Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Similar documents
Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

4 Homework: Forwards & Futures

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options

The Black-Scholes Equation

The Black-Scholes Model

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

The Black-Scholes Model

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Spring 2018 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

King s College London

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory).

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

The Black-Scholes Model

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

1 The continuous time limit

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Lévy models in finance

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

The Impact of Volatility Estimates in Hedging Effectiveness

Computational Finance

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Spring 2018 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. September 16, 2018

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

King s College London

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

CHAPTER 5 ELEMENTARY STOCHASTIC CALCULUS. In all of these X(t) is Brownian motion. 1. By considering X 2 (t), show that

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

due Saturday May 26, 2018, 12:00 noon

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Attempt QUESTIONS 1 and 2, and THREE other questions. Do not turn over until you are told to do so by the Invigilator.

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Attempt QUESTIONS 1 and 2, and THREE other questions. Do not turn over until you are told to do so by the Invigilator.

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Numerical schemes for SDEs

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Monte Carlo Simulations

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model

European call option with inflation-linked strike

Probability in Options Pricing

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

A Moment Matching Approach To The Valuation Of A Volume Weighted Average Price Option

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

A Classical Approach to the Black-and-Scholes Formula and its Critiques, Discretization of the model - Ingmar Glauche

Continuous Processes. Brownian motion Stochastic calculus Ito calculus

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Black-Scholes model: Derivation and solution

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

INVESTMENTS Class 2: Securities, Random Walk on Wall Street

Financial Risk Management

Randomness and Fractals

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Slides for DN2281, KTH 1

1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

Transcription:

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 2017 14 Lecture 14 November 15, 2017 Derivation of the Black-Scholes equation In this lecture we derive the Black-Scholes partial differential equation. The content of this lecture involves probability theory. The content of this lecture is not for examination. 1

14.1 Random variables and Geometric Brownian Motion Up to now we have denoted the stock price by S. It is a real valued variable which takes positive values S > 0 (and S = 0 means the company is bankrupt and out of business.) We have written formulas involving S, including partial differential equations. 1. Obviously the S which appears in the Black-Scholes-Merton equation, or in the associated formula for the fair value of a European call or put, is not a random variable. 2. For example, the Delta of a financial derivative with fair value V (S, t) is defined as the partial derivative = S. (14.1.1) 3. There is no random variable in the above formula for Delta. Hence to avoid confusion, let us employ the notation S r to denote a stock price which is a random variable. According to stochastic calculus, suppose the value of S r changes by a small infinitesimal amount ds r in an infinitesimal time interval dt. Then, if the random variable S r obeys geometric Brownian motion, we have the following expression ds r = µs r dt + σs r dw t. (14.1.2) The equation eq. (14.1.2) is called a stochastic differential equation. Here µ is the growth rate of the stock, and is a constant (not random) and is not important. More important is dw t. What is dw t or what is W t? That we must know. In probability theory, W t is a so-called Wiener process (named after Norbert Wiener). A Wiener process W t is a random walk (technically, a stochastic process) with the following properties. 1. A Wiener process W t is a continuous function of t. 2. In an infinitesimal time interval dt, the value of W t changes by a random value dw t. 3. The value of dw t is a random variable with a normal (Gaussian) distribution, with mean zero and variance dt. 4. Hence in an infinitesimal time interval dt, E[dW t ] = 0, E[(dW t ) 2 ] = dt. (14.1.3) 5. The increments dw t1 and dw t2 in two non-overlapping time intervals dt 1 and dt 2 are independent. Hence E[dW t1 dw t2 ] = E[dW t1 ] E[dW t2 ] = 0. (14.1.4) 6. Since the value of dt is infinitesimal, we in fact write the following (because the corrections are negligible) (dw t ) 2 = dt. (14.1.5) 2

14.2 Random change in value of derivative V (S, t) Suppose we have a derivative V (S, t) on a stock S (and t is the time). To begin with, we assume the stock does not pay dividends. In a small time interval δt, we can write the following Taylor series V (S + δs, t + δt) = V (S, t) + δt + S δs + 1 2 V 2 S 2 (δs)2 + (14.2.1) We now say the following: let the change δs be a random variable. Furthermore, let the random walk for the stock price obey geometric Brownian motion. Replace the δt by an infinitesimal dt and replace δs by ds r in eq. (14.2.1). Then the change in the value of V, say dv, is given by dv (S, t) = = = ( dt + S dsr + 1 2 V 2 dt + S 2 (dsr ) 2 + S (µsr dt + σs r dw t ) + 1 2 + µsr S + 1 2 σ2 (S r ) 2 2 V S 2 2 V S 2 σ2 (S r ) 2 (dw t ) 2 + ) dt + σs r S dw t + (14.2.2) Since the time interval dt is very short (infinitesimal), we neglect all the higher order terms in eq. (14.2.2). We also replace the value of S r by S in eq. (14.2.2). We know that S r = S at the time t. What we do not know is the value of dw t, which is a random variable. Hence we can write, neglecting the higher order terms, ( dv (S, t) = + µs S + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V S 2 Then eq. (14.2.3) is also a stochastic differential equation, for V. The only random term in eq. (14.2.3) is the last term, in dw t. 1. The random term in dw t in eq. (14.2.3) represents risk. ) dt + σs S dw t. (14.2.3) 2. We do not know its value, hence we do not know how the value of V will change. 3. That poses a difficulty, how to calculate a fair value for the derivative (a formula for V ). 3

14.3 Cancellation of risk: Delta hedging Note that the risky term in eq. (14.2.3) is proportional to / S, which is the value of the Delta of the derivative. Hence let us form a portfolio U(S, t) consisting of long V and short a number Delta of shares: Then using eq. (14.2.3) and eq. (14.1.2), U(S, t) = V (S, t) S. (14.3.1) du(s, t) = dv (S, t) ds r ( = ( = + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V S 2 + µs S + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V S 2 ) dt. ) dt + σs S dw t (µs dt + σs dw t ) (14.3.2) The term in dw t cancels out. There is no risky term in eq. (14.3.2). This procedure is called hedging. Hedging is the procedure of reducing the riskiness of a portfolio. 1. The risk in this case is proportional to the Delta of the derivative. 2. Hence if we are long one derivative, we hedge our risk by selling Delta shares of stock. 3. Hence the above procedure is called Delta hedging. We now come to a key observation: 1. Since the change in U has no risk, the value of U grows at the risk-free rate. 2. Mathematically, this means du/dt = ru at the time t. 3. Expressed in infinitesimals, we have du(s, t) = ru dt. (14.3.3) Equating the two expressions for du in eqs. (14.3.2) and (14.3.3) yields r(v S ) = + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V S 2. (14.3.4) Rearrange terms and write = / S to obtain a partial differential equation for V : + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V + rs S2 S rv = 0. (14.3.5) This is the Black-Scholes equation. 4

14.4 Dynamic hedging Note that in general the value of / S is not a constant. Hence the hedge must be continuously updated, to keep the portfolio U riskless. This procedure is called dynamic hedging. In static hedging, the hedge does not change with time. 14.4.1 Technical subtlety The fact that / S is not a constant in time raises a technical subtlety. Recall that it was stated above that to eliminate the risk in the portfolio U, it was necessary to short a number Delta of shares (see eq. (14.3.1)). Now by definition = / S. This raises the point: when it was stated that the portfolio U grows at the risk-free rate r (see eq. (14.3.3)), then the value of should change in the time interval dt also. However, the correct formulation is to say that we hedge by shorting a number Delta of shares, and this number does not change in the time interval dt. It is only the values of S and t, and therefore V, which change. The technical formulation is that the portfolio U is assumed to be self-financing. This is a detail of stochastic calculus which is beyond the scope of these lectures to justify. 5

14.5 Black-Scholes-Merton equation Extra care is required to derive the Black-Scholes-Merton equation, to include the contribution from the stock dividends in the time interval dt in eq. (14.3.3). If the stock pays continuous dividends with a yield q, then the growth of the riskless portfolio U in the infinitesimal time interval dt is This yields the Black-Scholes-Merton equation du(s, t) = ru dt + qs dt. (14.5.1) + 1 2 σ2 S 2 2 V + (r q)s S2 S rv = 0. (14.5.2) 6

14.6 Absence of unobservable parameters Notice that the value of µ cancelled out in eq. (14.3.2) and µ does not appear in the Black-Scholes equation eq. (14.3.5). Historically, this was the key breakthrough by Black and Scholes. The value of µ is the expected rate of return on the stock. Its value is essentially unobservable. 1. For example, investor A might believe the stock is risky, and will demand a high rate of return (large value of µ) to agree to buy the stock. 2. On the other hand, investor B might believe the stock is a safe investment, and will agree to buy it for a much lower rate of return (small value of µ). 3. Hence the value of µ depends on the risk preferences of individual investors. If the value of V depended on µ, it would be impossible to derive a fair value for V that all investors could agree on. This was a major difficulty with option pricing theory in the 1960s and earlier. Black and Scholes succeeded in deriving an equation for valuing derivatives which did not contain parameters that depend on individual investors. Hence Black and Scholes were able to calculate a fair value for options, which all investors could agree on. 7

14.7 Delta hedging using futures The material in this section will be repeated in other lectures because it is important and will be tested in examinations. The overall procedure of Delta hedging will be repeated in other lectures because it is important and will be tested in examinations. It is perfectly possible to Delta hedge an option (or any other derivative on a stock) using futures. Options traders do this all the time. If the stock does not pay dividends, the fair value of the futures is F = Se r(t t). (14.7.1) The Delta of the futures is futures = e r(t t). (14.7.2) Hence the number of futures contracts to short to Delta hedge the derivative is N fut = derivative futures r(t t) = e S. (14.7.3) It is also possible to use a futures contract whose expiration is not the same as the option. 1. This can happen if there is no suitable exchange listed futures contract. 2. Suppose the futures expiration time is T, where T T. 3. Then the number of futures contracts to short to Delta hedge the derivative is N fut = derivative futures = e r(t t) S. (14.7.4) 4. This is also done, in practice. 8