Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

Similar documents
Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

S t d with probability (1 p), where

Homework Assignments

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

1 The continuous time limit

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Risk Neutral Valuation

Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics (part two) Dr Nic Freeman

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Risk Neutral Measures

Stochastic Modelling Unit 3: Brownian Motion and Diffusions

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Continuous Processes. Brownian motion Stochastic calculus Ito calculus

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Martingale representation theorem

Enlargement of filtration

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Stochastic Calculus for Finance Brief Lecture Notes. Gautam Iyer

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Hedging under Arbitrage

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

1 IEOR 4701: Notes on Brownian Motion

The stochastic calculus

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Non-semimartingales in finance

Remarks: 1. Often we shall be sloppy about specifying the ltration. In all of our examples there will be a Brownian motion around and it will be impli

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Lévy models in finance

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Brownian Motion. Richard Lockhart. Simon Fraser University. STAT 870 Summer 2011

Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

The value of foresight

Introduction Taylor s Theorem Einstein s Theory Bachelier s Probability Law Brownian Motion Itô s Calculus. Itô s Calculus.

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics Maximum likelihood estimation for jump diffusions

Convergence. Any submartingale or supermartingale (Y, F) converges almost surely if it satisfies E Y n <. STAT2004 Martingale Convergence

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus With Applications

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

1 Geometric Brownian motion

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

then for any deterministic f,g and any other random variable

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Geometric Brownian Motions

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Probability without Measure!

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Hedging under arbitrage

Martingale Measure TA

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

The Black-Scholes Model

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

4 Risk-neutral pricing

Transcription:

Stochastic Finance C. Azizieh VUB C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance 1/91

Agenda of the course Stochastic calculus : introduction Black-Scholes model Interest rates models C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance 2/91

Stochastic calculus : introduction C. Azizieh VUB 3/91

Agenda Stochastic calculus Introduction I Stochastic calculus : introduction Probability space, stochastic process in continuous time, filtration, martingales, convergence of random variables Itô stochastic integral : motivation Itô stochastic integral : construction Itô lemma Stochastic differential equations Girsanov theorem 4/91

Probability space Stochastic calculus Introduction I We consider the set of all possible states of the world Ω, with a sigma-algebra F. We speak about the notion of measurable space (Ω, F). In financial modelling, Ω represents the different possible evolution scenarios in the market : each scenario ω Ω typically represents a possible evolution in time of the prices of a set of financial instruments. An element of the sigma-algebra, A F, represents an event, hence typically a set of scenarios, to which a probability can be attributed : 5/91

Probability space Stochastic calculus Introduction I A probability measure is a mapping : P : F [0, 1] : A P(A) such that : P( ) = 0, P(Ω) = 1, If A i (i IN 0 ) are 2 by 2 disjoint, then : P ( i IN0 A i ) = P(A i ) i=1 (sigma-additivity) We will always work on a probability space (Ω, F, P). 6/91

Stochastic process and filtration The prices of financial assets, or more generally, of market variables (e.g. : interest rates, exchange rates, etc), will be modelled by stochastic processes in continuous time, i.e. the given of a random variable at each instant t : X : [0, + ) Ω R : (t, ω) X(t, ω) such that X(t,.) : Ω R is a random variable for each fixed t. Hence we have : For a fixed scenario ω, we have a trajectory For a fixed instant t, we have a random variable Now, if t represents time, in order to model concepts like the progressive arrival of information, causality and predictability, we introduce the concept of filtration. 7/91

Stochastic process and filtration A filtration is an increasing family of sub-σ-algebras on the probability space : for all 0 < s < t. F 0 = {Ω, } F s F t F Interpretation : in a dynamical framework, when time passes, information is progressively revealed to the observer quantities seen as stochastic at t=0 are not stochastic anymore at a future instant t > 0 if their value is revealed to the observer in the mean time, i.e. given the available information at t > 0. The notion of filtration allows to enrich the modelling framework in order to take into account the time dimension and information flow. 8/91

Filtration and process Notions linked by two definitions : Definition (Natural filtration or filtration generated by a stochastic process) Every stochastic process X generates a filtration called the natural filtration of the process, and defined by : F t = σ(x(s) s t) t (filtration corresponding to the history of the process) Definition (Adapted process) A process X is said to be adapted to a filtration (F t ) if X(t) is F t measurable t 9/91

Filtration and process Concretely, if (F t ) represents the available information (in a market) through time, a process (X t ) is adapted if its value at t is known as soon as we have reach instant t. In finance, we will model prices of financial assets by adapted processes. Definition { A filtration {F t } is said to satisfy the usual conditions if F0 contains all sets of zero probability t 0 F t = F s (right continuous). s>t In what follows, we will always assume that the filtration satisfies the usual conditions (...) 10/91

Continuous stochastic process A continuous stochastic process is such that t X t (ω) is continuous for all ω Ω 0 Ω with P [Ω 0 ] = 1. In other words : a process whose trajectories are almost all continuous. 1.5 1 0.5 0 X(t) -0.5-1 -1.5-2 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 Time t 11/91

Continuous time martingale The notion of martingale is central in market finance. Definition (continuous time martingale) A stochastic process (M t ) t 0 is a martingale w.r.t. a filtration {F t } t if for all t : 1 M t is F t -measurable (adapted process) 2 M t is integrable (hence IE [ M t ] < ) 3 IE [M t F s ] = M s for all s < t. Interpretation : accumulated gains of a player in an equilibrated game In particular, E[M t ] = M 0. 12/91

Martingales - Doob s results in continuous time Definition (Stopping time in a continuous time framework) A random variable τ with values in R + { } is a stopping time w.r.t. the filtration {F t } t if {τ t} F t for all t 0. Interpretation : we don t need information on the future to know at each instant if τ has already occurred. Example : the first instant at which a stock price reaches some fixed level Counter-example : the last instant before a future date at which a stock reaches a given level. Other examples? 13/91

Martingales - Doob s results in continuous time An example of link between stopping time and stochastic process : Definition (Process stopped by a stopping time) Let (Y t ) t be an adapted process to the filtration {F t } t and let τ be a stopping time. The process stopped at instant τ, denoted by (Y τ t ) t or (Y t τ ) t is defined by Y τ t (ω) = Y t τ(ω) (ω) t. 14/91

Martingales - Doob s results in continuous time Example : Let Y be a stochastic process and let us define the stopping time : T = inf{t 0 Y (t) M} for M R (M = barrier). The process Y stopped at M is then : { Y (t) if t T Z (t) = Y (t T ) = M if t > T 15/91

Martingales - Doob s results in continuous time When we stop a (continuous) martingale with a stopping time, we still have a (continuous) martingale : Theorem (Doob s stopping time theorem) Let (M t ) t be a continuous martingale w.r.t. filtration {F t }. Let τ be a stopping time w.r.t. {F t }. Then the process X t = M t τ is a continuous martingale w.r.t. {F t }. Proof : see [Steele, section 4.4]. 16/91

Martingales - Doob s results in continuous time Theorem (Doob s maximal inequalities in continuous time) Let (M t ) t be a continuous non-negative sub-martingale and λ > 0.. Then for all p 1, we have : ( ) λ p P sup M t > λ IE [ M p ] T (1) {t:0 t T } and, if M T L p (dp) for some p > 1, then : sup M t p p p 1 M T p. (2) {t:0 t T } Proof : see [Steele, section 4.4]. 17/91

Convergence of random variables Let {X n n IN} be a sequence of random variables. What is lim n X n?? One can actually define different types of convergence : almost sure convergence quadratic convergence (or L 2 ) convergence in probability convergence in distribution convergence in L p norm... 18/91

Almost sure convergence X n p.s. X iff P[ω Ω X n (ω) X(ω)] = 1 Example : Strong law of large numbers : If (X n ) is a sequence of random variables i.i.d. with finite expectation IE[X 1 ] = µ, then : 1 n p.s. X i E[X 1 ] = µ n i=1 19/91

Quadratic convergence (or in L 2 ) X n X in quadratic mean (or in L 2 ) iff X n X 2 L = IE[(X 2 n X) 2 ] = (X n (ω) X(ω)) 2 dp(ω) 0 Ω 20/91

Convergence in probability P X n X iff ɛ > 0 : P[ω Ω : Xn (ω) X(ω) ɛ] 0 Link between these different types of convergence : Almost sure convergence convergence in probability Convergence in L 2 convergence in probability 21/91

Convergence in distribution X n D X iff f bounded continuous : E[f (Xn )] E[f (X)] In particular this is equivalent to the convergence of characteristic functions : Definition : characteristic function of a random variable X : z R : Φ X (z) := E[exp(izX)] = e izx(ω) dp(ω) = e izx dµ X (x) (characteristic function = inverse Fourier transform of the density of X if X has such a density (up to some normalization constant)...) Result : (X n ) converges in distribution iff we have convergence of characteristic functions : X n D X iff ΦXn (z) Φ X (z) for all z R Ω R 22/91

Convergence in distribution convergence in probability convergence in distribution Theorem (Central limit theorem) If (X n ) is a sequence of i.i.d. random variables with finite variance σ 2, then n i=1 X i ne[x 1 ] σ D N(0, 1) n 23/91

Brownian motion : Motivation Suppose that we would like to define a stochastic model for the evolution of a financial asset in continuous time. Discrete time Continuous time Deterministic model S n = S 0 (1 + i) n S(t) = S 0 e δt Stochastic model S n = S 0 n k=1 (1 + i k)?? 24/91

: Motivation Continuous deterministic model We consider a financial asset which evolves deterministically in time : constant rate of return : δ value of the asset at t : S(t) we assume a double linearity hypothesis : S(t) = δs(t) t the evolution of the price is supposed to be proportional to time and to the invested amount 25/91

: Motivation Continuous deterministic model If we take the limit for t 0, we obtain the differential equation : ds(t) = δs(t)dt whose solution (passing by (0, S(0))) is given by the exponential function : S(t) = S(0)e δt Now, if we assume that the rate of return is not constant anymore, i.e. if δ = δ(t), then the differential equation becomes : whose solution is given by : ds(t) = δ(t)s(t)dt t0 δ(s)ds S(t) = S(0)e 26/91

: Motivation Binomial model on several periods (discrete time model) : Deterministic model : Stochastic model : S(n) = S(0) n (1 + i k ) = S(0) k=1 S(n) = S(0) n k=1 e Y k n k=1 où Y 1,..., Y n are i.i.d. : { δ + σ p = 1/2 Y i = δ σ q = 1 p = 1/2 e δ k We can rewrite : Y i = δ + σx i where X i = { 1 1/2 1 1/2. 27/91

: Motivation We hence have : S(n) = S(0) n k=1 e δ+σx k = S(0)e nδ+σ n k=1 X k We hence obtain the cumulative log-return until n : log(s(n)/s(0)) = n Y i = i=1 }{{} δn + σ determ. trend n i=1 X i }{{} random walk In particular, the moments of cumulative log-returns are given by : E[log(S(n)/S(0))] = δn var[log(s(n)/s(0))] = σ 2 n (variance proportional to time) 28/91

: Motivation We will now consider passing to a continuous time model. This will be done in two steps : 1 Modification of the (space and time) scale of the random walk : The time periods of 1 are replaced by t, and jumps of +1 and -1 are replaced by jumps of + x and x on each period of time. The random walk then becomes : W (n) = x. and in terms of moments : E[W (n)] = 0 m X i, with m = n/ t i=1 Var[W (n)] = m( x) 2 = n ( x)2 t 29/91

: Motivation 2 Passing to the limit x, t 0 We will now consider a sequence of x k, t k with x k, t k 0 in such a way that the limiting process is non-trivial. For this purpose, we will require : (and not x k t k 1!) ( x k ) 2 t k 1 30/91

: Motivation Construction of BM as limit of a random walk : illustration 3 2 1 X k (t) 0-1 -2-3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Time t 31/91

: Motivation Construction of BM as limit of a random walk : illustration 3 2 1 X k (t) 0-1 -2-3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Time t 32/91

: Motivation Construction of BM as limit of a random walk : illustration 3 2 1 X k (t) 0-1 -2-3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Time t 33/91

: Motivation Construction of BM as limit of a random walk : illustration 3 2 1 X k (t) 0-1 -2-3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Time t 34/91

: Motivation Construction of BM as limit of a random walk : illustration 3 2 1 X k (t) 0-1 -2-3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Time t 35/91

: Motivation Construction of BM as limit of a random walk : illustration 3 2 1 X k (t) 0-1 -2-3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Time t 36/91

: Motivation Construction of BM as limit of a random walk : illustration 3 2 1 X k (t) 0-1 -2-3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Time t 37/91

: Motivation Construction of BM as limit of a random walk : illustration 3 2 1 X k (t) 0-1 -2-3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Time t 38/91

: Motivation One can show that the sequence of processes (W (k) (t)) defined above converges in distribution to a process with continuous trajectories called Brownian motion : where W (t) : t/ t k W (k) (t) = x k is a continuous time process is called Standard Brownian motion, or Wiener process, or infinitesimal random walk i=1 X i W (t) 39/91

: Motivation This convergence is actually the dynamic equivalent of the central limit theorem in the static case : If (X n ) is a sequence of i.i.d. random variables of mean µ and finite variance σ 2, then we note S n = n i=1 X i, S n nµ σ n D N(0, 1) 40/91

: Motivation By construction, this process W (t) has the following properties : (i) E[W (k) (t)] = 0 E[W (t)] = 0 (ii) var[w (k) (t)] = t ( X k ) 2 t k var[w (t)] = t (iii) W (k) (t) = sum of i.i.d. rvs W (t) N(0, t) (Central Limit Theorem) (iv) W is a process with independent and stationary increments 41/91

: Definition All these lead to the following definition : Definition (Standard ) A stochastic process {B t : 0 t < T } in continuous time is standard Brownian motion on [0, T ) if 1 B 0 = 0. 2 The increments of B t are independent, i.e. for all finite set of instants : 0 t 1 < t 2 <... < t n < T, the random variables are independent. B t2 B t1, B t3 B t2,..., B tn B tn 1 3 for all 0 s < t T, the increments B t B s have a Gaussian distribution of mean 0 and variance t s. 4 B t (ω) is a continuous function of t for almost all ω. 42/91

: Illustration A typical sample path : 1.5 1 0.5 0 X(t) -0.5-1 -1.5-2 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 Time t 43/91

: back to the stochastic continuous model The random walk W (k) (t) converges to the standard Brownian motion W (t). The price of the asset S(t) hence becomes at the limit : S (k) (t) = S(0)e tδ+σ x t/ tk k X k=1 k δt+σw (t) S(t) = S(0)e This is what will be called later geometric Brownian motion. 44/91

: Historical Perspective 1829 : Brown : movement of pollen particles in suspension 1900 : Bachelier models financial stock prices by a Brownian motion 1905 : Einstein models particles in suspension in a liquid or a gaz, subject to collisions 1923 : Wiener proposes a rigorous construction of Brownian motion (also called Wiener process ) 1944 : Ito contributes to define a stochastic integral w.r.t. a Brownian motion BM has become a central process in finance for modelling the uncertainty present in the markets 45/91

Brownian motion and the Markov property By using the independence of disjoint increments we directly obtain : i.e. Markov property. P[X t+s B X u, 0 u t] = P[X t+s B X t ]. We also get : P[X t+s B X t = x] = P[X t+s X t B x X t X 0 = x] = P[X t+s X t B x] = P[X t+s X t + x B] = P[Y B], where Y N (x, s). We also have : P[X t+s B X t = x] = B 1 2πs e (y x)2 /(2s) dy. 46/91

Non standard Brownian motion from level a Z (t) = a + B(t) where (B t ) is a standard BM Brownian motion from level a, with drift µ and volatility σ Z (t) = a + µt + σb t In particular, E[Z (t)] = a + µt var[z (t)] = σ 2 t 47/91

Brownian motion and Gaussian processes Definition ( Gaussian processes) {X t : 0 t < } is a Gaussian process iff every linear combination of values of X at different instants is normally distributed : n α k X tk k=1 has a normal distribution for all coefficients α k and instants t k. Remark : such a process is characterized by : a mean function t E[X t ] and an autocovariance function (s, t) Cov[X s, X t ]. Example of Gaussian process : Brownian motion. 48/91

Brownian motion and Gaussian processes Let us compute the covariance function of a Brownian motion. for all s t : cov (B s, B t ) = IE [(B t B s + B s ) B s ] = IE[B t B s ]IE[B s ]+IE [ B 2 s ] = IE [ B 2 s ] = s = cov (B s, B t ) = min (s, t) 0 s, t <. 49/91

Brownian motion and Gaussian processes Lemma Let {X t : 0 t T } be a Gaussian process with IE [X t ] = 0 for all 0 t T and let cov (X s, X t ) = min (s, t) for all 0 s, t T, then the process {X t } has independent increments. Moreover, if the process has continuous trajectories and X 0 = 0, then {X t } t is a standard Brownian motion on [0, T ]. 50/91

Martingales and Brownian motion Theorem Let (B t ) be a standard Brownian motion. Then : 1 (B t ) t 2 ( B 2 t t ) t ( ( 3 exp αbt α 2 t/2 )) t are martingales w.r.t. à {F t } t (= the family of sub-sigma algebra σ (B s, s t) completed by adding the sets of zero probability). 51/91

Martingales and Brownian motion Proof 1) B t F t-measurable, IE [ ] Bt 2 = t <, IE [B t B s F s ] = 0 since IE [B t B s] = 0. 2) ( Bt 2 t ) F t-measurable, IE [ B 2 t t ] IE[B t 2 ] + t = 2t, IE [ ] [ ] Bt 2 t F s = IE (B t B s) 2 Bs 2 + 2B tb s t F s ] = IE [(B t s) 2 F s t Bs 2 + 2Bs 2 = t s t + Bs 2 = Bs 2 s. 3) IE [ exp ( αb t α 2 t/2 ) ] F [ ( s ) = IE exp α (B t B s) α2 (t s) 2 = IE [exp (αb t s)] exp ( = exp αb s α2 s 2 ( α2 2 (t s) ) exp ] ( F s exp ( ) αb s α2 s 2 ) αb s α2 s 2 ). 52/91

Martingales and Brownian motion Remark : We can actually show that the converse is also true : if (X t ) is a continuous process such that (X t ) and (Xt 2 t) are martingales and X(0) = 0, then (X t ) is a standard Brownian motion Brownian motion appears as the fundamental example of continuous martingale 53/91

Brownian motion and bounded variation Let us consider a sequence of subdivisions of interval [0,t] : 0 = t 0 < t 1 <... < t n = t with thikness tending to 0 (lim n max 0 i n t i+1 t i = 0). We know that [ n ] n E ( B(t i )) 2 = t i = t. i=1 If f is a deterministic function with bounded variation, lim n n i=1 f (t i) exists, and n ( f (t i )) 2 = 0. lim n i=1 This implies that trajectories of a Brownian motion cannot be of bounded variation. In particular, they cannot be differentiable (in the classical sense). Hence, these trajectories are continuous everywhere but nowhere differentiable. i=1 54/91

Brownian motion and quadratic variation Lemma (Quadratic variation of a BM) Let t j = j 2 n t (j = 0,..., 2 n ) be a partition of [0,t]. Then Z n = (B(t j ) B(t j 1 )) 2 t in L 2 2 n j=1 Proof (i) E[Z n ] = t (ii) IE[(Z n t) 2 ] = Var[Z n ] = 2 n j=1 Var( B(t j) 2 ). Now, if X N(0, σ 2 ), then Var(X 2 ) = 2σ 4 (exercise), which implies : 2 n ( ) 2 t Var(Z n ) = 2 2 n = 2 n+1 t 2 0. 22n j=1 55/91

Let us consider a market composed of d assets of price at t : S t = (S 1 t,..., S d t ), modeled like a vector process A trading strategy can be modelled by a vector φ t describing the quantities invested in each of the assets at instant t : φ t = (φ 1 t,..., φ d t ) The value at t of the portfolio obtained by following this strategy is then given by : d V t(φ) = φ k t St k = φ t.s t k=1 We will denote by 0 = T 0, T 1,..., T n+1 = T the rebalancing instants : between 2 such instants, the composition of the portfolio is supposed unchanged. 56/91

We can then denote by φ i = (φ 1 i,..., φ d i ) the composition of the portfolio between T i and T i+1, and rewrite φ t as : n φ t = φ 0 I t=0 + φ i I ]Ti,T i+1 ] i=0 ( ) Generally, the rebalancing instants T i are random (depending e.g. from the levels reached by some assets in the market...). The strategy φ t appears as a Stochastic process. Definition (Simple predictable process) A process φ t (t [0, T ]) that can be represented by ( ) is called a simple predictable process if moreover the stochastic instants T i are stopping times, and if φ i are bounded random variables with φ i F Ti, (which means that the value φ i is revealed at instant T i ). 57/91

Example of simple predictable process (one of its component) : 58/91

Gain process for a simple trading strategy If φ t is simple (we speak about simple trading strategy), then the gain realized by the trader between T i and T i+1 is equal to the scalar product φ i.(s Ti+1 S Ti ) Hence the accumulated gain on [0, T ] of the trader beginning with an initial composition given by φ 0 can be written as : G T (φ) = φ 0.S 0 + n φ i.(s Ti+1 S Ti ) i=0 59/91

Definition (Stochastic integral of a simple predictable process) G T is called the stochastic integral of the simple predictable process φ w.r.t. the price process (S t ), and will be denoted by : T 0 φ(u).ds(u) In finance, the cumulative gains of a trader following a strategy lead naturally to a new concept of integral : the stochastic integral 60/91

In view of getting some results concerning option prices in given models we cannot limit ourselves to the case where φ is a simple strategy. Hence we need to give a sense to this stochastic integral / gain process, also in the case where the composition continuously changes with time. We will first give a sense to this integral in the case where S t is a Brownian motion of dimension 1, and in the case where φ t is a more general process (not necessarily simple) : t 0 φ(s)db s 61/91

A first naive idea would consist to define the stochastic integral as a limit obtained along each trajectory : ( ) t n [ ] φ(s)db s (ω) = lim φ ti 1 (ω) B ti (ω) B ti 1 (ω) max(t i t i 1 ) 0 0 The problem is that (almost all) trajectories of a Brownian motion have no bounded variation... and that this limit hence does not exist in general for a given trajectory! i=1 62/91

Itô integral - Construction The stochastic integral will be defined as a limit of Riemann sums, but not in the sense of a.s. convergence, but in quadratic convergence (L 2 ) Objective : give a mathematical sense to : I (X) (ω) = T 0 X (ω, t) db t. where X(t) is a general stochastic process. 63/91

Contrarily to the Riemann integral, the result can depend on the point y i [t i 1, t i ). In the Itô integral, we will fix y i = t i 1 ; The final objective is to develop an integral allowing to introduce and to study stochastic evolution equations in continuous time ( Śtochastic differential equations, describing the dynamics of market variables) 64/91

Notations B [0, T ] = the set of Borel sets on [0, T ] (Borel sigma-algebra, i.e. the smallest σ algebra containing all open sets in [0, T ].) {F t } t the standard Brownian filtration. for all fixed t : F t B = the smallest σ algebra containing the product sets A B où A F t and B B. We say that a stochastic process X (.,.) is measurable if X (.,.) is F T B-measurable. We say that a process X (.,.) is adapted if X (., t) F t, t (0, T ). 65/91

In summary, Itô stochastic integral will be defined by following the subsequent steps : Definition of Itô integral for a simple process Itô isometry : the stochastic integral preserves the L 2 norm (in other words, is continuous for that norm) Density of the set of simple processes within the set of adapted square-integrable stochastic processes (with the L 2 ) Extension by density of the Itô integral on the set of square-integrable adapted stochastic processes thanks to the Itô isometry 66/91

Construction - Step 1 - Integral of indicator functions If X = I (a,b] is an indicator function, with (a, b] [0, T ], then the integral of X w.r.t. a Brownian motion is defined as : I (X) (ω) = T 0 X(s)dB(s) = B b (ω) B a (ω). (3) 67/91

Construction - Step 2 - Integral of step functions If X is a step function (or staircase function), i.e. n 1 X (ω, t) = c i I ]ti,t i+1 ] où 0 = t 0 < t 1 <... < t n = deterministic subdivision, and c i are constant, then by definition (additivity of the integral) : i=0 T 0 n 1 T X(s)dB(s) = c i I ]ti,t i+1 ](s)db(s) = i=0 0 i c i (B(t i+1, ω) B(t i, ω)) 68/91

Construction - Step 3 - Integration of simple stochastic processes X is square-integrable simple process if it can be written as : n 1 X (ω, t) = a i (ω) 1 (ti <t t i+1 ) with a i F ti, IE [ ] ai 2 <, et 0 = t0 < t 1 <... < t n 1 < t n = T (we will denote by H0 2 the set of such processes). Then we define the stochastic integral of X H0 2 as : i=0 I (X) (ω) = T 0 n 1 X(s)dB(s) = a i (ω) (B(t i+1, ω) B(t i ; ω)). (4) i=0 69/91

Construction - Step 4 - Extension by density X is a square-integrable process on (0,T) if : X is an adapted process [ ] T IE 0 X 2 (ω, s)ds <. The set of square-integrable adapted processes will be denoted by H 2 = H 2 [0, T ] Mathematicians show that H 2 is a closed vector subspace of L 2 (dp dt). We will denote by H0 2 (0, T ) the set of simple square-integrable (cf. preceding slide). 70/91

Construction - Step 4 - Extension by density We will now extend the definition for all square-integrable processes X H 2. The key of this extension is Itô isometry Lemma (Ito Isometry on H 2 0 ) X H0 2, we have In other words : I (X) L 2 (dp) = X L 2 (dp dt) T IE((I(X)) 2 ) = IE( X 2 (s)ds). 0 71/91

Construction - Step 4 - Extension by density Proof of Itô isometry We first calculate X 2 L 2 (dp dt). X is a simple process, hence can be written in the form : X (ω, t) = n 1 a i (ω)1 (ti <t t i+1 ) i=0 with a i F ti, IE [ a 2 i Let us take the square of X : such that : IE ] < and 0 = t0 < t 1 <... < t n = T X 2 (ω, t) = n 1 ai 2 (ω) 1 (ti <t t i+1 ) i=0 [ ] T 0 X 2 (ω, t) dt = n 1 IE [ ai 2 i=0 ] (ti+1 t i ). 72/91

Construction - Etape 4 - Extension by density Let us compute now I (X) 2 L 2 (dp) : IE [ I (X) 2] = IE n 1 = IE i=0 a i (ω) ( ) ) 2 B ti+1 B ti ( n 1 i=0 [ a 2 i ( Bti+1 B t i ) 2 ] as the double products have a zero expectation. Then, as B ti+1 B ti is independent of a i F ti, we have : IE [I (X) 2] = n 1 IE [ ] ai 2 (ti+1 t i ). i=0 73/91

Construction - Step 4 - Extension by density We will now extend by density the stochastic integral to the set of square integrable processes. We will use the following result : Lemma (density of H 2 0 in H2 ) For each process X H 2, there exists a sequence {X n } with X n H0 2 such that [ ] T X X n 2 L 2 (dp dt) = IE (X(s) X n (s)) 2 ds 0 for n. 0 74/91

Itô integral - Construction - Step 4- Extension by density Consequence of the Itô isometry and the density result For each simple process of the sequence, we can define its stochastic integral : I(X n ) = T 0 X n(s)db(s) The idea is to define I (X) for a general process X (not necessarily simple) as the limit of the sequence I (X n ) n in L 2 : I (X) def = lim n (I (X n )) where I (X) L 2 (dp) and the convergence is such that I (X) I (X n ) L 2 (dp) 0. 75/91

Construction - Step 4 - Extension by density Let us check that the stochastic integral is well defined 1, i.e. that (1) the limit of the sequence I(X n ) exists and (2) does not depend on the considered sequence X n tending to X : (1) X X n L 2 (dp dt) 0 implies that (I (X n)) converges in L 2 (dp) : Indeed, the convergence of the sequence (X n) in L 2 (dp dt) implies that this is a Cauchy sequence in L 2 (dp dt), which thanks to the Itô isometry, implies that (I (X n)) is also a Cauchy sequence L 2 (dp). As L 2 (dp) is a complete metric space (convergence of Cauchy sequences towards limits belonging to the space), the Cauchy sequence (I (X n)) converges to an element of L 2 (dp), that we denote by I(X). 1. The argument developed here is classical in functional analysis 76/91

Construction - Step 4 - Extension by density (2) Is I(X) well defined? i.e. for another choice of the sequence (X n) n converging to X : X X n L2 (dp dt) 0, does the new sequence I (X n) converges to the same limit in L 2 (dp) as the initial sequence I (X n )? The answer is yes, since X n X n L2 (dp dt) 0 thanks to the triangle inequality, and Itô isometry implies that : I (X n ) I (X n) L2 (dp) 0. 77/91

Itô integral - Itô isometry Now, we will show that when extended by density to the whole space H 2, Itô integral is still an isometry : Theorem (Itô isometry in H 2 (0, T )) For X H 2 [0, T ], we have that I (X) L2 (dp) = X L 2 (dp dt). In other words, ( T ) 2 [ T ] IE X(s)dB(s) = IE X 2 (s)ds 0 0 78/91

Itô integral - Itô isometry Proof First, we chose (X n ) n H0 2 such that X n X L 2 (dp dt) 0 for n. The triangle inequality for the L 2 (dp dt) norm implies : X n L 2 (dp dt) X L 2 (dp dt). Similarly, since (I (X n )) n L 2 (dp) I (X), I (X n ) L2 (dp) I (X) L 2 (dp). But we know that on H0 2, Itô isometry holds : I (X n ) L2 (dp) = X n L2 (dp dt) n, and the uniqueness of the limit completes the proof. 79/91

Itô integral as a stochastic process I : H 2 L 2 (dp) has been defined, and maps a stochastic process on a random variable (and not a process). Now, we would like to be able to consider the evolution in time of the gains of the trader, i.e. be able to consider t X(u)dB(u) as a stochastic process (in mathematical 0 terms, we need a mapping which maps a process to a process). For that purpose, we introduce a truncation function m t H 2 [0, T ] defined by : { 1 if s [0, t] m t (ω, s) = 0 else. 80/91

Itô integral as a stochastic process For X H 2 [0, T ], the product m t X H 2 [0, T ] t [0, T ], hence I (m t X) = T 0 m t(u)x(u)db(u) is a well defined element of L 2 (dp) One can show that we can construct a continuous martingale M t such that t [0, T ], we have P (M t = I (m t X)) = 1. The process {M t, t [0, T ]} is then the Ito integral considered as a process. 81/91

Itô integral as a stochastic process Theorem (Itô integral as martingales) for all X H 2 [0, T ], there exists a process {M t, t [0, T ]} which is a continuous martingale w.r.t. the standard Brownian filtration (F t ) t such that the event : {ω : M t (ω) = I (m t X) (ω)} has a probability 1 for all t [0, T ]. Proof : [Steele, pg 83-84, thm 6.2] 82/91

Itô integral as a stochastic process The integral sign : notation for all X H 2 [0, T ] and if {M t : 0 t T } is a continuous martingale such that we write : P [M t = I (m t X)] = 1 for all 0 t T, M t (ω) = t 0 X (ω, s) db s 0 t T t 0 X (ω, s) db s is a notation for what is well defined in the left-hand side of the equation. 83/91

Itô integral as a stochastic process But the notation is well chosen since ( ) 2 [ t ] t X H 2 = IE X (ω, s) db s = IE X 2 (ω, s) ds 0 0 t [0, T ]. Moreover, we have the following result : Proposition for all 0 s t and for all b H 2, we have ( ) 2 [ t ] t IE b (ω, u) db u F s = IE b (ω, u) 2 du F s. (5) s s 84/91

Itô integral as a stochastic process Proof Inequality (5) is equivalent to A F s : [ ( ) ] t 2 [ IE 1 A s b (ω, u) db ] t u = IE 1 A s b2 (ω, u) du. This is true by Theorem 1.4 on slide 78 for the modified integrand : b (ω, u) = 0 u [0, s) (t, T ] 1 A b (ω, u) u [s, t] 85/91

Riemann s representation Theorem For all f : R R continuous, if we consider the partition of [0, T ] given by t i = i T n with 0 i n, we have : lim n i=1 n f ( ) ( ) T B ti 1 Bti B ti 1 = f (B s ) db s (6) where the limit is taken in the sense of the convergence in probability. 0 86/91

Stochastic integral : explicit calculation In some cases, this integral can be explicitly computed from the definition. Example : t 0 B s db s =? If we denote i B := B ti B ti 1 and i t := t i t i 1, we have : ( B ti 1 i B ) = ( Bti 1 B t i Bt 2 i 1) i i = 1 [ (B 2 2 ti B 2 ) ( ] 2 ti 1 Bti B ti 1) = 1 B 2 2( t B0 2 ) 1 2 i i ( i B ) 2 = 1 2 B2 t 1 2 ( i B ) 2, i 87/91

Stochastic integral : explicit calculation We have seen that ( i B ) 2 t i in L 2. We then get : t 0 B s db s = 1 2 B2 t 1 2 t. Remark : We just saw that ( i B) 2 behaves like i t i.e., formally : (db t ) 2 = dt 88/91

Riemann s representation Proposition (Gaussian integrals) Let f C[0, T ] (a deterministic function), then the process defined by X t = t 0 f (s)db s for all t [0, T ] is a Gaussian process of zero mean with indepent increments and with covariance function cov(x s, X t) = s t 0 f 2 (u)du. Moreover, if we consider the partition of [0, T ] given by t i = it for 0 i n n and ti [t i 1, t i ], then lim n n i=1 f (t i ) ( B ti B ti 1 ) = T 0 f (s)db s, where the limit is taken in the sense of the convergence in probability. 89/91

Interpretation trajectory by trajectory of the Ito integral Theorem (Interpretation trajectory by trajectory of the Ito integral on H 2 ) If f H 2 is bounded and if ν is a stopping time such that f (ω, s) = 0 for almost all ω {ω : s ν}, then for almost all ω {ω : t ν}. X t (ω) = t 0 f (ω, s) db s = 0 90/91

Interpretation trajectory by trajectory of the Ito integral Theorem (Persistence of the identity on H 2 ) If f and g H 2 and if ν is a stopping time such that f (ω, s) = g (ω, s) for almost all ω {ω : s ν}, then the integrals X t (ω) = t 0 f (ω, s) db s and Y t (ω) = t 0 g (ω, s) db s are equal for almost all ω {ω : t ν}. 91/91