Outsourcing of Mutual Funds Non-core Competencies

Similar documents
CFR Working Paper NO Knowledge Spillovers in the Mutual Fund Industry through Labor Mobility. G. Cici A. Kempf C.

Fund Manager Duality: Impact on Performance and Investment Behavior

An Assessment of Managerial Skill based on Cross-Sectional Mutual Fund Performance

Are Financial Advisors Useful? Evidence from Tax-Motivated Mutual Fund Flows

Outsourcing vs. Integration in the Mutual Fund Industry The Puzzle of Lower Returns

Portfolio Manager Ownership and Fund Performance

Does portfolio manager ownership affect fund performance? Finnish evidence

Mutual Fund Performance and Flows: The Effects of Liquidity Service Provision and Active Management

Supplementary Appendix for Outsourcing Mutual Fund Management: Firm Boundaries, Incentives and Performance

Foreign focused mutual funds and exchange traded funds: Do they improve portfolio management?

Industry Concentration and Mutual Fund Performance

Risk Taking and Performance of Bond Mutual Funds

Institutional Money Manager Mutual Funds *

Sentimental Mutual Fund Flows

Investor Flows and Fragility in Corporate Bond Funds. Itay Goldstein, Wharton Hao Jiang, Michigan State David Ng, Cornell

Historical Performance and characteristic of Mutual Fund

Is a Team Different From the Sum of Its Parts? Evidence from Mutual Fund Managers

Common Holdings in Mutual Fund Family

Governance in the U.S. Mutual Fund Industry

Mutual Fund Size versus Fees: When big boys become bad boys

The Use of ETFs by Actively Managed Mutual Funds *

Diseconomies of Scope and Mutual Fund Manager Performance. Richard Evans, Javier Gil-Bazo and Marc Lipson*

Identifying Skilled Mutual Fund Managers by their Ability to Forecast Earnings

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Liquidity skewness premium

The ABCs of Mutual Funds: A Natural Experiment on Fund Flows and Performance

Performance-Chasing Behavior in Mutual Funds: New Evidence from Multi-Fund Managers

New Evidence on the Demand for Advice within Retirement Plans

Is Investor Rationality Time Varying? Evidence from the Mutual Fund Industry

Diseconomies of Scope and Mutual Fund Manager Performance. Richard Evans, Javier Gil-Bazo and Marc Lipson*

Monthly Holdings Data and the Selection of Superior Mutual Funds + Edwin J. Elton* Martin J. Gruber*

Does MAX Matter for Mutual Funds? *

Defined Contribution Pension Plans: Sticky or Discerning Money?

THE DETERMINANTS OF FLOWS INTO RETAIL INTERNATIONAL EQUITY FUNDS *

Do Better Educated Mutual Fund Managers Outperform Their Peers?

Does fund size erode mutual fund performance?

Do Investors Care about Risk? Evidence from Mutual Fund Flows

What Drives Market Share in the Mutual Fund Industry? *

Does Herding Behavior Reveal Skill? An Analysis of Mutual fund Performance

Are There Disadvantaged Clienteles in Mutual Funds? Evidence from German Mutual Fund Investors

Investor Attrition and Mergers in Mutual Funds

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW MUCH DOES SIZE ERODE MUTUAL FUND PERFORMANCE? A REGRESSION DISCONTINUITY APPROACH. Jonathan Reuter Eric Zitzewitz

Active Management in Real Estate Mutual Funds

Investors seeking access to the bond

Does corporate governance matter in fund management company: the case of china

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

The Role of Work Experience in the Effect of Education. on Mutual Fund Performance

Sector Fund Performance

The Financial Review. Tailored versus Mass Produced: Portfolio Managers Concurrently Managing Separately Managed Accounts and Mutual Funds

* Conflict of Interest: Magnus hosted me at SIFR this past week!

CFR-Working Paper NO

January 12, Abstract. We identify a team approach in which the asset management company assembles

Azi Ben-Rephael Indiana University

Liquidity, Liquidity Risk, and the Cross Section of Mutual Fund Returns. Andrew A. Lynch and Xuemin (Sterling) Yan * Abstract

How Much Does Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? A Regression Discontinuity Approach *

Mutual fund expense waivers. Jared DeLisle Huntsman School of Business Utah State University Logan, UT 84322

CFR Working Paper NO

Essays on Institutional Investors. Yang Chen

Agency Conflicts in Delegated Portfolio Management: Evidence from Namesake Mutual Funds

CFR Working Paper NO

Strategic Performance Allocation in Institutional Asset Management Firms: Behold the Power of Stars and Dominant Clients *

What They Did in their Previous Lives: The Investment Value of Mutual Fund Managers Experience outside the Financial Sector

The Smart Money Effect: Retail versus Institutional Mutual Funds

Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance: Analysis of Holdings Returns

Lottery Mutual Funds *

Securities Lending by Mutual Funds

Diversification and Mutual Fund Performance

DERIVATIVES, SHORT SELLING AND U.S. EQUITY AND BOND MUTUAL FUNDS. Current Version September 2014

Why Do Institutional Plan Sponsors Hire and Fire their Investment Managers?

Does Fund Size Matter?: An Analysis of Small and Large Bond Fund Performance

Top Management Turnover: An Examination of Portfolio Holdings and Fund Performance*

The Rise of Anonymous Teams in Fund Management

The role of brokers and financial advisors behind investments into load funds *

Controlling for Fixed Income Exposure in Portfolio Evaluation: Evidence from Hybrid Mutual Funds

Why Do Fund Families Release Underperforming Incubated Mutual Funds?

Determinants of flows into retail international equity funds

Does Investor Care about SEC Comment Letter? Evidence from Mutual Fund Industry

Human Capital and the Structure of the Mutual Fund Industry

Does Selectivity in Mutual Fund Trades Exploit Sentiment Timing?

An Empirical Examination of Mutual Fund Boards

The Predictability of Managerial Heterogeneities in Mutual Funds

Changing Career Incentives and Risk-Taking. in the Mutual Fund Industry

Do the Actively Managed Mutual Funds Exploit the Stock Market Mispricing?

Fund flows, manager change and performance persistence

Size Doesn t Matter: Diseconomies of Scale in the Mutual Fund Industry Revisited

The impact of options use on mutual fund performance

How to measure mutual fund performance: economic versus statistical relevance

The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information. Production, and Initial Public Offerings. December 7, 2016

The Geography of Mutual Funds: The Advantage of Distant Investors

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Short Selling and the Subsequent Performance of Initial Public Offerings

Does Team Management Reduce Operational Risk? Evidence from the Financial Services Industry *

Performance Attribution: Are Sector Fund Managers Superior Stock Selectors?

Mutual Fund Incubation *

The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts

Asset Management Within Commercial Banking Groups: International Evidence

Mutual Fund Performance and Governance Structure: The Role of Portfolio Managers and Boards of Directors

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

Style Dispersion and Mutual Fund Performance

The effect of holdings data frequency on conclusions about mutual fund management behavior. This version: October 8, 2009

Transcription:

Outsourcing of Mutual Funds Non-core Competencies Christoph Sorhage This Draft: September 2014 ABSTRACT I investigate the consequences for mutual funds operational outcomes when fund families focus their efforts on their core competency, i.e. portfolio management, by outsourcing noncore activities to external providers. Specifically, I find that funds of families that outsource shareholder services have about 32 percent lower service fees than funds of families that cater for investors service needs internally. Consistent with service outsourcing releasing tied resources that can be spent on families core business, funds with delegated shareholder services outperform their peers by up to 91 basis points. This underperformance increases up to 136 basis points when outsourced funds are compared with internally administered funds that are also capable but choose not to outsource. Furthermore, these inhouse administered funds exhibit 10 percentage points lower growth rates per year and are more short-lived by up to a fifth. However, fund families decision to team-manage funds can substantially reduce the negative performance consequences. JEL classification: G23; L22; L84 Keywords: Mutual funds; Portfolio management focus; Outsourcing; Shareholder services Sorhage is from Department of Finance and Centre for Financial Research (CFR), University of Cologne. Email: sorhage@wiso.uni-koeln.de. The author wishes to thank several individuals who provided helpful comments on an earlier draft of the paper including Sebastian Bethke, Laura Dahm, Stefan Jaspersen, Alexander Kempf, Florian Sonnenburg and seminar participants at CFR, University of Cologne.

In 2012 U.S.-registered investment companies managed approximately $14.7 trillion for about 94 million U.S. investors (Investment Company Institute (2013)). This importance triggered a large and growing academic debate on mutual fund managers skills and characteristics that enable fund managers to generate positive alpha returns for their investors. 1 This popularity comes as no surprise given that fund managers, or, more generally speaking, the portfolio management is almost by definition considered as a mutual fund company s core competency and thus its source of success. On the contrary, the organizational structure of a mutual fund family, which encompasses portfolio management as the core business, has caught considerable less attention in the literature. Yet, fund families resource expenditure on non-core activities determines the resources at the disposal of portfolio management and thus the subsequent impact on funds operations. In this paper, I analyze how mutual funds operational outcomes are affected when fund families put a stronger focus on their core competency, i.e. portfolio management, through outsourcing of their non-core activities to external providers. The organizational literature proposes a multitude of theories for make-or-buy decisions that essentially aims to show when a company is best advised to outsource part of its value chain. 2 For instance, sourcing services from external specialists can be preferable to inhouse solutions if the contractor renders the service at lower costs or clients reservation price increases because the service is provided by a prestigious, external contractor. Accordingly, firms can improve their market position by focusing their efforts on their actual core business 1 This string of the literature is too vast to cover here. For some recent findings on fund managers skills see, e.g., Chen, Jegadeesh, and Wermers (2000), Elton, Gruber, and Blake (2012) and Kacperczyk, Nieuwerburgh, and Veldkamp (2014) who analyze fund managers stock picking and timing abilities. Studies investigating manager characteristics and their relation to fund performance subsume, e.g., an influence of manager experience (Kempf, Manconi, and Spalt (2013)); manager tenure (Golec (1996) and Ding and Wermers (2012)); manager education (Chevalier and Ellison (1999) and Gottesman and Morey (2006)); or manager gender (Niessen-Ruenzi and Ruenzi (2013)). 2 For a review on firms suitability for make-or-buy decisions see, e.g., Lafontaine and Slade (2007). 1

while reducing resource consumption in non-core areas through outsourcing (Prahalad and Hamel (1990)). In this spirit, I assess the value creation of fund families core policy by investigating how outsourcing of funds shareholder services impacts on fund expenses and performance. Shareholder services are a suitable testing object of fund families core competency focus for two reasons: First, shareholder services encompass a vast range of investor services, e.g., shareholder communications, the creation and recordkeeping of shareholder accounts, the processing of investor purchasing or redemption orders and the transmission of dividends and distributions to investors. Therefore mutual funds can strongly reduce resource consumption in a non-core area in terms of time by delegating the execution of these services to external providers. 3,4 Second, shareholder services strongly matter for mutual fund families on a monetary basis. Gremillion (2005) describes shareholder services as the largest component of funds expenses after investment management. In particular, I find that each fund spends approximately $1.7 million per year on shareholder services which represent about 12 percent of their total expenses. Therefore, shareholder services indeed present a substantial potential for cost reductions through outsourcing, which in turn are resources in terms of money that can be spent on funds actual field of expertise. Taken together, mutual fund families that emphasize their core competency through the strategic outsourcing of shareholder services as non-core activity can release tied resources in terms of time and money that can be spend on funds portfolio management. Hence, I hypothesize that outsourcing of shareholder services has the following main consequences for mutual funds: First, funds that employ external service providers (hereafter, 3 Shareholder service providers are often labeled as Transfer Agent or Shareholder Servicing Agent. For ease of exposition I refer to them as service provider. 4 At the same time these shareholder services are highly standardized. Hence, outsourcing funds can avoid some of the major impediments that complicate make-or-buy decisions, for instance, the hold-up problem, i.e., components are built on exact specifications so that sourcing firms are exposed to a lack of alternatives and thus diminished bargaining power in contract negotiations (see, e.g., Grossman and Helpman (2002)). 2

service-outsourced funds) exhibit lower service fees than funds that cater for investors service needs internally (hereafter, service-inhouse funds) because external providers very own competitive advantage lies with shareholder services. Second, extending the idea of a portfolio management-oriented family policy, service-outsourced funds pursue a general non-core cost discipline and have lower expenditures in another non-core area distribution/marketing while their core-management style is reflected in them having higher management fees. Third, service-outsourced funds have superior performance relative to service-inhouse funds since the lower resource expenditure on non-core fund activities correspond to more resources at the disposal of portfolio management. I investigate the relation between funds operational outcomes and outsourcing of shareholder services using mutual funds semi-annual reports N-SAR. Specifically, funds N- SAR reports contain information on their shareholder service providers that I categorize as outsourced if the service provider is unaffiliated to the management company. Using N-SAR information I observe that between 1996 and 2010 about 58 percent of all funds source shareholder services from external providers. In addition, consistent with the view of outsourcing as a strategic decision of management companies, I find that fund families either entirely consist of service-outsourced funds or administer all fund related shareholder services internally. I begin my analysis by comparing mutual fund expenses of service-outsourced funds with service-inhouse funds. Consistent with the first main hypothesis that service-outsourced funds seek to exploit cost reduction potentials in non-core areas, funds that delegate shareholder services to external providers exhibit about 32 percent lower service fees than service-inhouse funds. In addition, supporting the second main hypothesis that service-outsourced funds exert a general non-core cost discipline I find that service-outsourced funds have about 6 basis points lower 12B-1 fees. On the contrary, service-outsourced funds exhibit a higher concentration of monetary resources on their core business. In particular, service-outsourced funds have about 3

10 percent higher management fees than funds that take care of investors service needs internally. In my second set of tests I explore how funds focus on portfolio management through service outsourcing impacts on fund performance. Independent from the performance benchmark and net- or gross-of-fee returns, I find that funds that delegate shareholder services to external providers outperform their inhouse peers by up to 91 basis points per year in a multivariate regression approach and by up to 119 basis points in a matched-sample analysis. In a more detailed exploration, I account for a central prerequisite that influences the outsourcing decision of fund families: service outsourcing can only be considered as a strategic management decision of fund families if they can find a suitable external service provider. Thus, funds of families that are not capable to outsource shareholder services because there is no suitable external service provider (hereafter, service-inhouse forced funds) have to be separated from service-inhouse funds that belong to families that are capable to put a stronger focus on their core business but choose not to source services externally (hereafter, service-inhouse choice funds). Hence, I hypothesize to observe an even stronger impact of fund families core policy on fund performance if service-outsourced funds are compared with service-inhouse choice funds. Consistent with this hypothesis, I find that the underperformance from a weaker portfolio management orientation increases up to 136 basis points in a multivariate regression approach and becomes stronger the higher the number of external service providers is that are at the disposal of service-inhouse choice funds. Furthermore, I consider several alternative explanations for the outperformance of serviceoutsourced funds. First, service-inhouse funds implicitly do not declare portfolio management as their core competency and are prone to employ portfolio sub-advisors as an effective means to complement their portfolio management expertise (Del Guercio, Reuter, and Tkac (2007) and Debaere and Evans (2014)). However, Chen, Hong, Jiang, and Kubik (2013) show that subadvised funds underperform internally managed funds on average. Thus, service outsourcing 4

potentially captures the performance difference of this sub-advisor effect. Second, fund families that pursue a portfolio management core policy are unlikely to counteract a stronger portfolio management focus by tying their managers hands with investment restrictions on the use of, e.g., options, illiquid assets, or leverage. Thus, one could argue that the outperformance of service-outsourced funds is driven by them being subject to fewer investment constraints. Third, analyzing the distribution channel of funds Del Guercio and Reuter (2014) show evidence that is consistent with a market segmentation into performance-oriented direct-marketed funds and service-oriented brokered funds. Thus another possible explanation for the outperformance of service-outsourced funds could be that service outsourcing simply proxies for the direct distribution channel. I rule out these possibilities by showing that the outperformance of service-outsourced funds is unchanged even after sequentially controlling for sub-advised portfolio management, funds constraints, and funds distribution channels. To adress potential causality concerns that the performance finding is driven by endogeneity problems or not statistically robust I use two different test settings: First, I implement an instrumental variable (IV) approach. As an instrument I use the number of external service companies that offer shareholder services in the state where the fund s management company is located. The idea is that funds use of shareholder service outsourcing is more prevalent if the number of external providers in the proximity of the fund s management company is high. As expected, the first-stage results show that the decision to cater for investors service needs internally is strongly negative related to the number of service providers that do business in the state where the fund s management company is located. The second-stage regressions suggest an underperformance of service-inhouse choice funds that becomes even stronger when controlled for endogeneity problems. Second, I employ a permutation test with randomized outsourcing status. Since an insignificant number of permutations yield similar results to the observed underperformance of service-inhouse choice funds relative to service-outsourced funds, I conclude that the performance effect is indeed statistically reliable. 5

Building on the finding that service-inhouse choice funds underperform service-outsourced funds, raises the question how service-inhouse choice funds persist in the market. Hence, I investigate the implications for these funds market situation to examine whether serviceinhouse choice funds are made responsible by investors for their weaker focus on portfolio management. Looking at mutual fund flows, I find that service-inhouse choice funds grow at about 10 percentage points per year less than service-outsourced funds. Thus, fund investors seem to care whether fund families channel their efforts on their actual field of expertise. Alternatively, I examine the average life time of service-outsourced funds and service-inhouse choice funds. Consistent with the flow results, service-inhouse choice funds average life time decreases with the number of external service providers and is up to 1.7 years or about a fifth lower than for service-outsourced funds. Lastly, since funds of families that cater for investors needs are subject to strong negative effects for their market position, I investigate how management decisions of fund families that directly relate to portfolio management could mitigate the negative performance consequences of a less pronounced portfolio management focus. I explore such possibilities by investigating whether team-managed funds are less subject to a negative performance impact of retaining non-core activities internally since the non-core work load per head is less pronounced than for single-managed funds. As expected, I find that the underperformance of service-inhouse choice funds is reduced by up to 100 basis points when the fund is team-managed. This paper is related to a growing number of studies that examine the organizational structure of mutual funds. For instance, Nanda, Wang, and Zheng (2004) show evidence for fund family s star fund-creating behavior to increase family flows. Gaspar, Massa, and Matos (2006) analyze fund family s favoritism among funds and its impact on family profits. In a more recent study Kacperczyk and Seru (2012) analyze whether centralized or decentralized fund family structures are superior for the investment decision process. Kostovetsky and Warner (2012), Chen, Hong, Jiang, and Kubik (2013), Moreno, Rodriguez, and Zambrana (2013) and Debaere 6

and Evans (2014) analyze the decision of mutual fund families to outsource part of their portfolio management and the impact on fund performance. However, these studies so far consider cross-sectional differences that directly relate to portfolio management. This paper contributes to the literature in taking a more general view by accounting for the fact that mutual fund families encompass non-portfolio management, i.e. non-core, business units that consume resources which thus cannot be spent on a management company s actual core competency. This study is also related to studies that examine the competitive environment in the mutual fund industry which forces fund families to be concerned about how to persist (Wahal and Wang (2011) and Khorana and Servaes (2012)). I contribute to this literature by showing that fund families that emphasize their core business by externalizing non-core activities can exploit potentials for cost reductions and improve their funds performance to foster their competitive position in the market. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section I, I discuss the employed data set and sample summary statistics. Section II presents the findings on the impact of shareholder service outsourcing on mutual funds expenses and performance. Section III shows results on how the service outsourcing status impacts on fund performance if service-inhouse funds are separated into service-inhouse forced funds and service-inhouse choice funds. In Section IV I explore alternative explanations for the outperformance of service-outsourced funds. In Section V I implement an instrumental variable (IV) approach and permutation test to address potential causality concerns. Implications for funds market position and life time due to a stronger portfolio management-orientation are presented in Section VI. Section VII shows results on how the negative performance consequences for service-inhouse choice funds are interrelated to the management structure of funds. Section VIII concludes. 7

I. Data A. Sources and sample construction I obtain data on U.S. equity mutual funds between 1996 and 2010 from two sources: CRSP Survivor-Bias-Free U.S. Mutual Fund databases and filings of SEC Form N-SAR. From the CRSP Mutual Fund databases I obtain information on fund returns, total net assets under management (TNA), expense ratios, fund family identifier and other fund characteristics. Similar to the approach by Pástor and Stambaugh (2002) I assign a fund s investment objective based on the CRSP fund objective code. Since the focus is on actively managed U.S. domestic equity funds I take further steps to eliminate global, international, balanced, fixed-income and index funds. In addition, I exclude fund-year observations for which less than 12 months of gross-of-fee return data is available. If necessary, I aggregate data of share classes to the fund level by weighting the information with the TNA of the classes. In accordance to the Investment Company Act of 1940 investment companies need to file semi-annual N-SAR reports with the SEC that contain information on a variety of fund characteristics and their operations. 5 I merge the N-SAR database to CRSP similar to Christoffersen, Evans, and Musto (2013). Among the N-SAR information mutual funds report the name of their shareholder servicing agent during the period (Question 12A on N-SAR, i.e., Q12A). I determine the outsourcing status of a mutual fund s shareholder service by manually checking whether the service provider in N-SAR is affiliated with the management company reported in CRSP. 6 In some instances, mutual funds have more than one service provider. In that case, I classify a fund s shareholder service as outsourced if all service providers are 5 Starting in 1996 it became mandatory for mutual funds to file N-SAR reports with the SEC. Thus, to mitigate any selection bias, the sample period begins with the year 1996. 6 Specifically, the classification of a fund s service outsourcing status is based on a two-step procedure: First, CRSP assigns fund family identifier based on the investment management company that manages the fund. Thus, before determining the service status, I manually cross-check whether the management company reported in CRSP is identical to the advisor reported in N-SAR (Q8A). If the provided information diverge I adjust the CRSP family identifier in accordance to the advisor in N-SAR. In a second step, I compare the name of the service provider in N-SAR with the management company in CRSP and screen for affiliations between both entities using information from the funds 485APOS and 485BPOS SEC filings as well as LexisNexis. 8

unaffiliated to the management company. In addition, I obtain the funds total dollar value spent on the shareholder servicing agent(s) (Q72I), total expenses in dollars (Q72X), the number of months that the expense information applies to (Q72A), and the average monthly net assets during the period (Q75B) from N-SAR. I calculate funds monthly service fees by dividing the (monthly) dollar value spent on the servicing agent(s) (Q72I / Q72A) by the average monthly net assets during the period. Then I annualize the monthly estimate to obtain funds annual shareholder servicing fees. The final sample includes 692 fund families, 2,683 unique, actively managed U.S. equity funds and 19,352 fund-year observations. B. Sample characteristics Table I presents summary statistics on family, fund and service provider characteristics for the sample. Since the outsourcing decision is presumed to be a strategic decision on the family level I report the family statistics for the total sample and for both fund families that entirely consist of service-outsourced funds and fund families with no or partially outsourced shareholder services. All other information are at the fund level. - Insert Table I approximately here - On aggregate service-outsourced funds constitute about 58 percent of the sample. However, as expected, the outsourcing decision is highly concentrated within fund families, i.e., among families that do not entirely consist of service-outsourced funds only 1.85 percent of the funds receive shareholder services from unaffiliated service providers. Looking at fund family size, I observe that families with outsourced shareholder services are much smaller. This is consistent with the view that outsourcing families rely on service providers competitive advantage to realize lower costs through outsourcing than they could realize internally. In addition, fund families with unaffiliated service providers consist of a smaller number of funds. Likewise 9

service-outsourced funds are smaller and younger than service-inhouse funds. Furthermore, similar to Chen, Hong, Jiang, and Kubik (2013) and Moreno, Rodriguez, and Zambrana (2013) about 30 percent of all funds are sub-advised, i.e., some of the portfolio management responsibilities are delegated to external management companies. An interesting observation is, however, that the fraction of funds with sub-advised portfolio management is prevalent among service-inhouse funds, which is consistent with service-inhouse funds seeking complementary advisory services as expertise betterments. Looking at shareholder servicing costs, service-inhouse funds exhibit significantly higher costs for shareholder services than their outsourced peers. On average, shareholder servicing costs constitute about twice as much of total expenses and about 10 basis points more of the total expense ratio for service-inhouse funds than for service-outsourced funds. The average size of a service provider is not significantly different across service-outsourced and serviceinhouse funds. II. Main results In this section I explore the three main hypotheses: First, funds that delegate their shareholder services to external specialists exhibit lower service fees because they exploit their service providers competitive advantage in shareholder services. Second, the portfolio management-orientation of service-outsourced funds is represented in them having lower expenditures in another non-core area distribution/marketing and higher expenses on portfolio management. Third, service-outsourced funds generate superior fund performance relative to their inhouse peers which is consistent with a reduction of resource consumption in non-core activities and thus with a stronger focus on their actual field of expertise. 10

A. Service outsourcing and mutual fund expenses This section explores the first two main hypotheses that service-outsourced funds exhibit lower service fees than funds who take care of investors service needs internally as well as that their core policy is reflected in lower costs for distribution/marketing, i.e. 12B-1 fees, and higher management fees. Information on funds 12B-1 fees, management fees and total expense ratios are from CRSP, while funds service fees are calculated as described in Section I using information from N-SAR since service expenses are not available in CRSP. 7 To test for an impact of service outsourcing on mutual funds service fees and other expenses, I run pooled OLS regressions using these different fund fees as dependent variables: Fee i,t = α + β 1 Service outsourced i,t + γ 1 Ln TNA family i,t 1 + (1) γ 2 Family Focus i,t 1 + γ 3 Ln TNA i,t 1 + γ 4 Ln age i,t + γ 5 Turnover ratio i,t + ε i,t. The main independent variable is Service outsourced i,t, which is a binary variable that equals one if the service provider of fund i is unaffiliated to its management company in period t and zero otherwise. To control for potential family and fund influences I include, Ln TNA family i,t 1, the logarithm of the fund family s net assets under management, Family Focus i,t 1, the investment concentration of the fund family across investment segments as in Siggelkow (2003), Ln TNA i,t 1, the logarithm of the fund s total net assets under management, Ln age i,t, the logarithm of the fund s age, and, Turnover ratio i,t, the fund s yearly turnover ratio. In addition, I add year and segment fixed effects to control for any unobservable time or segment effects. Furthermore, since service outsourcing is a strategic 7 I report results for the management fee, 12B-1 fee, and total expense ratio using CRSP estimates because the tests in subsequent sections implicitly employ fee and other information from CRSP. However, due to high correlations between the information provided by CRSP and N-SAR, results of this section with expenses on advisory, distribution, and total expenses from N-SAR are qualitatively the same. 11

management decision at the fund family level I cluster standard errors at the family level to account for possible correlations within family groups. - Insert Table II approximately here - Results from Table II clearly support the first main hypothesis that service-outsourced funds have lower service fees. In particular, service-outsourced funds exhibit service fees that are 8 basis points lower than service fees of service-inhouse funds. To put this number into some perspective it is important to note that service-inhouse funds have service fees of approximately 25 basis points per year on average. In other words, service fees of service-outsourced funds are 32 percent lower, consistent with outsourcing as an effective means to exploit potentials for cost reductions in non-core activities of mutual funds. Furthermore, confirming the second main hypothesis, expenses for marketing/distribution are also lower for service-outsourced funds by about 6 basis points. In this spirit, service-outsourced funds total expense ratio is approximately 13 basis points lower than the one of service-inhouse funds which provides service-outsourced funds with a clear cost advantage. Finally, I find that management fees are economically and statistically significant higher for service-outsourced funds. In particular, management fees of funds with outsourced services are higher by about 6 basis points per year, which represents a relative difference of approximately 10 percent of service-inhouse funds average management fee. This is consistent with service-outsourced funds pursuing a core management style by spending significantly more on their actual field of expertise. Regarding the control variables I find no consistent and significant impact across all fund fee measures. In summary, the results of this set of tests are strongly in favor of the first two main hypotheses that service-outsourced funds use the delegation of shareholder services to external providers as a means to reduce non-core costs and to spent relatively more resources in terms 12

of money on portfolio management, consistent with a core competency management style of service-outsourced funds. B. Service outsourcing and fund performance In this section I test the third main hypothesis which postulates that service-outsourced funds perform better than service-inhouse funds. I use four different performance measures fund return, Khorana (1996) objective-adjusted return, Jensen (1968) alpha, and Carhart (1997) fourfactor alpha in a multivariate regression approach to analyze the impact of service outsourcing on mutual fund performance: Performance i,t = α + β 1 Service outsourced i,t + γ 1 Ln TNA family i,t 1 + (2) γ 2 Family Focus i,t 1 + γ 3 Ln TNA i,t 1 + γ 4 Ln age i,t + γ 5 Turnover ratio i,t + ε i,t. I run all tests for net- and gross-of-fee returns. The main independent variable is Service outsourced i,t, a binary variable that equals one if the service provider of the fund is unaffiliated to its management company and zero otherwise. The remaining controls and standard errors are as in Section II.A. - Insert Table III approximately here - Results reported in Table III confirm the third main hypothesis that service-outsourced funds exhibit superior performance relative to their inhouse peers. Looking at net-of-fee returns, service-outsourced funds outperform service-inhouse funds independently of the employed performance benchmark. The performance difference is most pronounced for fund returns with about 91 basis points per year on average. Using risk-adjusted performance measures the difference declines to 88 basis points for objective-adjusted returns, 78 basis points for Jensen alpha, and 50 basis points for Carhart alpha, however, all coefficients remain significant at the 13

1 percent or 5 percent level of statistical significance. Results for gross-of-fee returns are of a similar magnitude and three out of four performance measures are significant at the 1 percent level. Regarding the control variables, the results are consistent with the existing literature. Confirming the findings of Chen, Hong, Huang, and Kubik (2004) and Siggelkow (2003) I find a positive impact of Ln TNA family i,t 1 and Family Focus i,t 1 on fund performance. On the contrary, Ln TNA i,t 1 and Turnover ratio i,t impact negatively on performance as described in Berk and Green (2004) and Carhart (1997), respectively. As a robustness check to the third main hypothesis, I run a matched sample analysis between service-outsourced and service-inhouse funds. Thereby, each service-outsourced fund is matched with an equally weighted portfolio of service-inhouse funds that share the same characteristics. Specifically, in the base model I match a service-outsourced fund to all serviceinhouse funds that belong to the same investment segment and Ln TNA family i,t 1 decile in a certain year. I select Ln TNA family i,t 1 as the dominant matching criterion to account for the fact that service outsourcing decisions are strategic decisions at the family level as well as that service-outsourced and service-inhouse funds belong to families that on average strongly differ with respect to size as described in Section I.A. I account for other family and fund influences by extending the baseline match with other controls from Table III that have also been documented to impact on fund performance (see, e.g., Carhart (1997), Siggelkow (2003), Berk and Green (2004), Chen, Hong, Huang, and Kubik (2004) and Ferreira, Keswani, Miguel, and Ramos (2013)). Thus, in additional tests I link service-outsourced funds to all service-inhouse funds that, respectively, belong to the same Family Focus i,t 1, Ln TNA i,t 1, Ln age i,t, or Turnover ratio i,t decile. Finally, I measure performance differences between serviceoutsourced funds and the corresponding service-inhouse matching portfolio for the performance measures: fund return, Jensen (1968) alpha, and Carhart (1997) four-factor alpha. 14

- Insert Table IV approximately here - The results from Table IV clearly confirm the results from Table III. Independent of the employed performance measure and net- or gross-of-fee returns service-outsourced funds outperform their comparable service-inhouse funds. In particular, the outperformance becomes even larger than in the multivariate approach and amounts up to 119 basis points per year on average. In addition, the coefficients for all specifications are significant at the 1 percent level. Overall, the results from Table III and Table IV strongly support the third main hypothesis that service-outsourced funds generate superior performance for fund investors relative to service-inhouse funds. This is consistent with the view that service-outsourced funds are able to use resources in terms of time and money released through outsourcing that allows them to focus on their actual field of expertise. III. Service-inhouse separated by outsourcing capability In this section I extend the main finding that service-outsourced funds outperform serviceinhouse funds by accounting for the prerequisite that fund families have to be capable to outsource shareholder services to external providers. I adress this distinction among serviceinhouse funds by separating service-inhouse funds of families that are not capable to outsource shareholder services, i.e. service-inhouse forced funds, from service-inhouse funds that belong to families that are capable to put a stronger focus on their core business but choose not to source shareholder services externally, i.e. service-inhouse choice funds. Thus, comparing the fund performance of service-outsourced funds with service-inhouse choice funds provides a much cleaner comparison of an impact of a portfolio management-oriented family policy. More specifically, considering that fund families with service-inhouse funds are significantly larger than fund families who delegate investor services to external providers, some inhouse families could simply be too big to outsource. For instance, the assets under management of all actively managed U.S. domestic equity funds of Fidelity amount to approximately $179 15

billion in the year 2000. However, the largest external service provider Boston Financial Data Services has only about $68 billion assets under administration. Thus, even major external service providers are unable to handle a service mandate from large fund families such as Fidelity which forces them to administer investor assets internally. Thus, I determine the capability of fund families to outsource their shareholder services by comparing the size of the mutual fund family with the assets under administration of all external service providers during the same period. In particular, I define a service-inhouse fund as service-inhouse forced fund if its family s assets under management are larger than a certain threshold represented by the assets under administration of one of the largest external service providers. 8 In Table V I repeat the performance analysis from Section II but employ the two binary variables Service inhouse forced i,t and Service inhouse choice i,t as main independent variables. These variables equal one if a service-inhouse fund, respectively, is a service-inhouse forced fund or service-inhouse choice fund and zero otherwise. Specifically, in Panel A of Table V I define the Service inhouse forced i,t (Service inhouse choice i,t ) variable as one if the service-inhouse fund belongs to a fund family whose assets under management are larger (smaller) than the assets under administration of the sixth largest external service provider. Therefore, a Service inhouse forced i,t (Service inhouse choice i,t ) has at best five (at least six) external service providers at his disposal. - Insert Table V approximately here - 8 The estimation of each service providers assets under administration is executed in a two-step procedure. First, I use information from funds 485APOS and 485BPOS SEC filings as well as LexisNexis to identify affiliations between service providers. This is intended to avoid multiple counting problems in determining the number of unique service companies. Second, I estimate the assets under administration of a service provider by aggregating all assets under management of funds that source shareholder services from the respective service provider. If a fund has multiple service providers, I assume that a fund s assets under management are equally distributed among service providers. 16

The results from Panel A of Table V confirm the notion that the underperformance of service-inhouse funds is strongly dependent on the capability of their families to outsource. As hypothesized, service-inhouse choice funds underperform service-outsourced funds by up to 113 basis points independent of the employed performance benchmark and net- or gross-of-fee returns. On the contrary, service-inhouse forced funds exhibit no significant performance difference relative to service-outsourced funds. This is plausible since fund families that are too big to outsource are equipped with large economies of scale themselfes, which, if any, diminishes the potential for resource improvements. In addition, shareholder servicing divisions of service-inhouse forced funds families are very likely to posess a level of sophistication that does not require an involvement of their fund managers. Consequently the release of tied resourced in terms of time and money is strongly limited. As an additional check, I repeat the analysis in Panel B and Panel C assuming that fund families are incapable (capable) to outsource if their assets under management are, respectively, larger (smaller) than the assets under administration of the eighth or tenth largest external service provider. Results from these additional tests confirm the robustness of the findings of Panel A. In addition, the underperformance of service-inhouse choice funds becomes stronger the higher the number of external service providers is that are at their disposal. Overall, the results from Table V show that the underperformance resulting from a weaker portfolio management focus is limited to funds that belong to families that are capable to put a stronger focus on their core business through outsourcing but choose not to source services externally. IV. Alternative explanations There are a few alternative explanations for the observed outperformance of serviceoutsourced funds. In this section I explore these potential explanations. First, it is possible that service outsourcing is simply the flip side of retaining all portfolio management responsibilities, 17

i.e., to pass on the possibility to hire sub-advisors. For instance, Chen, Hong, Jiang, and Kubik (2013) show that sub-advised funds underperform funds that manage their assets internally. Thus, one could argue that the underperformance of funds who cater for investors service needs internally is simply driven by their need to make up for the lack of portfolio management expertise and thus a prevalence of sub-advisors. Second, funds restrictions on investment practices, e.g. options, illiquid assets, or leverage, have been documented as mechanisms for fund governance (Almazan, Brown, Carlson, and Chapman (2004)) but also as an impediment to generate positive returns for investors (Chen, Desai, and Krishnamurthy (2013)). Thus the outperformance of service-outsourced funds is potentially driven by fewer constraints imposed upon service-outsourced funds, which is consistent with families of service-outsourced funds passing on the possibility to tie their managers hands as part of a stronger portfolio management orientation. Third, a growing number of studies that examine the distribution channel of mutual funds shows that funds that are sold through financial advisors underperform direct-marketed funds (see, e.g., Bergstresser, Chalmers, and Tufano (2009) and Chalmers and Reuter (2014)). However, recent evidence by Del Guercio, Reuter, and Tkac (2010) and Del Guercio and Reuter (2014) indicates that the mutual fund market for retail investors is segmented into investors who demand advisory services aside from portfolio management, i.e. the brokered distribution channel of mutual funds, and sophisticated do-it-yourself investors who purely value portfolio management, i.e. the direct channel of mutual funds. Thus, it is possible that the outperformance of service-outsourced funds is simply the counterfactual of this market segmentation. For example, mutual fund companies that actively decide to compete for performance-oriented direct channel investors could use service outsourcing as a further means to achieve their strategic goals, while fund companies of the brokered channel who aim to cater for their investors service needs are also the ones that decide against service outsourcing. Hence, another possible explanation is that the outperformance of serviceoutsourced funds simply captures the performance focus of the direct distribution channel. 18

A. Impact of portfolio sub-advisor To rule out the possibility that the prevalence of sub-advisors among service-inhouse funds drives their underperformance relative to service-outsourced funds, I repeat the analysis from Table V and explicitly control for sub-advisors in a mutual fund. I identify the existence and the name of mutual funds sub-advisors using information from item Q8A and Q8B in the N- SAR reports filed with the SEC. 9 Since some mutual funds have multiple sub-advisors I follow the example by Chen, Hong, Jiang, and Kubik (2013) and consider a fund as being sub-advised if the fund hires at least one sub-advisor. - Insert Table VI approximately here - Results from Table VI show evidence that is consistent with the findings of Chen, Hong, Jiang, and Kubik (2013), Moreno, Rodriguez, and Zambrana (2013) and Debaere and Evans (2014). Although only significant for Carhart alpha, funds use of sub-advisors impacts negatively on fund performance. Apart from that, results are similar to those of Table V, if anything, even gain in statistical and economic significance. Specifically, looking at net-of-fee returns I find that the average difference in performance between service-outsourced and service-inhouse choice funds amounts to 117 basis points per year for fund returns. For riskadjusted performance measures the difference is about 130 basis points for objective-adjusted returns, 102 basis points for Jensen alpha, and 68 basis points for Carhart alpha. Results for gross-of-fee returns are of a similar magnitude and statistically significant across all performance benchmarks. For robustness I repeat the tests for alternative definitions of service-inhouse choice and service-inhouse forced funds. In Panel B and Panel C, I classify a service-inhouse fund as service-inhouse forced (choice) fund when the fund belongs to a fund family whose assets under 9 For earlier studies that follow the same approach see, e.g., Kuhnen (2009), Moreno, Rodriguez, and Zambrana (2013), and Debaere and Evans (2014). 19

management are, repsectively, larger (smaller) than the assets under administration of the eighth or tenth largest external service provider. Supporting the results from Table V the underperformance of service-inhouse funds becomes stronger the higher the number of external service providers is that are at their families disposal. B. Impact of fund constraints The superior fund performance of service-outsourced funds could be attributable to them being less subject to investment constraints. To address this concern I identify whether a fund is allowed to use specific investment practices using information from N-SAR item Q70 as in Almazan, Brown, Carlson, and Chapman (2004). Thereby funds investment practices are categorized in: the ability to use derivatives such as options and futures, the ability to invest in illiquid securities and the ability to use leverage. Then I follow the example by Almazan, Brown, Carlson, and Chapman (2004) and estimate funds exposure to investment constraints in a two-step process. First, I estimate a restriction score as the proportion of restricted practices within each category for all funds and periods. Second, I take the equally weighted average of the restriction scores across all categories to obtain the final Constraint score i,t for each fund i and period t. Finally, I repeat the test of the previous subsection, i.e. the sub-advisor control included, and additionally control for the Constraint score i,t. - Insert Table VII approximately here - Results from Table VII show no impact of funds constraint scores on the main result, thus confirming the results of Table V that service-outsourced funds outperform service-inhouse choice funds. Again, this observation is robust to the alternative definitions of outsourcing capability. 20

C. Impact of fund distribution channel I explore the possibility that service-outsourced funds are simply performance-oriented direct-marketed funds as in Del Guercio and Reuter (2014) by obtaining data on the primary distribution channels of U.S. equity fund shares from Thomson Reuters Lipper (Lipper). Lipper assigns each fund share class either to the direct, indirect, or institutional distribution channel. Share classes that are primarily sold to investors directly are grouped in the direct channel category, shares sold through financial advisors are categorized in the indirect channel, while the institutional distribution channel comprises share classes sold primarily to institutional investors. Since the Lipper classification is at the share class level I define a fund s distribution channel based on the share s channel that encompasses at least 50 percent of the fund s assets similar to Del Guercio, Reuter, and Tkac (2010) and Del Guercio and Reuter (2014). To ensure comparability to related studies I eliminate all fund-year observations that belong to the institutional channel from this analysis. - Insert Table VIII approximately here - Results from Table VIII confirm that there is a positive performance difference between direct and indirect sold funds consistent with the results of Bergstresser, Chalmers, and Tufano (2009), Chalmers and Reuter (2014), and Del Guercio and Reuter (2014). However, controlling for funds distribution channel does not dampen the outperformance of service-outsourced funds relative to service-inhouse choice funds. V. Causality concerns In this section I rule out remaining causality concerns for the outperformance of serviceoutsourced funds relative to service-inhouse choice funds. Specifically, in subsection A. I employ an instrumental variable approach to investigate whether uncontrolled or unobservable 21

characteristics drive the outperformance of service-outsourced funds. In subsection B. I examine whether the performance difference is statistically reliable by using a permutation test. A. Instrumental variable analysis To address the possibility that the observed outperformance of service-outsourced funds is attributable to endogeneity problems I implement an instrumental variable approach. As an instrument for whether shareholder services of a fund are outsourced I employ Number service providers in state i,t. Number service providers in state i,t represents the logarithm of 1 plus the number of external service companies that render shareholder services in the state where the funds management company is located. I identify the state where funds management companies are located using information from item Q8D in the N-SAR reports filed with the SEC. To be considered as a good instrument the number of external service providing companies in the state of the fund s management company needs to be correlated with the service outsourcing status but correlated with fund performance solely because of the outsourcing decision. I propose that Number service providers in state i,t serves as such a good instrument since the geographical region of a firm, respectively, the number of suppliers in a firm s region can be considered as a natural friction that could prevent firms from outsourcing (Grossman and Helpman (2002)). Specifically, I expect to observe that funds less frequently cater for investors service needs internally if the number of external service providers who do business in the proximity of the fund s management company is high. Since the dependent variable Service inhouse choice i,t is a binary variable that equals one if the service-inhouse fund belongs to a fund family that is capable to outsource but caters for investors service needs internally and zero otherwise, I employ a two-stage residual inclusion (2SRI) model as in Chen, Hong, Jiang, and Kubik (2013). 10 The first-stage specification is: 10 Hence, the analysis of this subsection is restricted to the observations of service-outsourced funds and serviceinhouse choice funds. 22

Service inhouse choice i,t = α + β 1 Number service providers in state i,t + (3) γ 1 Ln TNA family i,t 1 + γ 2 Family Focus i,t 1 + γ 3 Ln TNA i,t 1 + γ 4 Ln age i,t + γ 5 Turnover ratio i,t + ε i,t, whereby the main independent variable is Number service providers in state i,t. The remaining control variables are defined as in Section II. In addition, the first-stage regressions include time and segment fixed effects and standard errors that are clustered at the fund family level. 11 - Insert Table IX approximately here - The results of Table IX confirm the notion of a strong and significantly negative impact of the number of external service companies who do business in the state of the funds management company on the decision to administer shareholder services internally. The coefficients on Number service providers in state i,t suggest that a one standard deviation increase in the log number of shareholder services rendering companies in the state that the fund s management company is located (0.61) decreases the likelihood that the fund s shareholder services are internally administered by about 34 percent. In the second-stage I regress mutual fund performance on the binary variable Service inhouse choice i,t but include First stage residual i,t, the residual from the firststage regression, as additional independent variable. - Insert Table X approximately here - 11 In this and subsequent analyses I employ the (full) sample as in Table V to test for an impact of service outsourcing on fund performance. However, as additional check I repeat the analysis including all additional controls from the alternative explanations of Section IV, i.a. the sample is restricted to the observations that belong to funds that are marketed either directly to investors or brokered through financial advisors. The results (not reported) are qualitatively the same. 23