Kiyotaki and Moore [1997]

Similar documents
Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

Collateral and Amplification

Macroeconomics of Financial Markets

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Lorenzoni [2008] 1 The model. Econ 235, Spring Preferences and endowments. 1.2 Technology. Consumers: Preferences u = c 0 + c 1 + c 2

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Liquidity, Business Cycles, and Monetary Policy. Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and John Moore

Misallocation and the Distribution of Global Volatility: Online Appendix on Alternative Microfoundations

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

The Neoclassical Growth Model

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions

Bernanke and Gertler [1989]

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

A dynamic model with nominal rigidities.

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

ECON 3020: ACCELERATED MACROECONOMICS. Question 1: Inflation Expectations and Real Money Demand (20 points)

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Financial Development, Credit, and Business Cycles

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

X ln( +1 ) +1 [0 ] Γ( )

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

Bubbles and Credit Constraints

Long-Term Investment and Collateral Building with Limited Contract Enforcement

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Intermediary Leverage Cycles and Financial Stability Tobias Adrian and Nina Boyarchenko

Cash-in-Advance Model

Growth Theory: Review

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Collateral Constraints in a Monetary Economy

Capital Adequacy Requirements and Financial Friction in a. Neoclassical Growth Model

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

Overlapping Generations Model: Dynamic Efficiency and Social Security

In the Name of God. Macroeconomics. Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank

Balance Sheet Recessions

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

Econ 3029 Advanced Macro. Lecture 2: The Liquidity Trap

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model

Online Appendix: Extensions

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Household Leverage and the Recession

ECON 302: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory (Spring ) Discussion Section Week 7 March 7, 2014

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

1 No capital mobility

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Macroeconomics and finance

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Monetary/Fiscal Interactions: Cash in Advance

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34

Slides III - Complete Markets

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Transcription:

Kiyotaki and Moore [997] Econ 235, Spring 203 Heterogeneity: why else would you need markets! When assets serve as collateral, prices affect allocations Importance of who is pricing an asset Best users vs second-best users Forward-looking asset prices Asset trades as imperfect replacements for missing markets Amplification and persistence The basic model. Technology K is the endowment of land There is a measure of farmers and a measure m of gatherers, with access to different technologies If used by farmers, land produces fruit at a rate of y t+ = (a + c) k t c output is nontradeable the farmer must consume it in the period: upper bound on savings rate If used by gatherers, land produces fruit a a rate of y t+ = G(k G t )

with G > 0, G < 0.2 Preferences Both farmers and gatherers are risk-neutral and discount the future at rates β F < β G This pins down the interest rate at = β G. At this interest rate, Farmers want to borrow as much as possible (there are infinite gains from trade!) but a borrowing constraint will prevent this.3 Markets Competitive market for land: q t units of fruit per unit of land One-period borrowing at gross interest Debt requires collateral b t q t+ k t Threat not to work Ability to steal output Note the timing convention and the lack of uncertainty Borrow b t at t Need to repay b t at t + Own k t at the end of period t This land will yield (a + c) k t and be worth q t+ k t in period t + (sometimes people call the amount of capital you buy in period t to use in period t+ k t+. Here we are calling that k t ) Key implicit assumption: lenders cannot foreclose on output, just on land Paper has a long discussion of this, the threat of renegotiation, etc. 2

2 Equilibrium 2. Farmer s problem Assumption. c > s.t. ( β ) a max x t,k t,b t ( β F ) t xt x t + q t k t + b t (a + c) k t + q t k t + b t Proposition. Near a steady state, both () and (2) bind b t q t+ k t () x t ck t (2) Note that this is a statement about both the solution to the farmer s problem and about equilibrium prices in steady state The proof is by guess and verify Let u t q t q t+ (3) u t is the user cost of capital: it costs q t to buy it but you can resell it tomorrow for q t+ u t is also the downpayment requirement for a unit of land: it costs q t to buy it but you can borrow q t+ against it. Why? Comes from the specific form of the borrowing constraint Lender knows he can foreclose on land tomorrow Lends today up to the PV of land tomorrow In order to buy land the downpayment is the difference between the value of land today q t and the PV of land tomorrow q t+ This is also the cost of using the land for one period Consider the following uses for the marginal unit of tradeable fruit:. Consume it 2. Invest it with maximum leverage and reinvest the net tradeable fruit you obtain because of this, also with maximum leverage (consuming the extra nontradeable fruit) 3

3. Use it to repay debt for one period, and then resume path 2 The path of additional consumption you obtain:. {, 0, 0,...} 2. The following things happen: k t increases by u t b t increases by q t+ u t Therefore (a + c) k t + q t+ k t b t (which is HS of budget constraint at t + ) increases by (a + c + q t+ ) u t q t+ u t = (a + c) u t. Because he can pledge the land but not the fruit, investing with maximum leverage increases the farmer s net worth by the amount of additional fruit he will produce By assumption he will consume the nontradeable fruit c u t and buy land with the tradeable fruit, with maximum leverage, obtaining a u t u t+ in period t +, etc. The path of additional consumption is 3. The following things will happen: { 0, c u t, a u t c u t+, a u t a u t+ units of additional land } c u t+2,... (a + c) k t + q t+ k t b t will increase by due to the reduced borrowing By assumption, the farmer will use this extra net worth to increase land purchases with maximum leverage, obtaining u t+ units of land in period t +, etc. { } The path of additional consumption will be 0, 0, c u t+, a c u t+ u t+2,... To compare these we need to find out the equilibrium values of and u Now guess that the proposition is true and solve for capital holdings for the farmer: x t + q t k t + b t = (a + c) k t + q t k t + b t q t k t + b t = ak t + q t k t + q t+k t [ k t q t q ] t+k t = ak t + q t k t b t k t = u t [ak t + q t k t b t ] (4) Interpretation: tradeable net worth with maximum leverage 4

Now impose that the proposition is true at t as well: k t = u t [ak t + q t k t q t k t ] = u t ak t (5) Impose steady state: k = u ak u ss = a User cost is equal to tradeable marginal product Because you dedicate all the tradeable output to servicing debt Note than gatherers have no borrowing constraints, so the loan market will clear only if = β G Now we are in a position to compare the farmer s options.. NPV on consuming at the margin: 2. NPV of leveraged investment 0 + β F c a + ( β ) F 2 c a + ( β ) c F 3 c a +... = βf a β F Assumption exactly guarantees that this is better than immediate consumption 3. NPV of saving first and leveraged investment later: 0 + 0 + ( β ) F 2 c a + ( β ) F 3 c a +... = ( β ) F 2 which is inferior to leveraged investment right away as long as ( β F ) 2 < β F β F < β G c a β F which we have assumed Note on modeling technique: highly nonstandard assumptions (linear utility, difference in discount rates, weird nontradeable technology, etc...) to highlight one single mechanism. 5

2.2 Gatherer s problem max x t,k t,b t ( ) β G t xt s.t. x t + q t k G t + b t G ( k G t ) + qt k G t + b t FOC: ( ) β G t λt = 0 (6) ] q t λ t + [G (k t ) + q t+ λ t+ = 0 (7) λ t λ t+ = 0 (8) From (6) and (8), we confirm that = β G From (7) and (8), λ t ( ) G k G t = qt q t+ λ t+ = q t q t+ = u t (9) 2.3 Equilibrium In equilibrium, the land market has to clear, so k t + mk G t = K where k t satisfies (4) and kt G satisfies (9) Assumption 2. G (0) > a > G ( K ) m This assumption ensures that there will always be an interior solution for how much land the gatherers hold Define u(k) ( ) K k G m (0) This is the value that the user-cost of land must have in order for the land market to clear if the farmers have k units of land 6

i.e. the user cost of land that will persuade gatherers to hold the rest of the land An equilibrium can be characterized by equations: (4): evolution of farmers land holdings (): borrowing constraint, which always binds (0): user cost of capital for the market to clear (3): relation between land price and user cost starting from any initial b t, k t 3 Dynamics 3. Steady state We have seen that in steady state u = a. Using (3) qss = u ss = a () Also, using (0): And using (): G ( ) K k ss = u ss m b ss = a kss 3.2 Impulse response Consider a completely unexpected shock at t = 0, which multiplies output by + for one period only, assuming that the economy was in steady state (Notice that what will matter about its shock is not its effect on output but its effect on wealth. Start from (4): k 0 u 0 = a ( + ) k + q 0 k b and use: k = k ss b = b ss = qss k ss 7

u 0 = u ( k F 0 ) so that k 0 u(k 0 ) = [a ( + ) + q 0 q ss ] k ss (2) For periods after 0, where we know that () binds, we can simply use (5), so k t u (k t ) = ak t (3) Equations (2) and (3) determine the dynamic path of how much land is used by farmers Log-linearize. Let and define ( xt ) ˆx log x ss η d log u(k t) d log k t η is the elasticity of land supplied to farmers w.r.t. the user cost for gatherers elated to the curvature of G. If G is almost flat, a small increase in u releases a lot of land for farmers Log-linearize the LHS of equations (2) and (3): k t u(k t ) k ss u (k ss ) [ + ˆk t + η ] ˆk t Now the HS of (2), using that, by (), q ss = a [a ( + ) + q 0 q ss ] k ss [a ( + ) + q ss ( + ˆq 0 ) q ss ] k ss [ = a ( + ) + ] ˆq 0 k ss Now the HS of (3): ak t = ak ss ( + ˆk t ) Equating LHS and HS and using u (k ss ) = a: (2) can be approximated by k ss u (k ss ) [ + ˆk 0 + η ] [ ˆk 0 = a ( + ) + ] ˆq 0 k ss + ˆk 0 + η ˆk 0 = + + ˆq 0 ( + ) ˆk 0 + η ˆq 0 (4) 8

and (3) can be approximated by k ss u (k ss ) [ + ˆk t + η ] ˆk t = ak ( ss + ˆk ) t ( + ) ˆk t = η ˆk t (5) Equations (4) and (5) give us a linearized dynamic system in k and q HS of (4): impact of shock on net worth (in percentage terms) Direct Indirect via price of land. Scaled up by due to initial leverage LHS: increase in land holdings They increase less than one-for-one with net worth because of increasing u (higher user cost/downpayment requirement) (5) shows that there will be persistence With maximum leverage, net worth = ak t More land in the past more net worth today more land today 3.3 Initial effects of the shock (3) is a standard asset-pricing equation. Iterating forward and assuming there are no bubbles: q 0 = t u t Log-linearize LHS: q o q ss ( + ˆq 0 ) = u ss ( + ˆq 0) Now HS: t u t t u ss ( + û t ) = t u ss ( + η ˆk t ) 9

Therefore and using (5): u ss ( + ˆq 0) ˆq 0 = ˆq 0 η η t u ss ( + η ˆk t ) η tˆkt t ( + η ) t ˆk0 η η+ ˆk 0 (6) Now (4) and (6) are a pair of equations that we can solve for ˆq 0 and ˆk 0. Solving: ˆq 0 = η ˆk 0 = η η + [ + η Effect on price is of same order of magnitude as shock! (even though the shock is very short lived). The term ] can be very large! So effect on k 0 could be much more than one-for-one Persistence is the reason why there is amplification. Suppose future user costs did not change. Then the change in the value of land would just be: ˆq 0 = (just the present effect, i.e. the first term of (6)). Solving simultaneously with (4), we would get: ˆq 0 = η ˆk 0 = η ˆk t Contrast these static multipliers with the dynamic multipliers above. 0

The effect on total output at any point in time is given by: ŷ t = dy dk k ss Y ss ˆk t Use that and that in steady state ( ) K kt Y t = (a + c) k t + mg m dy dk = a + c G ( ) G ( ) = a to obtain ŷ t = [a + c a] kss Y ss ˆk t = a + c a a + c a+c a : productivity advantage of farmers a+c (a+c)kss : share of farmers in output Y ss (a + c) k ss ˆkt Y ss 4 emarks The paper has a second section that most people don t read, which extends to capital accumulation (rather than fixed land) There is also an appendix where some of the most nonstandard assumptions are relaxed Some of the ideas in these less-known sections reappear in Kiyotaki and Moore [202] and Kiyotaki and Moore [2005], which we will come to later The fact that shocks are unanticipated is quite important. against them if that was possible. Firms would want to insure Krishnamurthy [2003]: they would want to get insurance, but maybe the collateral constraint of insurance providers are the key. DiTella [202]: firms would get insurance against certain types of shocks but not others.

eferences Sebastian DiTella. Uncertainty shocks and balance sheet recessions. MIT Working Paper, 202. Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and John Moore. Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 05(2):2 48, April 997. Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and John Moore. 2002 Lawrence. Klein lecture: Liquidity and asset prices. International Economic eview, 46(2):37 349, 05 2005. Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and John Moore. Liquidity, business cycles and monetary policy. http://www.princeton.edu/ kiyotaki/papers/km6-2025.pdf, 202. Arvind Krishnamurthy. Collateral constraints and the amplification mechanism. Journal of Economic Theory, (2):277 292, 2003. 2