MEMO TO: Case study teams FROM: Steve O Connell DATE: December 3, 2002 SUBJECT: Differences between half-decadal dyn and gyso

Similar documents
ECON 450 Development Economics

1 Four facts on the U.S. historical growth experience, aka the Kaldor facts

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis

Growth 2. Chapter 6 (continued)

OVERTIME: Unit 5 Price Index Problems

Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America

Mitchell s Musings : Consistency May Be a Hobgoblin We Need to Mind. Daniel J.B. Mitchell

Economic growth: Interesting Facts and Examples. 2Topic

Problem Set 5 Answers. ( ) 2. Yes, like temperature. See the plot of utility in the notes. Marginal utility should be positive.

Notes 6: Examples in Action - The 1990 Recession, the 1974 Recession and the Expansion of the Late 1990s

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Chapter 4. Economic Growth

ECON 6022B Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Chapter 16. Price Levels and the Exchange Rate in the Long Run

Bank & Financial Institution Modeling: Certification Quiz Questions Module 3 Bank Valuation

Applied Economics. Growth and Convergence 1. Economics Department Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

ECON 206 MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS Roumen Vesselinov Class # 10

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

1 The Solow Growth Model

Revised Collins/Bosworth Growth Accounting Decompositions

Adjusting Nominal Values to

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1)

Imagine that countries A and B each have ten people (or ten equally large groups of people) with incomes distributed as follows:

EC202 Macroeconomics

Chapter 18: The Correlational Procedures

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET

A NEW MEASURE OF THE MONETARY "VELOCITY" (STOCK/FLOW) RATIO AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MONETARY POLICY AND ECONOMIC FORECASTING

Both the quizzes and exams are closed book. However, For quizzes: Formulas will be provided with quiz papers if there is any need.

h Edition Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries

Money and Exchange rates

Money, Inflation, and Interest Rates

Notes on classical growth theory (optional read)

Numerical Descriptive Measures. Measures of Center: Mean and Median

1. Actual estimation may be more complex because of the use of statistical methods.

San Francisco State University ECON 302. Money

MACROECONOMICS. Solow Growth Model Applications and Extensions. Zongye Huang ISEM, CUEB

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Passive Opportunities for Master Limited Partnerships (MLP) Investors: The Morningstar MLP Index Family

Generalized Dynamic Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering the Market Volatility Shocks

Macroeconomics, 7e (Blanchard) Chapter 2: A Tour of the Book. 2.1 Aggregate Output.

Whither the US equity markets?

Chapter 4: Micro Kuznets and Macro TFP Decompositions

Things you should know about inflation

19. CONFIDENCE INTERVALS FOR THE MEAN; KNOWN VARIANCE

Part III. Cycles and Growth:

Risk Reduction Potential

PowerPoint. to accompany. Chapter 11. Systematic Risk and the Equity Risk Premium

Chapter 6. y y. Standardizing with z-scores. Standardizing with z-scores (cont.)

Chapter Twenty. In This Chapter 4/29/2018. Chapter 22 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money

Solow instead assumed a standard neo-classical production function with diminishing marginal product for both labor and capital.

Adjusting Nominal Values to Real Values *

CHAPTER 2 Measurement

Appendix C An Added Note to Chapter 4 on the Intercepts in the Pooled Estimates

Intermediate Macroeconomics: Basic Definitions and Accounting

Emerging Asia s Impact on Australian Growth: Some Insights From GEM

Demand for Money MV T = PT,

Price Hedging and Revenue by Segment

Portfolio Sharpening

ECO155L19.doc 1 OKAY SO WHAT WE WANT TO DO IS WE WANT TO DISTINGUISH BETWEEN NOMINAL AND REAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT. WE SORT OF

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Theory of the rate of return

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Opening the Economy. Topic 9

Exam Number. Section

Lesson Exponential Models & Logarithms

Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

Which Is the Better Valuation Metric? The P/E Ratio or the PEG Ratio: Part 1

Capstone Design. Cost Estimating and Estimating Models

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Testing the Solow Growth Theory

Exchange Rate Fluctuations Revised: January 7, 2012

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Economic Growth Models and Inequality

CHAPTER 14 BOND PORTFOLIOS

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

3. Money multiplier. Using derivatives, find the effect on the money multiplier of a rise in r and a fall in l.

Getting Mexico to Grow With NAFTA: The World Bank's Analysis. October 13, 2004

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

AFM 371 Winter 2008 Chapter 19 - Dividends And Other Payouts

Intro to GLM Day 2: GLM and Maximum Likelihood

The NBER s Business-Cycle Dating Procedure

Goals of Topic 8. NX back!! What is the link between the exchange rate and net exports? How do different policies affect the trade deficit?

INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMIC GROWTH. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

CRS Report for Congress

How (not) to measure Competition

Socio-economic Series Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada:

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

Money Supply, Inflation, and Interest Rates

How Much Should We Invest in Emerging Markets?

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

China might NEVER become the biggest

The Theory of Economic Growth

Unit 2: Measurement of Economic Performance Tracking GDP Over Time

The Theory of Economic Growth

Guidance Update. ID Watchdog, Inc. (Stock Symbol - Other OTC: IDWAF) (Stock Symbol - Toronto SXV: IDW.V)

The global economic landscape has

Transcription:

MEMO TO: Case study teams FROM: Steve O Connell DATE: December 3, 2002 SUBJECT: Differences between half-decadal dyn and gyso. Introduction In the O Connell/Ndulu (999) paper we used two different series for growth in real GDP per capita: dyn for the pooled conditional model, and gyso for the Hoeffler augmented Solow model. The purpose of this note is to explain the differences between half-decadal values of these two variables. As a general caveat, we urge country teams to take the following approach: Do not allow differences in the two series to get in the way of the presentation and analysis of stylized facts in your macro/growth section. Particularly in your exposition, choose one series and stick with it. Do not present different growth rates in different tables except where necessary, and if you do so add a footnote to each table noting that the two series are different and indicating whether the differences are critical to your interpretation or not. In most cases, the differences between the two series are not large enough to alter the overall story or the key puzzles of growth in your country. In the few cases in which differences are really large, you must decide whether anything can be learned by examining the differences. While the guidelines below may be helpful in this respect, be prepared to come to terms with the fact that both series are subject to substantial measurement error. To the degree possible, emphasize themes that are supported by both series. Where differences are large, use what you know about your country s growth record to choose which of the two series to emphasize. Remember that a key reason for differences between the Hoeffler and Ndulu/O Connell decompositions is that the empirical models are different (see the O Connell and Ndulu framework paper, African Growth Performance: A Focus on Sources of Growth, April 999). The Hoeffler model is a structural model in which investment appears on the right-hand side and the parameters are estimated by instrumental variables; the Ndulu/O Connell model is a reducedform in which investment is excluded and the parameters are estimated by OLS. Adjust your use of these models accordingly. For example, a hallmark of the Hoeffler approach is that the use of instrumental variables resulted in a very large parameter on investment. Moreover, as you know, African investment rates are often very low at international prices. When very low investment is multiplied by a very large parameter, actual growth may be dramatically under-predicted because the estimated contribution of investment is so small. In such cases, do not let the large average residual throw you off; check whether changes in the Hoeffler residuals from episode to episode largely agree with those coming from the Ndulu/O Connell model. The watch-word is: be creative, look for the common stylized themes, and then focus on the rest of your paper.

2. The two growth variables The two variables are defined as follows, using the half-decade between 970 and 97 as an example: dyn = 974 97 gyso = 00 (ln ~ y ln ~ t yt t= 97 yt y 00 y t= 970 t t ) = 00 (ln ~ y ln ~ 97 y970 ), where y is real GDP per capita in constant local currency units and y ~ is real GDP per capita in constant US dollars at 98 international prices (sometimes referred to as PPPadjusted real GDP). While these two variables should tell roughly the same story, they are not identical. The correlation between the two series, for countries in SSA and excluding the 990s (for reasons we explain in 3(a) below), is only 0.68. It is apparent from the definitions above that there are three explanations for the lack of a perfect correlation between the two series: the underlying annual growth rates are calculated differently, the half-decades include different sets of years, and the underlying real GDP variables are defined differently. I briefly review these below, from the empirically least important to the most important. Difference : The method for calculating growth is different because dyn uses the discrete-time formula while gyso uses the difference in logs. This is not an important difference, however, when time averages are used. (a) The two formulas are often used interchangeably because the approximation ln(+ x) x is very good for small values of x. If we define x as yt yt, then ln( + x) is exactly equal to ln yt, and the yt y approximation therefore tells us that y t t ln y t. Figure shows yt the approximation, which is clearly better the closer the growth rate is to zero. (b) The figure also shows that x > ln( + x) for any nonzero value of x. The discrete-time formula will therefore systematically produce a slightly higher average value for growth if the same underlying series and set of years is used (in the annual data, for example, applying the discrete-time formula rather than the log formula to ~ y increases average growth in SSA by about 0.28 percentage points). This difference will tend to be larger when the variance in growth is higher, because as the figure shows, the gyso variable dampens positive outliers and exaggerates negative outliers by comparison with dyn. 2

(c) Overall, the use of a different formula for annual growth does not explain much of the difference between half-decadal values of the two series. If we use the discrete time formula for both series, the correlation between halfdecadal values (again excluding the 990s) rises only very slightly, from 0.68 to 0.69. At the individual country level, the difference should matter only in outlier half-decades, i.e. half-decades containing annual observations with extreme growth or decline. Difference 2: The time aggregation is different because dyn is an average of annual growth rates for 960-64, 96-69, etc, while gyso is an average of annual growth for 96-6, 966-70, etc. This is a fairly important difference, given the variance of growth rates in SSA. (a) For the dyn variable we used the more common convention for aggregating by half-decades or decades. Neither approach is obviously superior, however. (b) This particular difference between the two series is moderately important empirically. The table below shows correlations between different versions of the variables, using the discrete-time formula to calculate all underlying growth rates. The correlations on the diagonal are below solely because of the time shift. Those off the diagonal reflect both the time shift and the difference in definition of real GDP (y versus y ~ ). The definitional difference is clearly the most important empirically, but the timing does matter. Correlations using alternative timing Half-decades calculated using (e.g.) Half-decades calculated using (e.g.) 97-7 growth rates dyn gyso * dyn 0.86 0.69 970-74 growth rates gyso * 0.6 0.83 * For this table, gyso is calculated using the discrete-time formula rather than the difference in logs. Difference 3: The definition of real GDP per capita is different because dyn is calculated at constant local prices and gyso is calculated at constant 98 international prices. This is the most important difference between the two variables. If we eliminate other differences, the correlation between the two series rises from its current value of 0.68 only to 0.7 (again excluding the 990s). (a) While the PPP-adjusted series is superior for international comparisons of levels of real GDP, neither variable is clearly preferable for comparisons of growth rates. The reason we used the dyn variable in the pooled full specification is that it was available in the 990s, unlike the PPP-adjusted data from the Penn World Tables which was available only until 992. (Anke Hoeffler s model was run using half-decadal observations only through 990. In the data spreadsheets we distributed, any observations for gyso after 992 are based on a World Bank proxy for real GDP at international prices. This 3

proxy was constructed by using historical international-price GDP shares to aggregate constant-local currency growth rates for the components of GDP. Differences between gyso and dyn are therefore, by construction, smaller in the 990s than in other half-decades.) (b) If we eliminate other differences by using the same years for the half-decadal averages and the same method for calculating growth (i.e. either percentage changes or log differences), the correlation between half-decadal growth rates of y and y ~ rises from 0.68 to about 0.73 for SSA (excluding the 990s). (c) What then explains the substantial remaining differences between the two series? Both series use constant base-year prices to aggregate real growth rates of underlying GDP components. Differences can arise from differing relative prices, differing base years, or differing real series for the underlying GDP components. Unfortunately, it is difficult to say anything systematic about the likely net effect of these influences. Below we identify two systematic influences ((d) and (e)) arising from differences between international and domestic prices. But there is little we can say about differences arising from differences in the base year or in the disaggregated real growth series. (d) Suppose therefore that the same base year and disaggregated real growth rates were used. Then the domestic price data would be expected to give lower relative weight to nontraded components than traded components by comparison with the PPP-adjusted data, consistent with the well-known tendency for nontraded goods and services to be relatively cheaper at domestic prices than at international prices in low-income countries. This means dyn would tend to grow faster (slower) than gyso, other things equal, during periods of relatively rapid growth in the traded (nontraded) sectors e.g. periods of substantial real depreciation (appreciation). (e) Under the same assumption about base year and underlying real growth rates, an additional difference arises within the traded goods sector. The domestic currency data would tend to give higher relative weight to tariff- or quotaprotected traded goods sectors than the international price data. This means that under a very aggressive import substitution policy, for example, rapid growth of import-protected sectors could produce a situation in which the traded component of local currency real GDP is growing faster than the traded component of international-price real GDP. Brecher and Diaz-Alejandro demonstrated years ago that in this situation the traded component of international-price real GDP could even be falling (they actually referred to total real GDP, because all goods were traded in their model). This outcome can emerge if growth is driven by capital accumulation and the importprotected sector is relatively capital intensive. The traded component of international-price real GDP can fall in this case because the capital accumulation goes mainly into the import-competing sector, which is already too large at international prices. The traded component of real GDP rises at distorted domestic prices, but may actually fall at international prices because of the worsening distortion. 4

Figure : Alternative growth rate formulas dyn, gyso " dyn" = x (4 ) " gyso " = ln( + x) = ln y t 0 x yt y y t t