BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING AND BLACK-SCHOLES

Similar documents
Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Homework Assignments

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Homework Assignments

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Option Pricing Models. c 2013 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 205

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Stochastic Interest Rates

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options

The Multistep Binomial Model

Math 489/Math 889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Dunbar, Fall 2007

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

American options and early exercise

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Lecture 16: Delta Hedging

1 The continuous time limit

1 Geometric Brownian motion

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

Problems from 9th edition of Probability and Statistical Inference by Hogg, Tanis and Zimmerman:

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

Option Pricing With Dividends

RISK ADJUSTMENT FOR LOSS RESERVING BY A COST OF CAPITAL TECHNIQUE

ANALYSIS OF THE BINOMIAL METHOD

Computational Finance Binomial Trees Analysis

Advanced Numerical Methods

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Option Pricing Models for European Options

IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models. Fall 2013, Professor Whitt. Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10.

Arbitrages and pricing of stock options

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Derivative Securities

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

δ j 1 (S j S j 1 ) (2.3) j=1

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Central Limit Theorem (cont d) 7/28/2006

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

Degree project. Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model

Tutorial 11: Limit Theorems. Baoxiang Wang & Yihan Zhang bxwang, April 10, 2017

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Chapter 3 Common Families of Distributions. Definition 3.4.1: A family of pmfs or pdfs is called exponential family if it can be expressed as

Option pricing with regime switching by trinomial tree method

Statistical Tables Compiled by Alan J. Terry

Roy Model of Self-Selection: General Case

Probability in Options Pricing

EE641 Digital Image Processing II: Purdue University VISE - October 29,

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

The Normal Distribution

STAT 830 Convergence in Distribution

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

Estimation. Focus Points 10/11/2011. Estimating p in the Binomial Distribution. Section 7.3

The simplest model for pricingderivative securities is the binomial model. It generalizes

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS AND MULTIPLE-EXPIRY EXOTICS

P VaR0.01 (X) > 2 VaR 0.01 (X). (10 p) Problem 4

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

Risk Neutral Valuation, the Black-

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Lecture: Continuous Time Finance Lecturer: o. Univ. Prof. Dr. phil. Helmut Strasser

1 Parameterization of Binomial Models and Derivation of the Black-Scholes PDE.

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Lévy models in finance

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral

Fixed-Income Options

Outline One-step model Risk-neutral valuation Two-step model Delta u&d Girsanov s Theorem. Binomial Trees. Haipeng Xing

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

Introduction to Financial Mathematics

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.gn] 13 Aug 2018

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Option Pricing for Discrete Hedging and Non-Gaussian Processes

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION. Lecture 5: Dynamic Programming and a Visit to the Soft Side

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

9 Expectation and Variance

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Mathematics in Finance

Modeling the Real Term Structure

Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 5: Tools from Option Pricing

The Black-Scholes Model

MA : Introductory Probability

Numerical Evaluation of Multivariate Contingent Claims

Chapter 7. Sampling Distributions and the Central Limit Theorem

Lecture Stat 302 Introduction to Probability - Slides 15

Transcription:

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING AND BLACK-CHOLE JOHN THICKTUN 1. Introduction This paper aims to investigate the assumptions under which the binomial option pricing model converges to the Blac-choles formula. The results are not original; the paper mostly follows the outline of Cox, Ross, and Rubenstein[1]. However, the convergence is treated in greater detail than I have found elsewhere in the literature. This exercise clarifies the assumptions behind the binomial model and subsequent convergence results. 2. The Binomial Model We begin by defining the binomial option pricing model. uppose we have an option on an underlying with a current price. Denote the option s strie by K, its expiry by T, and let r be one plus the continuously compounded ris-free rate. We model the option s price using a branching binomial tree over n discrete time periods. Let u represent one plus a positive return on the underlying s value over a single period and similarly let d represent a negative return. Denote the single-period interest rate by r n and let π be the ris-neutral probability; i.e. r n = πu + 1 πd 1. Then the binomial model for the price C of the option is given by 1 C = 1 rn π 1 π n max0, u d n K. =1 This model can be interpreted as follows. At each discrete time step, the underlying may increase or decrease in value, by u or d respectively, as controlled by independent Bernp random variables. Therefore, after n time steps, the underlying will have made up moves where Bn, p. The value of the option at expiry is then P = max0, u d n K. This is the payoff of the option. The expected value of the option at expiry using this model follows by the law of the unconscious statistician: E[P ] = =1 n p 1 p n P. 1 We implicitly assume d rn u maing 0 π 1. This assumption is reasonable; it amounts to a statement that there exists a future state of the world in which holding the underlying asset yields a profit. 1

2 JOHN THICKTUN We might naively thin that we could price an option by discounting this expected value. This is not the case! No-arbitrage constraints 2 instead force us to substitute the risneutral probability π for the true probability p. Accordingly, we may view the binomial model as the discounted expected payoff of the option in a ris-neutral world: C = 1 ] rn E π [max0, u d n K = 1 rn E π [P ]. Note that the binomial model is contingent upon model parameters u, d, and n. Clearly modeling n discrete time steps is imprecise; in real-world trading, underlying price moves are effectively a continuous process. The purpose of the paper is essentially to investigate the limiting behavior of this model as n. Choice of u and d is more open. After some algebraic preliminaries in section 3, we will consider these parameters in section 4. Then, in section 5, we will see how binomial pricing converges in the limit to the Blac-choles formula. 3. Algebraic Considerations The object of this section is merely to algebraically re-formulate the model we have introduced. Knowledgeable readers will see the pattern of Blac-choles begin to emerge. Proposition 3.1. Let a = min P > 0. Then for some ζ [0, 1 we have a = logk/ n log d logu/d + ζ. Proof. By definition of a, u a d n a > K. olving for a we have a log u + n a log d + log > log K alog u log d > log K log n log d a > logk/ n log d. logu/d Introducing an error term, it follows that for some ζ 0, a = logk/ n log d logu/d + ζ. Furthermore because a was defined to be minimal we see that ζ < 1. Proposition 3.2. Let a = min P > 0 and define π = u/r n π then C = B a; n, π Krn n B a; n, π. 2 The no-arbitrage constraints of the binomial model are beyond the scope of this paper. ee [1] for details. The idea is to construct a portfolio of the underlying and risless asset that replicates the returns of the option for a single period. Then, extrapolate to the n-period case by induction.

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING AND BLACK-CHOLE 3 Proof. Let a = min P > 0. Note P is monotone increasing, so we may re-write the binomial model as C = 1 rn π 1 π n u d n K =a = r n n =a =a π 1 π n u d n Krn n =a π 1 π n. Recall that π is ris-neutral. ubstituing π = u/r n π we see that 1 π = rn 1 1 πd and therefore [ ] n πu [ ] 1 πd n rn n π 1 π n u d n = = π 1 π n. We therefore see that C = =a =a r n π 1 π n Kr n n r n =a =a π 1 π n. = 1 Ba; n, π Krn n 1 Ba; n, π = B a; n, π Krn n B a; n, π. The last equality follows from the symmetry of the binomial distribution. 4. tatistical Considerations We now turn our attention to the model parameters u and d. There are many plausible choices available to us, each of which leads to slightly different binomial models. ee Chance[5] for a discussion and comparison of many proposals. There does not appear to be a final word yet in the literature on the selection of binomial model parameters. Chance gives us the modest observation that binomial option pricing is a remarably flexible procedure. The reader may also be interested in Liesen and Reimer[6], who suggest that parameter choice has implications for the model s rate of convergence For our purposes, we will adopt the parameter choices of Cox, Ross, and Rubenstein[1]. In particular, we introduce a new paramter σ and tae u = e σ T/n and d = 1/u. This may appear unhelpful; we have merely renamed our u and d parameters in terms of σ. But we will see at the end of this section that the parameter σ has a meaningful interpretation. Proposition 4.1. Let u = e σt/n and let q satisfy q log u+1 q log d <. If Bn, q then as n, [ ] [ ] E log n = νt, Var log n σ 2 T.

4 JOHN THICKTUN Proof. By our hypothesized condition on q, there must be some ν R such that In other words, for some ν we have q = ν + logu 2 logu ν = q log u + 1 q log d. = ν + σ T/n 2σ T/n = 1 2 + ν T 2σ n. First we will examine the mean of log returns. Recall that Bn, q, so by proposition C.1, E[] = nq. Note by definition that n/ = u d n and by linearity, E [log n/] = E[ logu/d + n log d] = nq logu/d + logd. = n2q 1 logu = n ν/σ T/n σ T/n = νt. Now we will examine the variance. ince Bn, q by proposition C.2 we have Var[] = nq1 q. Then by basic algebra, Var [log n/] = Var [ logu/d + n log d] = nq1 q logu/d 2 = 4q1 q logu 2 n = 2q2 2qσ 2 T/n = 1 + ν T/n 1 ν T/n σ 2 T. σ σ = 1 ν2 σ 2 T/n σ 2 T = σ 2 T ν2 T 2 σ 2 n. And so we may conclude that [ ] lim Var log n = σ 2 T. n From this we see that under the mild condition q log u + 1 q log d <, the log return of the underlying has variance σ 2 T. In particular both the ris neutral measure π and π as well as the physical measure p satisfy this condition. Proposition 4.2. Let u = e σ T/n and let ν = q logu+1 q logd <. If Bn, q then as n, log n/ d N νt, σ 2 T. Proof. By definition, we have log n = log u d n = 2 n logu = 2 nσ T/n. By basic algebra we see that P log n/ x = P 2 nσ T/n x = P x n 2 σ 2 T + n 2.

Let z = BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING AND BLACK-CHOLE 5 x n 2 + n σ 2 T 2. Because Bn, q we have P log n/ x = Bz, n, q. Let y be such that z = y np1 q + nq. ome algebra shows us that q = ν + logu 2 logu = ν + σ T/n 2σ T/n = 1 2 + ν T 2σ n. And substituting this value of q, a bit more algebra shows us that as n, = x n T y = z nq nq1 q = x n 2 ν σ 2 T T n 2σ n 4 ν2 T 4σ 2 = ν T n nσ 2 ν 2 T = x n νt n nt σ 2 ν 2 T = 2 It follows by the central limit theorem that x n σ 2 T ν T n σ n ν2 T σ 2 x νt σ 2 T ν 2 T 2 /n x νt σ T. lim P n log n/ x = lim Bz, n, q = N y; 0, 1 = N x; νt, n σ2 T. Regarding notation: we have seen that logn/ converges to a normal under many probability measures q. Moreover, these normals share a common variance σ 2 T ; they are therefore fully characterized by the parameter ν. We have consistenly adopted the notation E q to denote expectation of a discrete process under the Bernoulli measure with parameter q. We will use E ν to denote expectation of a continuous process under the normal measure with paramter ν derived by the limiting behavior of a discrete process under q. Before moving on, we digress to mae an historical observation. Cox, Ross, and Rubenstein initially chose their u and d parameters with the intent of fitting their model to the empirical process of underlying asset returns. This is unnecessary; any choices of u, d and ris neutral measure satisfying no-arbitrage constraints are admissable. But their choice gives us an interpretation of σ. If we assume that asset returns are distributed lie log N µ, σ 2, then by the preceeding proposition, σ is the volatility of the underlying asset. Although evidence shows that asset returns are not log-normal, we may interpret σ as a crude estimate of volatility. Proposition 5.1. The discount factor r n n 5. The Blac-choles Formula is constant in n; in particular r n n = e T log r. Proof. Let n y denote the number of periods in a year. Then by definition we have r n = r 1/ny where r is the n-period return. Recalling that T is the time in years to expiry of the option, T = n/n y, 1 = r n/ny = r T = e T log r. r n n

6 JOHN THICKTUN This is clearly constant as n varies. Proposition 5.2. Under the ris-neutral measure π, ] E ν [log = log r σ2 2 T. Proof. By definition of the binomial model, [ ] E π = πu + 1 πd. 1 And because n is independent of, n n E π n/ = E π / 1 = E π [ / 1 ] = πu + 1 πd n. =1 =1 Therefore by definition of π and proposition 5.1, E π [ n/] = r n n = e T log r. And so we have log E π [n/] = T log r. By continuity, and proposition 4.1 respectively, T log r = lim log E π[ n n/] = log lim E π[ n n/] = log E ν [ /]. And because / is lognormally distributed proposition 4.2 by proposition B.1 log E ν / = E ν [log /] + 1 2 Var ν[log /]. It follows that E ν [log /] = T log r σ2 T 2. Proposition 5.3. Under the measure π = u/r n π, [ ] E ν log = log r + σ2 2 Proof. By definition of π, π = u rn d. r n u d Rearranging this equation shows us that T. r n = [1/uπ + 1/d1 π ] 1. And therefore we have r T = [1/uπ + 1/d1 π ] n. Now running our model in reverse, note that E π [ 1 / ] = 1/uπ + 1/d1 π.

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING AND BLACK-CHOLE 7 We setch the remaining details of the proof, which is quite similar to the proof for π given above: log E ν [/ ] = lim n log E π [/ n] = logr T = T log r. The inverse of a lognormal distribution is lognormal, so we have T log r = E ν [log / ] + 1 2 Var ν [log/ ] And we see that E ν [log /] = T log r + σ2 T 2. Proposition 5.4. Let a = min P > 0 and a = d p np1 p np. Then lim d p = 1 [ ] n σ log + E p log. T K Proof. By proposition 3.1, a = Therefore by our definition of d p, we have And with some algebra, we see that logk/ n log d logu/d + ζ. d p np1 p np = log/k + n log d logu/d ζ. log/k + log d + p logu/dn d p = logu/d ζ. np1 p np1 p ubstituting the values of the mean and variance of the binomial process we have [ ] log n log K + E p d p = td p [log n ] ζ np1 p. By proposition 3.1, 0 < ζ < 1. Therefore the second term above vanishes as n. By proposition 4.1 we may substitute the variance σ 2 T leaving us with lim d p = 1 [ ] n σ log + lim T K E p log n n [ Theorem 5.5 Blac-choles. Let d 1,2 = 1 σ log ] T K + log r ± σ2 2 T. Then C = N d 1 Ke logrt N d 2.

8 JOHN THICKTUN Proof. By proposition 3.2, we have C = B a; n, π Krn n B a; n, π. Taing the limit as n, C = lim B a; n, n π K lim n r n n lim B a; n, π. n = N d 1 Ke logrt N d 2. The limiting expressions are replaced via propositions A.2 and 5.1. The values of d 1 and d 2 are obtained via proposition 5.5. Appendix A. Log-normal tatistics Proposition A.1. Let X log N µ, σ 2. Then Proof. By definition, X = e Y subsequent algebra, = e µ E[X] = E[e Y ] = = E[X] = e µ+σ/2. where Y N µ, σ 2. Then by the expectation rule and e y 1 2πσ 2 e y µ2 /2σ 2 dy e u+µ 1 2πσ 2 e u2 /2σ 2 du 1 e 2σ2 u u 2 2σ 2 du = e µ 2πσ 2 = e µ+σ2 /2 1 e u σ2 2 +σ 4 2σ 2 du 2πσ 2 1 2πσ 2 e u σ2 2 2σ 2 du = e µ+σ2 /2. The last equality follows because the integral is taen over a normal density and therefore must integrate to 1; this can be proved directly by the polar coordinates method of Gauss. Appendix B. Binomial tatistics Proposition B.1. Let be binomially distributed with parameters n and p. Then Proof. Let q = 1 p. Then E[] = P r = = np =1 =1 =1 E[] = np. p q n = 1 n p q n 1 =1 1 p 1 q 1 = np p q 1 =0 = npp + q = np.

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING AND BLACK-CHOLE 9 The last reduction is attained by applying the binomial theorem noting that p + q = 1. Alternatively, we may interpret the last sum as summing over the probabilities of a binomial distribution with parameters and p, which must of course sum to 1. Proposition B.2. Let be binomially distributed with parameters n and p. Then Proof. Let q = 1 p. Then = Var[] = E[ 2 ] E[] 2 = Var[] = np1 p. 2 P r np 2 = =1 1 n p q n np 2 = np 1 =1 = np = np =0 = np + 1 =0 2 p q n np 2 =1 1 p 1 q 1 np 2 1 =1 p q np 2 p q + p q np 2 =0 n 2 p q + p q np 2 1 =1 n 2 = np p p 1 q n 2 1 + p q np 2 1 =1 n 2 = np p p 1 q n 2 1 + p q np 2. 1 =1 =0 =0 =0 = np pp + q n 2 + p + q np 2 = npnp + 1 p np 2 = np1 p.

10 JOHN THICKTUN Appendix C. Properties of the CRR parameters Lemma C.1. If p is the physical measure, π is the ris-neutral measure, and π = u/r n π, lim p = lim π = lim n n n π = 1 2 Proof. Recall from proposition 4.1 that p = 1 2 + µ T 2σ n. From this is clearly follows that p 1/2 as n. By definitions and proposition 5.1, T/n π = r n d u d = e T/n log r e σ e σt/n e σ. T/n Clearly both the numerator and denominator vanish as n. Therefore by l Hôpital, lim π = lim d e T/n log r e σ T/n n n dn e σt/n e σ. T/n Taing derivatives with respect to continuous n gives us d dn eσ T/n = σ T e σ T/n 2n 3/2. And with a bit of algebra we have π = 2T logre T/n log r / n + σ T e σ T/n σ T e σ T/n + σ T e σ T/n The first term in the numerator goes to zero and therefore we have lim π = lim σ T e σ T/n n n σ T e σt/n + σ T e σ = 1 T/n 2. Finally, by continuity we observe that u lim = lim n r eσ T/n e T/n log r = lim eσ T/n+T/n log r = 1. n n n It follows that π 1/2 as n.

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING AND BLACK-CHOLE 11 References [1] Cox, John C., tephen A. Ross, and Mar Rubinstein, Option pricing: A simplified approach. Journal of financial Economics 7.3 1979: 229-263. [2] Timothy Kevin Kuria Kamanu, Continuous time limit of the Binomial Model. http://users.aims.ac. za/~mmbele/tim_essay.pdf [3] Don M. Chance Convergence of the Binomial Model to the Blac-choles Model. http://www.bus.lsu. edu/academics/finance/faculty/dchance/instructional/tn00-08.pdf [4] teven R. Dunbar The de Moivre-Laplace Central Limit Theorem http://www.math. unl.edu/~sdunbar1/probabilitytheory/lessons/bernoullitrials/demoivrelaplaceclt/ demoivrelaplaceclt.pdf [5] Don M. Chance A ynthesis of Binomial Option Pricing Models for Lognormally Distributed Assets Available at RN 969834 2007 [6] Leisen, Dietmar PJ, and Matthias Reimer. Binomial models for option valuation-examining and improving convergence. Applied Mathematical Finance 3.4 1996: 319-346.