introducing lending and borrowing accounts whose unit prices appreciate at lending and borrowing rates, respectively, and by restricting the investments in these assets to be nonnegative and nonpositive, respectively. 1 A set-valued mapping T : Ω R n is F t-measurable if ω Ω T (ω) U F t for every open U R n. 3

Consider now an agent whose financial position is described by an (F t ) T - adapted sequence of cash-flows c = (c t ) T in the sense that the agent has to deliver a random amount c t of cash at time t. We allow c t to take both positive and negative values so it may describe both endowments as well as liabilities. In particular, c 0 may be interpreted as an initial endowment while the subsequent payments c t, t = 1,..., T may be interpreted as the cash-flows associated with financial liabilities. We will denote the linear space of (F t ) T -adapted sequences of cash-flows by M = (c t ) T c t L 0 (Ω, F t, P ). Here and in what follows, L 0 (Ω, F t, P ) stands for the linear space of equivalence classes of F t -measurable real-valued functions. As usual, two measurable functions are equivalent if they coincide P -almost surely. Given c M, and nondecreasing 2 convex functions V t on L 0 (Ω, F t, P ), we will study the problem minimize V t (S t ( x t ) + c t ) over x N D, (ALM) where N D := x N x t D t, t = 0,..., T 1, x T = 0 and x t := x t x t 1. We always define x 1 = 0 so the elements of N D describe trading strategies that start and end at liquidated positions. The functions V t measure the disutility (regret, loss,... ) caused by the net expenditure S t ( x t ) + c t of updating the portfolio and paying out the claim c t at time t. We allow V t to be extended realvalued but assume that V t (0) = 0. We interpret the value of V t (S t ( x t ) + c t ) as + unless S t ( x t ) L 0 (Ω, F t, P ). In other words, the formulation of (ALM) includes the implicit constraint that x t dom S t almost surely. Problem (ALM) can be interpreted as an asset-liability management problem where one looks for a trading strategy whose proceeds fit the liabilities c M optimally as measured by the disutility functions V t. Despite the simple appearance, (ALM) covers many more familiar instances of portfolio optimization problems. In particular, when 3 V t = δ L 0 for t < T, we can write it as minimize V T (S T ( x T ) + c T ) over x N D subject to S t ( x t ) + c t 0, t = 0,..., T 1. (1) This is an illiquid version of the classical utility maximization problem. Example 1 (Numeraire and stochastic integration) Assume, as e.g. in Çetin and Rogers [5] and Czichowsky et al. [7], that there is a perfectly liquid asset (numeraire), say 0 J, such that S t (x) = x 0 + S t ( x) and D t = R D t, 2 A function V t : L 0 (Ω, F t, P ) R is nondecreasing if V t(c 1 t ) Vt(c2 t ) whenever c1 t c2 t almost surely. 3 Here and in what follows, δ C denotes the indicator function of a set C: δ C (x) equals 0 or + depending on whether x C or not. 4

where S and D are the cost process and the constraints for the remaining risky assets J = J \ 0. We can then use the budget constraint in (1) to substitute out the numeraire from the problem. Indeed, defining x 0 t = x 0 t 1 S t ( x t ) c t t = 0,..., T 1, the budget constraint holds as an equality for t = 1,..., T 1 and 1 x 0 T 1 = 1 S t ( x t ) Substituting this in the objective (and recalling that x T = 0 for x N D ), problem (1) becomes ( T ) minimize V T S t ( x t ) + c t over x N D, which shows that in the presence of a numeraire, the timing of payments is irrelevant. This is the problem studied in [5] in the case of strictly convex S t and in [7] in the case of sublinear S t. In linear market models with S t ( x, ω) = s t (ω) x t, we can express the accumulated trading costs as a stochastic integral, S t ( x t ) = c t. 1 s t x t = x t s t+1. We then recover constrained discrete-time versions of the utility maximization problems studied e.g. in [23, 9, 24, 2, 3]. In [23, 24, 2], the financial position of the agent was described solely in terms of an initial endowment w R without future liabilities. This corresponds to c 0 = w and c t = 0 for t > 0. We will denote the optimal value of problem (ALM) by ϕ(c) := V t (S t ( x t ) + c t ). inf x N D It is easily verified that ϕ is a convex function on M. The value function ϕ has a central role in the valuation of financial contracts with multiple payout dates; see [34]. In the completely risk averse case where V t = δ L 0 for all t = 0,..., T, we get ϕ = δ C, where C = c M x N D : S t ( x t ) + c t 0 is the set of claim processes that can be superhedged without a cost; see [33] for further discussion and references on superhedging. On the other hand, since the functions V t are nondecreasing, we can write ϕ as the infimal convolution T ϕ(c) = inf V t (d t ) d M c d C (2) = inf d C V t (c t d t ), t 5

of δ C and the function V(d) = V t (d t ) as is seen by first writing (ALM) in the form minimize V t (d t ) over x N, d M subject to S t ( x t ) + c t d t, x t D t. (3) The variable d may be interpreted as investments the agent makes to his portfolio over time. Alternatively, one may interpret c and d as endowment and consumption, respectively, in the spirit of the optimal consumption-investment problem of Karatzas and Zitković [21] in liquid markets in continuous time. 3 Duality Prices of financial products are often expressed in terms of dual variables of one kind or another. Prices of bonds can be expressed in terms of zero curves, which represent the time-value of money. In models with a cash-account, on the other hand, prices of random cash-flows are often expressed in terms of martingale measures. In illiquid markets without a cash-account, one needs more general dual variables that encompass both the time value of money as well as the randomness. This section derives a dual representation for the value function ϕ of (ALM) in terms of such variables. When specialized to more traditional market models, we recover (discrete-time versions of) some well-known duality results for portfolio optimization. Pricing formulas for contingent claims can then be derived from the general relationships between the optimal investment and contingent claim valuation; see [34]. Our strategy is to embed (ALM) in the general stochastic optimization duality framework of [31] which is essentially an instance of the classical conjugate duality framework of Rockafellar [38]. The bilinear form c, y := E c t y t puts the space M 1 := (c t ) T c t L 1 (Ω, F t, P ) of integrable sequences of cash-flows in separating duality with the space M := (y t ) T y t L (Ω, F t, P ) of essentially bounded adapted processes. Given a convex function f on M 1, its conjugate on M is defined by f (y) = sup c M 1 c, y f(c). 6

Being the pointwise supremum of continuous linear functions, f is convex and lower semicontinuous with respect to the weak topology σ(m, M 1 ). The classical biconjugate theorem says that if f is proper and lower semicontinuous with respect to the L 1 -norm, then it has the dual representation f(c) = sup c, y f (y); (4) y M see Moreau [27]. This abstract formula is behind many fundamental duality results in mathematical finance. In order to apply it to (ALM), we will first establish the lower semicontinuity of the value function ϕ. We will assume from now on that V t (c t ) = Ev t (c t ) := v t (c t (ω), ω)dp (ω), where v t is an F t -measurable normal integrand on R Ω such that v t (, ω) is proper, nondecreasing and convex with v t (0, ω) = 0 for every ω Ω. As usual, we define the integral of a measurable function as + unless the positive part of the function is integrable. Given a market model (S, D), we obtain another market model (S, D ) by defining S t (, ω) and D t (ω) pointwise as the recession function and recession cone of S t (, ω) and D t (ω), respectively. When S is sublinear and D is conical, we simply have (S, D) = (S, D ). By [37, Corollary 8.3.2 and Theorem 8.5], S t (x, ω) = sup α>0 S t (αx, ω), α D t (ω) = α>0 αd t (ω). The required measurability properties hold by [39, Exercises 14.54 and 14.21] while the convexity and topological properties come directly from the definitions. The following is derived in [34] from a more general result of [35] on stochastic optimization. Theorem 2 Assume that x N D St ( x t ) 0 is a linear space and that v t (, ω) are nonconstant functions with v t m for some integrable function m L 1. Then the value function ϕ is a proper lower semicontinuous convex function on M 1 and the infimum in (ALM) is attained for every c M 1. The linearity condition in Theorem 2 is a generalization of the no-arbitrage condition in classical perfectly liquid markets; see [32, Section 4]. In particular, when S t (x) = s t x and D t R J, the linearity condition means that any x N D with s t x 0 almost surely for all t has s t x = 0 almost surely for all t, i.e. there are no self-financing trading strategies that generate nonzero revenue. This is exactly the no-arbitrage condition. In nonlinear market models, the linearity condition is implied by the so called robust no-arbitrage condition; see [32, Section 4]. In the most risk averse case where v t = δ R for every t, Theorem 2 7

says that the set C is closed. In the classical linear model of Example 1, we thus recover the key closedness result of Schachermayer [42, Lemma 2.1]. The linearity condition holds also if D t (ω) x R J S t (x, ω) 0 = 0 almost surely for every t. Indeed, since x 1 = 0, by definition, this condition implies x N D S t ( x t ) 0 = 0. This certainly holds if D t R J + and x R J S t (x, ω) 0 R J + = 0. Here, the first condition means that infinite short positions are prohibited while the second means that there are no completely worthless assets. Nonconstancy of v t (, ω) in Theorem 2 simply means that the investor always prefers more money to less. The lower bound is a more significant restriction since it excludes e.g. the logarithmic utility. In Kramkov and Schachermayer [23] and Rasonyi and Stettner [36] such bounds were avoided but, at present, it is unclear if the lower bound can be relaxed in illiquid markets. However, Guasoni [13, Theorem 5.2] gives the existence of optimal solutions in a continuous time model with a cash-account and proportional transaction with similar conditions on the utility function as in [23] and [36]. Much like in [36] and the proof of Theorem 2, his approach was based on the direct method rather than duality arguments as e.g. in [23]. While Theorem 2 establishes the validity of the dual representation for the value function ϕ, its conjugate ϕ can be expressed in terms of the support function σ C (y) = sup c M 1 c, y c C of C and the conjugates of the disutility functions v t as follows. vt (y, ω) = supcy v t (c, ω) c R Lemma 3 The conjugate of ϕ can be expressed as ϕ (y) = σ C (y) + E Proof. Problem (ALM) can be written as vt (y t ). minimize Ef(x, d, c) over x N, d M, where f : (R J ) T +1 R T +1 R T +1 Ω R is defined T v t(d t, ω) if S t ( x t, ω) + c t d t, x t D t (ω), x T = 0, f(x, d, c, ω) = + otherwise. Since v t and S t are normal integrands and D t are measurable, it follows from Theorem 14.36 and Proposition 14.44 of [39] that f is a normal integrand. We 8

are thus in the general stochastic optimization framework of [31] so, by [31, Theorem 2.2], ϕ (y) = inf El(x, d, y), (5) x N,d M where l(x, d, y, ω) = inf c R T +1f(x, d, c, ω) T c ty t. We can write l as + unless x X(ω), l(x, d, y, ω) = T [v t(d t, ω) + y t S t ( x t, ω) d t y t ] if x X(ω) and y 0, otherwise, where X(ω) = x (R J ) T +1 x t dom S t (, ω), x t D t (ω) t. Unless y 0 almost surely, the infimum in (5) equals (it is attained e.g. by (x, d) = (0, 0)). For y 0, ϕ (y) = inf x N,d M = inf x N = inf x N E E E [y t S t ( x t ) + v t (d t ) d t y t ] x X y t S t ( x t ) x X + inf E T [v t (d t ) d t y t ] d M y t S t ( x t ) x X E vt (y t ), where the second equality holds since we can restrict the minimization, without affecting the infimum, to those x N and d M for which both integrands have integrable positive parts. The last equality comes from the interchange rule for normal integrands; see e.g. [39, Theorem 14.60]. A similar argument in the case v t δ R, shows that σ C (y) = inf x N E y t S t ( x t ) x X for y 0 while σ C (y) = for y 0. The form of the conjugate in Lemma 3 is not surprising given the expression (2) of ϕ as the infimal convolution of δ C and V. However, the infimal convolution is taken in the space M of all adapted claim processes, not over M 1. One could, of course, concentrate on integrable claim processes from the beginning and study the function ϕ(c) = inf E v t (d t ) d M 1 c d C which has the same conjugate and essentially the same economic interpretation as ϕ. However, the proof of Theorem 2 breaks down if d M is restricted to M 1 9

and we do not know whether ϕ is lower semicontinuous under the assumptions of Theorem 2. Combining Theorem 2 and Lemma 3 with the biconjugate theorem gives the following. Theorem 4 Under assumptions of Theorem 2, the value function of (ALM) has the dual representation ϕ(c) = c, y σ C (y) E vt (y t ). sup y M In general, the supremum in the above expression need not be attained; see Remark 7 below. When C is a cone, the dual representation can be written ϕ(c) = sup c, y E vt (y t ), y C where C := y M c, y 0 c C M 1 is the polar cone of C. This is similar in form with the primal formulation ϕ(c) = inf E v t (c t d t ). d C Example 5 Much of duality theory in optimal investment has studied the optimum value as a function of the initial endowment only; see e.g. Kramkov and Schachermayer [23] or Klein and Rogers [22]. The function V (c 0 ) = ϕ(c 0, 0,..., 0) gives the optimum value of (ALM) for an agent with initial capital c 0 and no future liabilities/endowments. Using (2), we can write this as V (c 0 ) = inf T v t (d t ), d C(c 0) (6) where the set C(c 0 ) = d M (c 0, 0,..., 0) d C consists of sequences of investments needed to finance a riskless trading strategy when starting with initial capital c 0. If ϕ is proper and lower semicontinuous (see Theorem 2), the biconjugate theorem gives where V (c 0 ) = sup c 0 y 0 ϕ (y) = sup c 0 y 0 U(y 0 ) y M U(y 0 ) = y 0 R inf (z) z z M ϕ 0 = y 0. If C is conical, we can use Lemma 3 to write U analogously to (6) as U(y 0 ) = inf E T vt (z t ), z Y(y 0) 10

where Y(y 0 ) = z C z 0 = y 0. In general, there is no reason to believe that U is lower semicontinuous nor that the infimum in its definition is attained. In some cases, however, it is possible to enlarge the set Y(y 0 ) so that the function U becomes lower semicontinuous and the infimum is attained; see [7, Section 4] for details. In order to relate the above to more familiar duality results in optimal investment, we need an explicit expression for the support function σ C. A cost process S is said to be integrable if S t (x, ) is integrable for every x R J and t = 0,..., T. Integrability implies that dom S t (, ω) = R J almost surely 4. A linear cost process S t (x, ω) = s t (ω) x is integrable if and only if s t are integrable. The following result, where N 1 denotes the space of integrable R J -valued adapted processes and E t the conditional expectation with respect to F t, is from [30, Lemma A1]. Its proof is based on the classical Fenchel Moreau Rockafellar duality theorem. Lemma 6 If S is integrable, then T 1 σ C (y) = inf E(y t S t ) (z t ) + Eσ Dt (E t z t+1 ) z N 1 for every y M + while σ C (y) = + for y / M +. Moreover, the infimum is attained for every y M +. If S is sublinear and integrable (so that dom S t = R J and S t is the indicator of its domain), we get (y t S t ) (z) = δ(z y t dom S t ). If in addition, D is conical, we have σ Dt = δ D t and σ C = δ C, where, by Lemma 6, C = y M + z N 1 : z t y t dom S t, E t [ z t+1 ] D t. The polar cone of C can also be written as 5 C = y M + s N : s t dom S t, E t [ (y t+1 s t+1 )] D t. In unconstrained linear models with S t (x, ω) = s t (ω) x and D t (ω) = R J, we get dom S t = s t and D t (ω) = 0 so that C = y M + ys is a martingale, while in models with bid-ask spreads, we get dom S t = [s t, s + t ] and C = y M + s N : s t s t s + t, ys is a martingale. When short selling is prohibited, i.e. when D t = R J +, the condition E t [ (y t+1 s t+1 )] D t means that ys is a supermartingale. 4 Integrability implies P (S t(x, ) R) = 1 for every x R J so P (S t(x, ) R x Q J ) = 1, where Q denotes the rational numbers. Since S t(, ω) are convex, this implies P (S t(x, ω) R x R J ) = 1. 5 Here we use the fact that the integrability of S implies that every selector of dom S t is integrable. 11

Remark 7 (Shadow prices) In unconstrained models with bid-ask spreads, the dual representation of the value function can be written ϕ(c) = c, y E vt (y t ) s N : s t s t s + t, ys is a martingale. sup y M If the supremum is attained, the corresponding s N has the property that the optimum value of (ALM) is not affected if trading costs are reduced by replacing S by the linear cost functions S t (x, ω) = s t (ω) x. Indeed, the corresponding value function ϕ satisfies ϕ(c) ϕ(c) sup c, y ϕ (y) y M = sup c, y E vt (y t ) ys is a martingale. y M where the first inequality holds because S S and the equality comes from Lemma 3. If ϕ is proper and lower semicontinuous and if the supremum in its dual representation is attained by a y M and s, then the last supremum equals ϕ(c). In [7], price processes s such that ϕ(c) = ϕ(c) are called shadow prices. If the disutility functions v t are strictly increasing, then in the presence of a shadow price s, the optimal solution x N D of (ALM), which exists under the assumptions of Theorem 2, must satisfy the complementarity conditions x t > 0 = s t = s + t and x t < 0 = s t = s t since otherwise x would achieve strictly lower trading costs and thus, a strictly lower objective value in the model with the linear cost functions S t. Section 3 of [7, ] gives an example where shadow prices do not exist and thus, the supremum in the dual representation of ϕ is not attained. In the presence of a numeraire (see Example 1), the elements of C can be expressed in terms of probability measures. Corollary 8 (Numeraire and martingale measures) Assume that S is integrable and that S t (x, ω) = x 0 + S t ( x, ω) and D t (ω) = R D t (ω), where S is sublinear and D is conical. Then 6 C = posy M + Q P : y t = E t dq dp where P = Q P s Ñ : s t dom S t, E Q t s t+1 D t Q-a.s. and Ñ denotes the set of adapted R J\0 -valued processes. 6 For a subset C of a vector space, pos C := αx α 0, x C. 12

Proof. We get dom S t = 1 dom S t and D t = 0 D t so, by Lemma 6, y C iff y is a nonnegative martingale and E t [ (y t+1 s t+1 )] D t for some (F t ) T -adapted selector s of dom S such that y s is integrable. Clearly, C = posy C Ey T = 1. If y C with Ey T = 1, then y T is the density of a probability measure Q P and, by [12, Proposition A.12], E Q t [ s t+1 ] = E t[y T s t+1 ] E t y T = E t[ (y t+1 s t+1 )] E t y T Q-a.s. Since D t is a cone, this implies E Q t [ s t+1 ] D t Q-almost surely. Thus, y C Ey T = 1 y M dq + Q P : y t = E t dp. Conversely, if y t = E t [dq/dp ] for some Q P, we get similarly that E t [y T s t+1 ] D t Q-a.s.. Since E t [y T s t+1 ] = 0 P -almost surely on any A F t with Q(A) = 0 and since 0 D t, we get E t [y T s t+1 ] D t P -a.s. and thus, y C. We thus have y C Ey T = 1 = y M + Q P : y t = E t dq dp which completes the proof. In the classical linear model with S t (x, ω) = s t (ω) x and D t = R J, we have dom S t = s t and D t = 0 so the set P in Corollary 8 becomes the set of absolutely continuous martingale measures. In unconstrained models with bid-ask spreads, P is the set of absolutely continuous probability measures Q such that there exists a Q-martingale s with s t s t s + t for all t. Example 9 In the setting of Corollary 8, the dual representation of ϕ in Theorem 4 can be written as ϕ(c) = sup y C E [c t y t vt (y t )] = sup sup E λ 0 Q P = sup sup λ 0 Q P dq T c t λe t dp vt dq (λe t dp ) λe Q T c t E vt dq (λe t dp ). This is an illiquid discrete-time version of the dual problem of the optimal consumption problem from Karatzas and Zitković [21] which extends the duality 13

framework of Kramkov and Schachermayer [23] by allowing consumption of wealth over time. When v t = δ R for t < T, we obtain a discrete-time version with illiquidity effects of the duality results in Owen and Zitković [29] and Biagini, Frittelli and Graselli [3]. In the exponential case v T (c) = 1 α (eαc 1), we get vt (y) = (y ln y y + 1)/α and the supremum over λ is attained at This gives ϕ(c) = sup Q P λ = exp(e(α c t y t y T ln y T )). 1 α exp[αeq [ = 1 α exp sup αe Q Q P c t H(Q P )] 1 α ] T c t H(Q P ) 1 α. In the linear case S t (x) = s t x, this reduces to a discrete-time version of the duality framework of [9]; see also [20] and [1]. 4 Conclusions This paper studied optimal investment in the general conjugate duality framework of convex analysis. This has the benefit of allowing for various generalizations to the classical market models based on the theory of stochastic integration. In particular, the introduction of portfolio constraints and nonlinear illiquidity effects poses no particular problems compared to the classical model of perfectly liquid markets. One could also include dividend payments as proposed in [4]. Separation of dividend payments from total returns is important in the presence of transaction costs. The optimization problem studied in this paper has important applications in accounting and in the valuation of swap contracts and other financial products with multiple payout dates. This has been studied in [34]. The related duality theory will be developed elsewhere. References [1] D. Becherer. Rational hedging and valuation of integrated risks under constant absolute risk aversion. Insurance Math. Econom., 33(1):1 28, 2003. [2] S. Biagini and M. Frittelli. A unified framework for utility maximization problems: An orlicz spaces approach. The Annals of Applied Probability, 18(3):929 966, 2008. 14

[3] S. Biagini, M. Frittelli, and M. Grasselli. Indifference price with general semimartingales. Mathematical Finance, 21(3):423 446, 2011. [4] T. Bielecki, I. Cialenco, and R. Rodriguez. No-arbitrage pricing for dividend-paying securities in discrete-time markets with transaction costs. Technical report, 2012. [5] U. Çetin and L. C. G. Rogers. Modelling liquidity effects in discrete time. Mathematical Finance, 17(1):15 29, 2007. [6] J. Cvitanić and I. Karatzas. Convex duality in constrained portfolio optimization. Ann. Appl. Probab., 2(4):767 818, 1992. [7] C. Czichowsky, J. Muhle-Karbe, and W. Schachermayer. Transaction costs, shadow prices, and connections to duality. preprint, 2012. [8] R. C. Dalang, A. Morton, and W. Willinger. Equivalent martingale measures and no-arbitrage in stochastic securities market models. Stochastics Stochastics Rep., 29(2):185 201, 1990. [9] F. Delbaen, P. Grandits, T. Rheinländer, D. Samperi, M. Schweizer, and C. Stricker. Exponential hedging and entropic penalties. Math. Finance, 12(2):99 123, 2002. [10] F. Delbaen and W. Schachermayer. The Mathematics of Arbitrage. Springer Finance. Springer-Verlag, Berlin Heidelberg, 2006. [11] M. A. H. Dempster, I. V. Evstigneev, and M. I. Taksar. Asset pricing and hedging in financial markets with transaction costs: An approach based on the Von Neumann Gale model. Annals of Finance, 2(4):327 355, 2006. [12] H. Föllmer and A. Schied. Stochastic finance. Walter de Gruyter & Co., Berlin, extended edition, 2011. An introduction in discrete time. [13] P. Guasoni. Optimal investment with transaction costs and without semimartingales. Ann. Appl. Probab., 12(4):1227 1246, 2002. [14] P. Guasoni. Risk minimization under transaction costs. Finance Stoch., 6(1):91 113, 2002. [15] J. M. Harrison and D. M. Kreps. Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities markets. J. Econom. Theory, 20(3):381 408, 1979. [16] J. M. Harrison and S. R. Pliska. Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of continuous trading. Stochastic Process. Appl., 11(3):215 260, 1981. [17] E. Jouini and H. Kallal. Arbitrage in securities markets with short-sales constraints. Math. Finance, 5(3):197 232, 1995. 15

[18] E. Jouini and H. Kallal. Martingales and arbitrage in securities markets with transaction costs. J. Econom. Theory, 66(1):178 197, 1995. [19] Y. M. Kabanov and M. Safarian. Markets with transaction costs. Springer Finance. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 2009. Mathematical theory. [20] Y. M. Kabanov and Ch. Stricker. On the optimal portfolio for the exponential utility maximization: remarks to the six-author paper Exponential hedging and entropic penalties [Math. Finance 12 (2002), no. 2, 99 123; MR1891730 (2003b:91046)] by F. Delbaen, P. Grandits, T. Rheinländer, D. Samperi, M. Schweizer and C. Stricker. Math. Finance, 12(2):125 134, 2002. [21] I. Karatzas and G. Zitković. Optimal consumption from investment and random endowment in incomplete semimartingale markets. The Annals of Probability, 31(4):1821 1858, 2003. [22] I. Klein and L. C. G. Rogers. Duality in optimal investment and consumption problems with market frictions. Math. Finance, 17(2):225 247, 2007. [23] D. Kramkov and W. Schachermayer. The condition on the asymptotic elasticity of utility functions and optimal investment in incomplete markets. Annals of Applied Probability, 9(3):904 950, 1999. [24] D. Kramkov and W. Schachermayer. Necessary and sufficient conditions in the problem of optimal investment in incomplete markets. Ann. Appl. Probab., 13(4):1504 1516, 2003. [25] D. M. Kreps. Arbitrage and equilibrium in economies with infinitely many commodities. J. Math. Econom., 8(1):15 35, 1981. [26] P. Malo and T. Pennanen. Reduced form modeling of limit order markets. Quantitative Finance, 12(7):1025 1036, 2012. [27] J.-J. Moreau. Fonctionelles convexes. Séminaire sur les Equations aux Dérivées Partielles. Collège de France, Paris, 1967. [28] C. Napp. The Dalang-Morton-Willinger theorem under cone constraints. J. Math. Econom., 39(1-2):111 126, 2003. Special issue on equilibrium with asymmetric information. [29] M. P. Owen and G. Žitković. Optimal investment with an unbounded random endowment and utility-based pricing. Math. Finance, 19(1):129 159, 2009. [30] T. Pennanen. Arbitrage and deflators in illiquid markets. Finance and Stochastics, 15(1):57 83, 2011. [31] T. Pennanen. Convex duality in stochastic optimization and mathematical finance. Mathematics of Operations Research, 36(2):340 362, 2011. 16

[32] T. Pennanen. Dual representation of superhedging costs in illiquid markets. Mathematics and Financial Economics, 5:233 248, 2011. [33] T. Pennanen. Superhedging in illiquid markets. Mathematical Finance, 21(3):519 540, 2011. [34] T. Pennanen. Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets. manuscript, 2013. [35] T. Pennanen and A.-P. Perkkiö. Stochastic programs without duality gaps. Mathematical Programming, 136(1):91 110, 2012. [36] M. Rásonyi and L. Stettner. On utility maximization in discrete-time financial market models. Ann. Appl. Probab., 15(2):1367 1395, 2005. [37] R. T. Rockafellar. Convex analysis. Princeton Mathematical Series, No. 28. Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J., 1970. [38] R. T. Rockafellar. Conjugate duality and optimization. Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, Philadelphia, Pa., 1974. [39] R. T. Rockafellar and R. J.-B. Wets. Variational analysis, volume 317 of Grundlehren der Mathematischen Wissenschaften [Fundamental Principles of Mathematical Sciences]. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1998. [40] L. C. G. Rogers. Optimal Investment. Springer, Berlin, 2013. [41] D. B. Rokhlin. An extended version of the Dalang-Morton-Willinger theorem under convex portfolio constraints. Theory Probab. Appl., 49(3):429 443, 2005. [42] W. Schachermayer. A Hilbert space proof of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing in finite discrete time. Insurance Math. Econom., 11(4):249 257, 1992. [43] W. Schachermayer. The fundamental theorem of asset pricing under proportional transaction costs in finite discrete time. Math. Finance, 14(1):19 48, 2004. 17