Determination of Market Clearing Price in Pool Markets with Elastic Demand

Similar documents
A Fast Procedure for Transmission Loss Allocation of Power Systems by Using DC-OPF

ASSESSMENT OF TRANSMISSION CONGESTION IMPACTS ON ELECTRICITY MARKETS

Pricing Transmission

Stepping Through Co-Optimisation

Optimal Bidding Strategies in Electricity Markets*

Economic Dispatch. Quantitative Energy Economics. Anthony Papavasiliou 1 / 21

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Transmission congestion management effects on reducing cost of bilateral market and increasing traders profits

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

AGENERATION company s (Genco s) objective, in a competitive

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Problem set Fall 2012.

Financial Transmission Rights Markets: An Overview

This appendix discusses two extensions of the cost concepts developed in Chapter 10.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Design of a Transmission Rights Exchange

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Intro to Economic analysis

International Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics

BRIDGE REHABILITATION PROGRAM WITH ROUTE CHOICE CONSIDERATION

Electricity market reform to enhance the energy and reserve pricing mechanism: Observations from PJM

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Hedging Risk. Quantitative Energy Economics. Anthony Papavasiliou 1 / 47

Firm s Problem. Simon Board. This Version: September 20, 2009 First Version: December, 2009.

Chapter 7 A Multi-Market Approach to Multi-User Allocation

This section addresses the specific timeline, format and mechanics for a base auction

H. Raouf Sheybani* and M. Oloomi Buygi**

Solutions to Midterm Exam. ECON Financial Economics Boston College, Department of Economics Spring Tuesday, March 19, 10:30-11:45am

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Solution Guide to Exercises for Chapter 4 Decision making under uncertainty

A Tutorial on the Flowgates versus Nodal Pricing Debate. Fernando L. Alvarado Shmuel S. Oren PSERC IAB Meeting Tutorial November 30, 2000

Posting Date: 08/01/2015 Gentry Crowson, Market Forensics

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

Bounding the Composite Value at Risk for Energy Service Company Operation with DEnv, an Interval-Based Algorithm

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

THE operators of power transmission networks are

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions

GPD-POT and GEV block maxima

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Market Design. Econ University of Notre Dame

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Tutorial 4 - Pigouvian Taxes and Pollution Permits II. Corrections

CEMARE Research Paper 167. Fishery share systems and ITQ markets: who should pay for quota? A Hatcher CEMARE

A MATHEMATICAL PROGRAMMING APPROACH TO ANALYZE THE ACTIVITY-BASED COSTING PRODUCT-MIX DECISION WITH CAPACITY EXPANSIONS

Scarcity Pricing Market Design Considerations

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Section 2 Solutions. Econ 50 - Stanford University - Winter Quarter 2015/16. January 22, Solve the following utility maximization problem:

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

CHAPTER 2: Optimal Decisions Using Marginal Analysis MULTIPLE CHOICE

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

Consumers cannot afford all the goods and services they desire. Consumers are limited by their income and the prices of goods.

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

1 The Solow Growth Model

ECON Micro Foundations

Integer Programming Models

LOSS AND CONSTRAINT EXCESS PAYMENT

Reuben Gronau s Model of Time Allocation and Home Production

Generation Production Costs, Scheduling & Operating Rate

Inter-Session Network Coding with Strategic Users: A Game-Theoretic Analysis of Network Coding

Price Regulations in a Multi-unit Uniform Price Auction

Exercise 1. Jan Abrell Centre for Energy Policy and Economics (CEPE) D-MTEC, ETH Zurich. Exercise

Cross-border exchange and sharing of generation reserve capacity

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Locational Marginal Pricing

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Table of Contents List of Figures...3 List of Tables...3 Definitions and Abbreviations...4 Introduction...7

True_ The Lagrangian method is one way to solve constrained maximization problems.

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

Economics 386-A1. Practice Assignment 3. S Landon Fall 2003

Valuation of Transmission Assets and Projects. Transmission Investment: Opportunities in Asset Sales, Recapitalization and Enhancements

Evaluating Electricity Generation, Energy Options, and Complex Networks

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

and, we have z=1.5x. Substituting in the constraint leads to, x=7.38 and z=11.07.

Intermediate Microeconomics

Value-at-Risk Based Portfolio Management in Electric Power Sector

Bank Leverage and Social Welfare

5.2 Transmission Congestion Credit Calculation Eligibility.

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2 Solutions

Comparative Study between Linear and Graphical Methods in Solving Optimization Problems

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Locational Marginal Pricing

Yale ICF Working Paper No First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, Safety First Portfolio Insurance

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY LECTURE 12: THE DERIVATION OF THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE

Crediting Wind and Solar Renewables in Electricity Capacity Markets: The Effects of Alternative Definitions upon Market Efficiency. The Energy Journal

Transcription:

Determination of Market Clearing Price in Pool Markets with Elastic Demand ijuna Kunju K and P S Nagendra Rao Department of Electrical Engineering Indian Institute of Science, angalore 560012 kbijuna@gmail.com, nagendra@ee.iisc.ernet.in Department of Electrical and Electronics Engg T.K.M.College of Engineering, Kollam 691005 Abstract Determination of Market Clearing Price is one of the prime functions of a pool operator. In many of the existing markets, market clearing is based on stepped bids received from generators and consumers. However, quadratic bid functions have more information and are more realistic. A simple closed form solution scheme to compute the clearing price from such supply and offer bids submitted to the operator is proposed in this paper. I. INTRODUCTION The most popular form of electricity market so far has been the centralized auction, which has often mimicked the procedures used for central dispatch in the past, reflecting concerns over system security [1], [2], [3]. After the auction, some pool-based electricity markets operate under a systemwide market price [3] while others have elected the approach of nodal (or locational) marginal prices [4]. The bids supplied by the generators/generating companies indicate the quantity of power they are ready to supply at a certain price in terms of a price function [1], [2]. In many pool markets, the consumers also submit offers in terms of quantity of power required and a price function (at which they are prepared to purchase) [5]. In the single-price auction, the market-clearing price is determined by a merit order algorithm [6]: a wellestablished technique where all participating generators bids are ordered according to increasing levels while participating consumers bids are ranked according to decreasing levels. The market clearing price is then defined by the intersection of the aggregate demand and supply curves. This method has the advantage that it is very simple to implement. With this process the total demand that can be met and the individual generations accepted/ loads supplied can be decided fairly easily. The stepped bids in use are approximations of the true cost function of the generating units. A basic requirement for the success of market dictated utility operation is that the bids must reflect the true costs of operation. Hence, it is easy to see that use of quadratic functions to represent the cost of generation would provide a better representation of the true cost of generation. It may also be noted that the use of quadratic functions to represent the cost of generation has been in use in power systems for a long time now. Hence, continuing to use this form of cost functions (bid functions) should be more acceptable to the industry rather than adopting the step form of cost functions. A similar argument holds good for the bids of loads also. It must be pointed out that there has been a considerable body of research which attempts to forecast the MCP [7], [8], [9], [10]. Such forecasts are meant to be used by the bidders in order to tune their bids to maximize their individual profits. Techniques based on artificial intelligence and probability theory have been proposed for this purpose. It is easy to see that such techniques are obviously not intended to maximize the societal benefit and hence, cannot be expected to achieve the desired goals of restructured markets. The aim of this paper is to develop a method for determining the market clearing price in the case of pool markets under the assumption of no congestion. In this development, it is considered that generator bid functions and the load valuation functions are quadratic functions of real power. The maximum and minimum limits on both individual generations and loads are also accounted in this process. The proposed method has been developed by extending an earlier method [11], meant for determining the generation schedules in vertically integrated power systems. However the method in [11] does not consider the bids of consumers and it also requires the total demand to be specified. In this approach, a formula is developed in Section II to find the clearing price where the generator and load bids are quadratic functions of real power. It is then shown how this formula can be used in a systematic way to handle the limits on loads and generators and arrive at the final schedule. A detailed illustration of the algorithm is given in Section III and the paper is concluded in the next Section. In Section III, methods of handling generators bids and consumers offerswith and without limits, fixed demands (block bids) and their combinations are illustrated. II. A FORMULA FOR MARKET CLEARING PRICE Consider a system with N generators and M consumers. Let the generator bid function for the i th generator be C i (Pg i )=a i Pg 2 i + b i Pg i + c i and the consumer benefit function for the j th load be f j (Pd j )=α j Pd 2 j + β j Pd j + γ j 214

The objective of the pool market operator is to maximise the social welfare function f j (Pd j ) C i (Pg i ) subject to the power balance constraint, (Pg i )= (Pd j ) (1) Hence, the augmented objective function for unconstrained optimisation is L = C i (Pg i ) f j (Pd j ) λ( (Pg i ) (Pd j )) where λ is the Lagrangian multiplier. The conditions for optimality of L are given by dl dλ = dc i =0 i (2) dp g i and dl dλ = df j =0 j (3) dp d j Equations (2)and (3) imply that for optimality, the incremental cost functions of all the generation as well as the incremental utility function of all loads must be equal to λ. The incremental cost for generators can also be written as dc i = λ =2a i Pg i + b i, i N (4) dp g i At the optimum, the incremental costs of all generators are same and we have, 2a i Pg i +b i =2a k Pg k +b k = λ i N,for a particular k N (5) Pg i = 2a kpg k + b k b i, i N (6) 2a i Let the total demand (total generation) given by (1) be equal to P R. Therefore, (Pg i )= 2a k Pg k + b k b i 2a i = P R (7) N 2a k Pg k ( 1 N )+b k ( 1 ) ( b i )=2P R. (8) a i a i a i Define two parameters A and, and and (8) can be written as A = = ( 1 ) (9) a i ( b i a i ). (10) (2a k Pg k + b k )A =2P R + (11) where (2a k Pg k + b k )=λ Hence the value of λ is obtained as λ = 2P R + A Similarly, with the demand offers, it can be shown that where, A d = d = (12) λ = 2P R + d A d (13) ( 1 ) (14) α i Solving (12) and (13), we have ( β i α i ) (15) P R = A d A d 2(A d A) λ = ( d) (A A d ) (16) (17) The schedules for each of the generators and the demand of each consumer that can be met is obtained as, Pg i = λ b i 2a i i (18) Pd i = λ β i 2α i i (19) A. Incorporating the Limits The formula in (17) for the market clearing price is valid only if the corresponding generators and loads given by (18) and (19) are within their limits. However, this may not always happen. If at any stage of calculation of the system λ using (17), the corresponding schedule results in limit violations, then the violating loads / generations must be constrained at the limits that they are violating and the net difference between such allocated loads and generations has to be first optimally allocated among the non violating generators / loads. For this step also, the formula derived above is made use of. After this step, the cost functions of the non violating generators / loads are modified to reflect the partial allocation of load / generation that has been done to the particular entity. The process of finding the system market clearing price is continued considering only the non violating generators / loads and the modified incremental cost functions of these generators and loads. 215

III. ILLUSTRATION OF THE METHOD Consider a system consisting of three generators and two consumers with variable demands. The generator cost functions of the three units as given in [11] are, C 1 =0.003Pg 2 1 +2Pg 1 +80 C 2 =0.015Pg 2 2 +1.45Pg 2 + 100 C 3 =0.01Pg 2 3 +0.95Pg 3 + 120 The offer functions of the two consumers are, Rs/h, Rs/h, Rs/h. f 1 = 0.002Pd 2 1 +5Pd 1 + 150 Rs/h, f 2 = 0.001Pd 2 2 +6Pd 2 + 200 Rs/h. A. Case 1: No Limit Constraints For this system the values of A,, A d and d are calculated using (9), (10), (14) and (15)as A = 1 0.003 + 1 0.015 + 1 0.01 = 500 = 2 0.003 + 1.45 0.015 + 0.95 0.01 = 858.33 A d = 1 0.002 + 1 0.001 = 1500 5 d = 0.002 + 6 0.001 = 8500 Now, the total demand that can be supplied is obtained using (16) as (500 8500) ( 1500 858.33) P R = = 740.63MW. 2( 1500 500) The Market Clearing Price is obtained using (12) or (13) as λ = 2 740.63 + 858.33 500 =4.6792 Rs/MW Or 2 740.63 8500 λ = =4.6792 Rs/MW 1500 The schedules are then found using (18) and (19)as Pg 1 = 4.679 2 2 0.003 = 446.5MW Pg 3 = 4.679 1.45 5 4.679 0.95 = 107.64MW = 186.46MW Pd 1 = 4.679 5 2 0.002 =80.2MW Pd 2 = 4.679 6 2 0.001 = 660.4MW. Case 2: Maximum Limit on Generator Output In addition to the conditions in case 1, suppose that generator 1 has a maximum limit of 400 MW. Hence, the generation of this unit must be constrained to 400 MW, instead of 446.5 MW calculated above. In addition, this generation has to be allocated optimally among the customers. Pgx 1 = 400MW. The corresponding λ int is computed (13) using the values of A d and d obtained earlier 2 400 8500 λ int = =5.1333 Rs/MW 1500 The allocation of 400 MW among the loads would be corresponding to this λ int of 5.1333. This value turn out to be Pd 1 = 5.133 5 = 33.3 MW 2 0.002 Pd 2 = 5.133 6 = 433.3 MW 2 0.001 The negative value implies the violation of minimum limit for Pd 1. So, the full 400 MW is allocated to Pd 2.Now,the remaining generators (No. 2 and No. 3) and demand bids are to be used in the next stage. However, the incremental cost function of Pd 2 is to be changed to 2α 2 Pd 2 + β 2 to account for the allocation of 400 MW and the modified value of β is obtained as β 2 =2 α 2 Pd 2 + β 2 β 2 =2 0.001 400 + 6 = 5.2 With this procedure for accounting of the allocated component of this demand, the slope of the incremental cost function of Pd 2 does not change, only the constant value changes. So, for further scheduling, only the value of d will change to d (A d will remain the same). d 5 = 0.002 + 5.2 0.001 = 7700 Since, the set of available generators has changed, the values of A and (9,10) are to be recalculated and the new values are A = 1 0.015 + 1 0.01 = 166.67 = 1.45 0.015 + 0.95 0.01 = 191.67 From the new set, the demand that can be supplied is found out as (166.67 7700) ( 1500 191.67) P Rn = = 298.7501MW 2( 1500 166.67) The new system λ being 2 298.7501 + 191.67 λ = =4.7350 Rs/MW 166.67 The individual shares of the loads and generations are calculated using (18,19) and the schedules are 4.7350 1.45 5 = 109.5 MW 216

4.7350 0.95 Pg 3 = = 189.25 MW Pd 1 = 4.7350 5 =66.25 MW 2 0.002 4.7350 5.2 Pd 2 = = 232.5 MW 2 0.001 The final schedules for the three generators are 400.0, 109.5 and 189.25 MW respectively. The values for the two final demands are 66.25 and 632.5 MW (i.e.400mw+232.5mw) respectively. The Market Clearing Price is 4.735 Rs/MW. Since the generator with a lower cost has been constrained at its maximum limit, the total demand supplied reduces from a possible 740.63 MW level to 698.75 MW while the clearing price shows a rise from 4.6792 to 4.735 Rs/MW. It is not difficult to see that the solution obtained by this method satisfies the Kuhn Tucker conditions also. The optimal incremental cost for the total system is 4.735 Rs/MW where as the incremental cost of the generator constrained at its maximum limit is λ 1 =2 0.003 400 + 2 = 4.4 Rs/MW C. Case 3: Maximum Limit on Load Consider that the schedule is as in case 1, and suppose that, in addition, there is a maximum limit on the load at node 2 (specified) of 600MW. This implies a constraint violation. Hence, first this load (600MW) is to be optimally allocated between generators. An intermediate value of λ for allocating this 600MW among the generators is found using (12) as λ int = 2 Prn+ A = 2 600 + 858.3333 500 and the corresponding allocation are Pg 1 = 4.1167 2 2 0.003 = 352.76MW 4.1167 1.45 5 =88.6667MW =4.1167 Rs/MW 4.1167 0.95 Pg 3 = = 158.3333MW Now, the incremental cost functions of the generators have to be modified to reflect this allocation. The slope a i of all the generators remain unchanged, and it is easy to see that b i of all the generators must be now taken as 4.1167. Now for the next stage of optimisation, the value of need to be calculated again and is denoted as. = 4.1167 0.003 + 4.1167 0.015 + 4.1167 0.01 = 2058.35 Now, the demand has to be met is of consumer 1. The new values of A d and d corresponding to this situation are A d = 1 0.002 = 500 d = 5 0.002 = 2500 The additional demand that can be met is P R (500 2500) ( 500 2058.35) = = 110.4125 MW 2( 500 500) This turns out to be the demand of consumer 1 Pd 1 = 110.4125 MW. The new clearing price is obtained using (16) as 2 110.4125 + 2058.35 λ = =4.5584 Rs/MW 500 Or 2 110.4125 2500 λ = =4.5584 Rs/MW 500 The contribution of the three generators towards this additional load are Pg 1 =73.61MW 14.72MW Pg 3 =22.08MW Hence, the final schedules for the three generators are 426.377 (352.76 + 73.61), 103.3867 (88.6667+14.72) and 180.4133 (158.333 + 22.08) MW respectively. The two demands are 110.4125 and 600.0 MW. The Market Clearing Price is 4.5584 Rs/MW. Here since the demand with a higher valuation is constrained at the maximum limit, the total demand met gets reduced from 740.63 MW to 710.4125 MW while the clearing price decreases from 4.735 to 4.5584 Rs/MW. D. Case 4: Maximum Limits on oth Generators and Consumer Loads Here, we consider both the constraints to be operative simultaneously. The generation 1 has a maximum limit of 400 MW and the maximum demand of consumer 2 is 600 MW. From the optimal schedule of case 1 it is seen that both limits are violated. So Pg 1 is fixed at 400 MW and Pd 2 is fixed at 600 MW. The difference of these two values is 200 MW of demand. This demand is optimally distributed among the two generators not set at their limits as follows. The intermediate value of λ is obtained using values of A and already calculated in (Case 2) as 166.67 and 191.67 respectively. λ int = 2 Pr + 2 200 + 191.67 A = =3.55Rs/MW 166.67 and the corresponding allocation to the two generators are 3.55 1.45 5 =70MW 3.55 0.95 Pg 3 = = 130MW The incremental cost function of the two generators now have to be modified such that they have the same value of b i equal to 3.55 with their a i values remaining unchanged. So, the value of is calculated again as = 3.55 0.015 + 3.55 0.01 = 591.67 217

Now, the demand that is to be met is only that of consumer 1. Hence, the new value of A d and d are A d = 500 d = 2500 Hence, the additional load that can be met is P R (166.67 2500) ( 500 591.67) = =90.625 MW 2( 500 166.67) Therefore, the demand of consumer 1 is also 90.625 MW. Pd 1 =90.625 MW. The new clearing price is 2 90.625 + 591.67 λ = =4.6375 Rs/MW 166.67 Or 2 90.625 2500 λ = =4.6375 Rs/MW 500 The contribution of the two generators towards this load is 4.6375 3.55 =36.25 MW 5 4.6375 3.55 Pg 3 = =54.375 MW The final schedules are generations 400.0, 106.25 and 184.375 MW respectively. The final demands are 90.625 and 600.0 MW. The Market Clearing Price is 4.6375 Rs/MW. E. Case 5: Mixed Load - (No Limit violation) This example is provided to illustrate the method when the system has both fixed loads and price sensitive loads. The 30 bus system is used for this illustration. The bids and offers details of the 30 bus system used here is given Tab. I. There are loads which do not submit offer function implying that they are ready to accept power at any cost. In this system the total fixed demand by those consumers is 75.4 MW. TALE I THE IDS OF 30 US SYSTEM Gen No. a i b i Dem No. α i β i 1 0.02 2.00 2-0.02 6.0 2 0.0175 1.75 7-0.02 4.4 22 0.0625 1.00 8-0.02 4.8 27 0.0083 3.25 12-0.02 4.2 23 0.025 3.00 21-0.02 4.8 13 0.025 3.00 30-0.02 4.0 The value of A for the set of supply bids is 323.6248 and is 847.5662. The corresponding values for demand bids are A d is 300 and d is 1410. In the first step, the fixed demand is allocated to the generators. Considering all the six available generators share the demand, the value of λ int is first calculated λ int = 2 Pr + A 2 75.4 + 323.6248 = =2.928Rs/MW 847.5663 It is clear that for three generators, 13, 23 and 27 their b i value is greater than this λ int and hence their output is set to zero. The values of A and are then recalculated with three generators only. The new values are A = 123.1429 and = 216. λ int = 2 Pr + A = 2 75.4 + 216 123.1429 =2.9787Rs/MW This value of λ int is still lesser than the b i of the generators at 13, 23 and 27 and their output has been correctly allocated to be zero. Using this λ int we get, Pg 1 =24.4675MW Pg 2 =35.1057MW Pg 22 =15.8296MW The incremental cost function of these three generators now have to be modified such that they have the same value of b i as 2.9787 with their a i values remaining unchanged. So, the value of is calculated again as = 2.9787 0.02 + 2.9787 0.0175 + 2.9787 0.0625 + 3.25 0.0083 + 3 0.025 + 3 0.025 = 998.3719 The total demand of the nodes with price dependent loads is then determined by (16) P R = (323.624 1410) ( 300 998.3719) 2( 300 323.624) The new clearing price is found by (17) λ =3.862Rs/MW = 125.72MW. The individual share of generations and loads are then found from the clearing price by substituting in (18,19) TALE II THE SCHEDULES OTAINED FOR 30 US SYSTEM Gen No. Pg i Pg i Pg final i Dem No. Pd i 1 24.47 22.11 46.58 2 53.45 2 35.10 25.27 60.37 7 13.45 22 15.83 7.10 22.93 8 23.45 27 0.0000 36.74 36.74 12 8.45 23 0.0000 17.25 17.25 21 23.46 13 0.0000 17.25 17.25 30 3.46 Gen. 75.4 125.72 201.12 Var.Dem. 125.72 F. Case 6: Mixed Load with Limit Violation Consider the system as in case 5, and suppose that in addition there is a maximum limit of 50 MW on the demand of consumer 2, Pd max 2 =50MW. The steps of Case 5 are repeated until its last stage, where it is seen that the load assigned to consumer 2 is greater than its maximum value. Hence the demand of consumer 1 is fixedto50mw,pd 2 = 50MW.Afterthefixed demand allocation, this demand is allocated. So the values of A and are taken considering all six generators (323.6248 and 998.3719 respectively). Now, this demand is distributed optimally among the generators as demonstrated earlier. The intermediate λ considering all six 218

generators, for this load of 50 MW turned out to be 3.3940 Rs/MW. λ int = 2 Pr + A 2 50 + 323.6248 = =3.394Rs/MW 998.3718 The schedules of generators are Pg 1 =10.3825MW, Pg 2 =11.8657MW Pg 22 =3.3224MW, Pg 27 =8.6403MW Pg 23 =7.88MW, Pg 13 =7.88MW The next step of scheduling requires the modified cost function for all the generators. The value of b i of all generators is now 3.394. The values of A,, A d and d for the new set of available demands and generators and with the modified cost functions are 323.6248, 1098.4, -250 and -1110. The value of λ obtained is 3.8499 Rs/MW and the additional demand is 73.762 MW. There is no additional constraint violation and so the schedule is final. The generations and demands met are λ =3.8499Rs/MW, Pg 1 =46.288MW, Pg 22 =22.7996MW, Pg 23 =17.000MW, Pd 2 =50.00MW, P R = 199.1MW 59.9985MW Pg 27 =36.0082MW Pg 13 =17.000MW Pd 7 =13.725MW REFERENCES [1] S. Stoft, Power System Economics: Designing Markets For Electricity. IEEE Press:John Wiley and Sons, 2002. [2] M. Ilic, F. Galiana, and L. Fink, Power System Restructuring: Engineering and Economics. Dordrecht: Kluwer, 1998. [3] F. A. Wolak and R. H. Patrick, The impact of market rules and market structure on the price determination process in the england & wales electricity market, University California Energy Institute,erkeley,POWER Reports, Tech. Rep. PWP-047, April 1997. [4] PJM, PJM Interconnection, PJM Manual 11 : Scheduling Operations, Revision 21. http://www.pjm.com/contributions/pjmmanuals/pdf/m11v21.pdf, January 31, 2004. [5] R. D. Christie,. F. Woolenberg, and I. Wangensteen, Transmission management in the deregulated environment, Proceedings of the IEEE, vol. 88, no. 2, pp. 170 195, February 2000. [6] N. Fabra, N. H. von der Fehr, and D. Harbord, Modelling electricity auctions, The Electricity Journal, Elsevier Science Inc., pp. 72 81, August/September 2002. [7] Y. S. C. Yuen, Experience in day-ahead market price forecasting, in 6th lnternarional Conference on Adrances in Power System Control, Operation and Management, APSCOM 2003, Hong Kong, November 2003, pp. 123 128. [8] E. Ni and P.. Luh, Experience in day-ahead market price forecasting, in IEEE Power Engineering Society Winter Meeting, vol. 3, January/February 2001, pp. 1518 1523. [9] F. J. Nogales, J. Contreras, A. J. Conejo, and R. Espinola, Forecasting next-day electricity prices by time series models, IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 17, no. 2, pp. 342 348, May 2002. [10] C.-Y. Hsiao and Y.-Y. Hong, Locational marginal price forecasting in deregulated electricity markets using artificial intelligence, IEE Proceedings- Generation,Transmission & Distribution, vol. 149, no. 5, pp. 621 626, September 2002. [11] P. S. N. Rao, Direct method of determining optimum generation schedules, Institution of Engineers (India) Journal- Electrical, vol. 67, pp. 251 253, June 1987. Pd 8 =23.7525MW, Pd 12 =8.7525MW Pd 21 =23.7525MW, Pd 30 =3.7525MW. The demand with high valuation is limited in quantity and hence the system incremental price reduces as compared with the previous case. In this case, the fixed demand can be considered as a block bid with infinite offer. The offer can have a format of specified quantity of power at a specified price also. However, in such a case, the fixed demand will be supplied only when the system incremental cost is same as the offer price of the demand (not the first demand to be supplied as done in this case). IV. CONCLUDING REMARKS A method of determining the Market Clearing Price and the schedules based on the bids submitted by the consumers and generators has been proposed in this paper. The bids are assumed to be quadratic functions of real power instead of the stepped bids currently in use. A close form solution (formula) for determining the system λ based on bids has been developed. It is shown that this formula can be used in a systematic way when limits on the generation/loads have to be accounted. The algorithm is simple and give the global optimal solution for this problem. The method can be used to find the market schedules when network constraints need not be considered; such results are also useful in assessing the impact of network constraints on the market schedules and prices. 219