The Twin Ds. Optimal Default and Devaluation

Similar documents
A Model of the Twin Ds: Optimal Default and Devaluation

Prudential Policy For Peggers

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity Currency Pegs And Involuntary Unemployment

A Model of the Twin Ds: Optimal Default and Devaluation

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A MODEL OF THE TWIN DS: OPTIMAL DEFAULT AND DEVALUATION. Seunghoon Na Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martin Uribe Vivian Z.

The Twin Ds: Optimal Default and Devaluation

Center for Quantitative Economic Research WORKING PAPER SERIES. A Model of the Twin Ds: Optimal Default and Devaluation

AModeloftheTwinDs: Optimal Default and Devaluation

International Macroeconomics

International Macroeconomics

Towards a General Equilibrium Foundation for the Observed Term Structure and Design in Sovereign Bonds

slides chapter 9 nominal rigidity exchange rates, and unemployment

Sovereign default and debt renegotiation

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1

Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default on External Debt

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

slides chapter 10 fixed exchange rates, taxes, and capital controls

Pegs and Pain. November 21, 2011

Schäuble versus Tsipras: a New-Keynesian DSGE Model with Sovereign Default for the Eurozone Debt Crisis

Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Data and Some Theory

Twin Ds and Credit to the Private Sector

Sudden stops, time inconsistency, and the duration of sovereign debt

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Prudential Policy For Peggers

The sovereign default puzzle: A new approach to debt sustainability analysis

Sovereign Default and the Choice of Maturity

Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Sovereign Default, Exit and Contagion in a Monetary Union

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults. June 3, 2009

D10.4 Theoretical paper: A New Keynesian DSGE model with endogenous sovereign default

Fiscal Policy, Sovereign Risk, and Unemployment

Sovereign Risk, Private Credit, and Stabilization Policies

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Reserves and Sudden Stops

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

International Debt Deleveraging

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Fiscal Policy, Sovereign Risk, and Unemployment

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Optimal Devaluations

How does labour market structure affect the response of economies to shocks?

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University

Commodity Prices and Sovereign Default: A New Perspective on the Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect

Maturity Structure of Haircut of Sovereign Bonds

Austerity in the Aftermath of the Great Recession

Deflation, Credit Collapse and Great Depressions. Enrique G. Mendoza

Fiscal Austerity during Debt Crises

Devaluation Risk and the Business Cycle Implications of Exchange Rate Management

Sovereign Default Risk with Working Capital in Emerging Economies

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in Emerging Economies

Debt Denomination and Default Risk in Emerging Markets

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

Default risk and risk averse international investors

Financial Integration and International Risk Sharing

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default

Liquidity Crises, Liquidity Lines and Sovereign Risk

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ariel Zetlin-Jones and Ali Shourideh

Growth Regimes, Endogenous Elections, and Sovereign Default Risk

Exchange Rate Adjustment in Financial Crises

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

Reputational Effects in Sovereign Default

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default

Volatility Risk Pass-Through

Saving Europe? Some Unpleasant Supply-Side Arithmetic of Fiscal Austerity

Fiscal Devaluations. Emmanuel Farhi Gita Gopinath Oleg Itskhoki Harvard Harvard Princeton. Cambridge University April / 23

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

Did the 1980s in Latin America Need to Be a Lost Decade?

Default Risk, Sectoral Reallocation, and Persistent Recessions

2017 Federico Caffè Lectures. Monetary Policy in Times of Low Inflation

Credit Booms, Financial Crises and Macroprudential Policy

TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Transcription:

Optimal Default and Devaluation by Na, Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, and Yue June 30, 2017 1

Motivation There is a strong empirical link between sovereign default and large devaluations. Reinhart (2002) examines data from 58 countries over the period 1970 to 1999 and finds that: The unconditional probability of a large devaluation in any 24- month period is 17%. The probability of a large devaluation conditional on the 24- month period containing a default is 84%. Reinhart refers to this phenomenon as the Twin Ds. 2

New Evidence on the Twin Ds Phenomenon Expand the Reinhart sample to 2013. Produce a dynamic picture of the Twin Ds phenomenon to show the behavior of the exchange rate not only in the year of default but also before and after default. Key Findings: (1) The Twin Ds phenomenon continues to be present in the expanded dataset. (2) The dynamic perspective shows that devaluations around default are more akin to a change in the level of the nominal exchange rate than to a switch to a higher rate of depreciation. 3

Six Recent Default Episodes Argentina Uruguay Ukraine 3 2.5 5 Exchange Rate 2.5 2 1.5 Exchange Rate 2 1.5 Exchange Rate 4 3 2 1 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year 1 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Year 1 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 Year Russia 2.2 Paraguay 10 Ecuador Exchange Rate 8 6 4 2 1 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 Year Exchange Rate 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Year Nominal Exchange Rate Exchange Rate 8 6 4 2 1 0 1996 1998 2000 2002 Year Default Date Notes. Exchange rates are nominal dollar exchange rates, annual average, first observation normalized to unity. Data sources: Default dates, Uribe and Schmitt-Grohé (2017, Chapter 13, Table 13.19). Exchange rates, World Development Indicators, (WDI). 4

Cumulative Excess Devaluation Evidence from 117 Default Episodes: 1975-2013 50 45 Excess devaluations Default date 40 35 30 percent 25 20 15 10 5 0 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 Years after default Notes. Median of cumulative devaluations conditional on default in year 0 minus unconditional median. Sample contains 117 default episodes between 1975 and 2013 in 70 countries. Data sources: see notes to previous figure. 5

Countries Default in Bad Times 5 Output Around Default Events 4 3 2 Percent deviation from trend 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 Years after default Notes. Annual log-quadratically detrended GDP. The year of default is normalized to 0. Median over 105 default episodes between 1975 and 2014. 6

This Paper Develops a model with two key frictions: Imperfect enforcement of debt contracts (Eaton and Gersovitz, RES 1981). Downward nominal wage rigidity (Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, JPE 2016). Intuition for Why Twin Ds are Optimal in the Present Model In the present model, like in Eaton-Gersovitz-type models, default occurs in the context of highly depressed aggregate demand. Low demand puts downward pressure on real wages. A large devaluation reduces the real value of downwardly rigid nominal wages, thereby preventing potentially large involuntary unemployment. 7

Illustration of Narrative: Argentina 1996-2006 4 Nominal Exchange Rate (E t ) Unemployment Rate + Underemployment Rate 40 Pesos per U.S. Dollar 3 2 1 Percent 35 30 25 0 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year 20 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year Nominal Wage (W t ) 1.4 Real Wage (W t /E t ) 1.2 Pesos per Hour 12 Index 1996=1 1 0.8 6 0.6 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year 0.4 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year Vertical Line 1998, beginning of recession. Vertical Line 2002, default and devaluation. 8

Related Literature Fiscal consequence of devaluations, flow effects: Balance of payment crisis literature. High devaluation rate as a way to create seignorage to finance fiscal deficits (ex: Krugman, 1979). Fiscal consequence of devaluations, stock effects: Devaluation as indirect default on stock of local currency denominated debt (ex: Calvo, 1988; Corsetti and Dedola, 2014; Aguiar et al., 2013; Da Rocha, Gimenéz, and Lores, 2013; Kriwoluzky, Müller, and Wolf, 2014; Moussa, 2013; Du and Schreger, 2015). Real models of default à la Eaton and Gersovitz. (ex: Arellano, 2008; Aguiar and Gopinath, 2006; Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza, 2010; Kim and Zhang, 2012; Martinez and Sapriza, 2010; Chatterjee and Eyigungor, 2012; Mendoza and Yue, 2012.) 9

The Model 10

Households subject to Choose c t, c T t, cn t, d t+1 to maximize E 0 t=0 β t U(c t ) c t = A(c T t, c N t ) P T t ct t + P N t c N t + E t d t = P T t ỹt t + W th t + E t (1 τ d t )q td t+1 + E t φ t + E t f t h t h and d t+1 d where c t =consumption; c T t, cn t =consumption of tradables,nontradables; d t debt due in t; q t = inverse of gross interest rate; ỹt T exogenous and stochastic endowment of tradables; h t = hours worked; Pt T, Pt N =nominal price of tradables, nontradables; E t = nominal exchange rate (domestic-currency price of foreign currency); W t =nominal wage; τt d= capital control tax; φ t, f t =profits and government transfer. Law of one price: Pt T = Pt T E t, where Pt T = 1 = foreign price of tradables. Households take h t as given. Debt is denominated in foreign currency (original sin). 11

The Demand for Nontradables One first-order condition associated with the household s optimization problem is p t = A 2(c T t, cn t ) A 1 (c T t, cn t ) where p t P N t /E t is the relative price of nontradables in terms of tradables. This expression defines a demand for nontradables, c N t, as a decreasing function of the relative price p t, holding constant the desired consumption of tradables, c T t. 12

The Demand for Nontradables price, p A 2(c T 0,cN ) A 1(c T 0,cN ) A 2(c T 1,cN ) A 1(c T 1,cN ) quantity, c N c T 1 < ct 0 A Contraction in Traded Absorption, c T t for Nontradables Down and to the Left, Shifts the Demand 13

Firms Produce nontradables using labor. They choose h t to maximize profits: p t F(h t ) W t E t h t First-order condition: p t = W t/e t F (h t ) can be interpreted as the supply schedule for nontradables given real wages, W t /E t 14

The Supply of Nontradables p W 0 /E 0 F (h) W 0 /E 1 F (h) h E 1 > E 0 A Devaluation (E t ) Shifts The Supply Schedule to the Right 15

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity W t γw t 1 W t = nominal wage in period t. γ = degree of downward wage rigidity. Think of γ as being around 1. Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (JPE, 2016) estimate γ = 0.99 at quarterly frequency. 16

Closing of the Labor Market The following slackness condition is assumed to hold at all times: ( h h t ) ( W t γw t 1 ) = 0. Express in real terms where ( h h t ) ( w t γ w t 1 ɛ t ) = 0, w t W t E t = real wage in units of tradables. ɛ t E t E t 1 =the gross devaluation rate in period t. 17

Optimal Exchange-Rate Policy p A 2(c T 0,F(h) ) A 1(c T 0,F(h) ) p 0 p PEG A 2(c T 1,F(h) ) A 1(c T 1,F(h) ) B A W 0 /E 0 F (h) p OPT C W 0 /E 1 F (h) h PEG h = h OPT c T 1 < ct 0 (caused by, e.g., negative endowment shock, yt t ) E 1 > E 0 (optimal devaluation) negative external shock, y T t, calls for a devaluation. h 18

Optimal Default (Eaton-Gersovitz) Each period t, the government can be either in good financial standing or in bad financial standing. If the government is in good financial standing, it can choose to either honor its debt (indicated by I t = 1) or default. If it defaults, it immediately acquires bad financial standing (indicated by I t = 0). If the government is in bad financial standing in t, then it regains good financial standing in t + 1 with exogenous probability θ, and maintains bad standing with probability 1 θ. 19

Two Costs of Default (1) Financial Exclusion: While the country is in bad financial standing (I t = 0), it cannot participate in international credit markets, (1 I t )d t+1 = 0. (2) Output Loss: The endowment received by households is given by ỹ T t = { y T t if I t = 1 (good standing) y T t L(yT t ) if I t = 0 (bad standing) where L( ) is an increasing function. 20

Risk-Neutral Foreign Lenders The price of debt, q t, must satisfy 1 + r = Prob{I t+1 = 1 I t = 1} q t, where r is the risk-free interest rate. 21

Competitive Equilibrium: Processes c T t, h t, w t, q t, d t+1, λ t that satisfy w t γ w t 1 ɛ t given policies I t, ɛ t, τ d t c T t = yt t (1 I t)l(y T t ) + I t[q t d t+1 d t ] (1 I t )d t+1 = 0 λ t = U (A(c T t, F(h t )))A 1 (c T t, F(h t )) I t [ (1 τ d t )q t λ t βe t λ t+1 ] = 0 A 2 (c T t, F(h t)) A 1 (c T t, F(h t)) F (h t ) = w t ; (h t h) ( w t γ w ) t 1 ɛ = 0; and ht h t I t [q t E ti t+1 1+r ] = 0 22

Optimal Default and Optimal Exchange Rate Policy Benevolent Government s Problem: Pick policies I t, ɛ t, τ d t to bring about the best competitive equilibrium subject to the constraint that it lacks commitment. When the government can choose ɛ t freely, we can write the competitive equilibrium conditions in a more compact form: 23

Equilibrium conditions w t γ w t 1 ɛ t c T t = yt t (1 I t)l(y T t ) + I t[q t d t+1 d t ] (1 I t )d t+1 = 0 λ t = U (A(c T t, F(h t )))A 1 (c T t, F(h t )) I t [ (1 τ d t )q t λ t βe t λ t+1 ] = 0 A 2 (c T t, F(h t)) A 1 (c T t, F(h t)) F (h t ) = w t ; (h t h) ( w t γ w ) t 1 ɛ = 0; and ht h t I t [q t E ti t+1 1+r ] = 0 Result: Given processes {c T t, h t, d t+1, q t, I t } that satisfy the boxed conditions, one can find processes w t, λ t, ɛ t, τt d so that all equilibrium conditions are satisfied. 24

Lack of Commitment Restrict attention to Markov perfect equilibira. Period-t government takes default decision of period-t + 1 government to be a function of pay-off relevant state variables in period t + 1 I t+1 = Î(y T t+1, d t+1) If I t = 1, then, by participation constraint q t = E ti t+1 1 + r = E tî(yt t+1, d t+1) 1 + r = q(y T t, d t+1) Last equality uses the facts that yt T is an exogenous first-order Markov process and that d t+1 is in the information set of period t. 25

Optimal Policy Value of continuing to service debt: s.t. v c (y T t, d t ) = max {c T t,d t+1,h t } { U ( A ( c T t, F(h t ) )) + βe t v g (yt+1 T }, d t+1) c T t = yt t + q(yt t, d t+1)d t+1 d t h t h Value of bad financial standing: v b (yt T { ( ( ) = max U A c T )) {c T t, F(h t ) + βe t [θv g (yt+1 T,0) + (1 θ)vb (y T ]} t+1 ) t,h t } s.t. c T t = yt t L(yT t ) h t h 26

Value of good standing: v g (y T t, d t) = max { v c (y T t, d t), v b (y T t )} Default set: D(d t ) = { y T t : v c (y T t, d t) < v b (y T t )} Equilibrium participation constraint q(yt T, d t+1) = 1-Prob { yt+1 T D(d t+1) yt T 1 + r } Under optimal policy: h t = h. With h t = h, problem is identical to Arellano (2008) version of Eaton-Gersovitz model. 27

The Family of Optimal Devaluation Policies ɛ t γ w t 1 w f (c T t ), where w f (c T t ) denotes the full-employment real wage, defined as w f (c T t ) A 2(c T t, F( h)) A 1 (c T t, F( h)) F ( h); with wf (c T t ) c T t > 0. Hence, under optimal policy devaluations go hand in hand with contractions. model has the potential to predict the Twin Ds phenomenon because in the Eaton-Gersovitz countries default in bad times. 28

Quantitative Analysis 29

Functional Forms and Calibration The time unit is a quarter. U(c) = c1 σ 1 1 σ ; σ = 2 A(c T, c N ) = [ a(c T ) 1 1 ξ + (1 a)(c N ) 1 1 ξ ] 1 1 1 ξ ; ξ = 1/σ, a = 0.26 F(h t ) = h α t ; α = 0.75 Output loss, L(y T t ) = max {0, δ 1y T t + δ 2(y T t )2 } Set β = 0.85, δ 1 = 0.35, and δ 2 = 0.44 to ensure: (a) E(d t /y T t ) = 60%, (b) Prob of default equal to 2.6 per century, and (c) Average output loss in autarky of 7%. Set γ = 0.99 wages can fall by up to 4% per year. ln y T t = 0.93ln y T t 1 + 0.037µ t, µ t N(0,1) (Argentina, 1983-2001) From the family of optimal policies pick: ɛ t = w t 1 w f (c T t ) 30

Asymmetric Output Cost of Default y T t y T t L(y T t ) y T t 31

A Typical Default Episode Under Optimal Policy 1 0.95 Tradable Output, y T t Consumption of Tradables, c T t 1 0.95 1.4 1.3 1.2 Nominal Exchange Rate, E t 0.9 0.9 1.1 0.85 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 Real Wage, w t 2.2 2 0.85 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 Relative Price of Nontradables, p t 2.8 2.6 1 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 Country Interest-Rate Premium 6 5 1.8 2.4 %/yr 4 1.6 2.2 3 1.4 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 2 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 2 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 Model predicts the Twin Ds Phenomenon 32

Optimal Default Under Currency Pegs Suppose the central bank picks ɛ t = 1 t 33

Optimal Policy Under a Peg Value of continuing to service the debt { ( ( v c (yt T, d t, w t 1 ) = max U A c T t, F(h t ) )) + βe t v g (yt+1, T d t+1, w t ) } {c T t,d t+1,w t,h t } s.t. c T t + d t = y T t + q(y T t, d t+1, w t )d t+1 h t h A 2 (c T t, F(h t)) A 1 (c T t, F(h t)) F (h t ) = w t w t γw t 1 Value of being in bad financial standing { ( ( v b (yt T, w t 1 ) = max U A c T t, F(h t ) )) [ + βe t θv g (yt+1,0, T w t ) + (1 θ)v b (yt+1, T w t ) ]} {c T,w t t,h t } s.t. c T t = y T t L(y T t ) h t h A 2 (c T t, F(h t)) A 1 (c T t, F(h t)) F (h t ) = w t w t γw t 1 34

Value of being in good standing v g (y T t, d t, w t 1 ) = max { v c (y T t, d t, w t 1 ), v b (y T t, w t 1) }. Default set D(d t, w t 1 ) = { yt T : v b (yt T, w t 1 ) > v c (yt T }, d t, w t 1 ). Equilibrium participation constraint { q(yt T, d t+1, w t ) = 1-Prob yt+1 T } D(d t+1, w t ) 1 + r Observations: (1) Impossible to get rid of wage-rigidity constraints (except for slackness); (2) States are now: y T t, d t, w t 1 ; 35

Under Fixed Exchange Rates Defaults are Accompanied by Massive Unemployment Tradable Output, yt T 1 0.95 0.9 0.85 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 Real Wage, w t 2.5 0.95 0.9 0.85 Consumption of Tradables, c T t 1 0.8 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 Relative Price of Nontradables, p t 3 % 20 15 10 5 Unemployment Rate 0 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 Country Interest-Rate Premium 15 10 2 2.5 %/yr 5 1.5 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 peg 2 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 optimal devaluation 0 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 36

Peggers Can Support Less External Debt 2.5 Currency Peg Optimal Devaluation Policy 2 1.5 density 1 0.5 0 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 external debt (d t ) Note. Debt distributions are conditional on being in good financial standing. 37

Bailouts, Pegs, and Debt Sustainability 38

120 Debt to GDP, Greece, 1970 to 2011 100 80 Percent of annual GDP 60 40 20 0 20 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 low debt prior to accession to Eurozone, in 1995, just 11.9 percent. thereafter debt explodes reaching more than 100 percent by 2007. 39

The rise in debt occurs at a time when interest rates in Greece reach record lows. Interest Rate, Greece, 1980Q3-2011Q4 25 percent per year 20 15 10 5 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Notes. 1980Q3 to 1992Q2, overnight rate; 1992Q3-2011Q4 10-year government bond rate. Data sources: Bank of Greece and Eurostat. 40

This suggests that accession to the Eurozone was interpreted by markets as being accompanied to some degree with implicit bailout guarantees... 41

The prospect of bailouts (or ability to commit to repay) increases eqm level of debt 1 0.9 Currency Peg Optimal Devaluation Policy Currency Peg with Bailouts 0.8 0.7 0.6 density 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 external debt (d t ) Note. Debt distributions are conditional on being in good financial standing. The distribution under the optimal float is truncated at 1 to preserve a comparable scale across the three densities. Model calibrated to the Greek economy. 42

Absent an implicit bailout guarantee, debt declines after adoption of peg: External Debt to GDP Ratios: GIPS versus Ecuador, 1990 to 2011 120 Ecuador GIPS 100 80 % of GDP 60 40 20 0 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 year 43

Conclusions The paper provides new empirical evidence of the Twin Ds: defaults are typically accompanied by large one-time devaluations. It introduces nominal rigidities and exchange-rate policy into models with default risk à la Eaton-Gersovitz. The resulting model predicts that under the optimal policy defaults are accompanied by large devaluations, thus, capturing the Twin Ds phenomenon. The incentives to devalue around default are large. Under a currency peg, defaults are predicted to be accompanied by massive unemployment of around 20 percent. 44

Extras 45

Sensitivity Analysis 1. Long-Maturity Debt 2. Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass Through 3. Patience and the Twin Ds (higher β) 46

1.) Long-Maturity Debt: model continues to predict Twin Ds phenomenon Optimal Devaluation Around the Typical Default Episode 1.2 Tradable Output, y T t Consumption of Tradables, c T t 1 1.6 Nominal Exchange Rate, E t 1.1 0.95 1.4 1 0.9 1.2 0.9 0.85 1 0.8 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 0.8 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 0.8 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 2.2 Real Wage, w t Relative Price of Nontradables, p t 3 Country Interest-Rate Premium 15 2 2.5 10 1.8 1.6 2 5 1.4 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 1.5 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 long-maturity 0 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 short-maturity 47

2.) Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass Through Optimal Devaluation Around the Typical Default Episode 1.6 Nominal Exchange Rate, E t 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 Perfect Pass Through (η=1) Imperfect Pass Through (η=0.5) 0.9 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 48

3.) Patience and the Twin Ds (higher β) Optimal Devaluation Around the Typical Default Episode 1.6 1.5 1.4 Nominal Exchange Rate, E t β=0.85 β=0.95 β=0.98 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 49

Empirical Evidence on the Behavior of Capital Controls and Reserve Requirements Around Default The model predicts that debt taxes increase as the economy approaches default. Is this prediction of the model supported in the data? Take a look at the next two plots. The first shows that capital control measures increase and the second shows that reserve requirements increase. 1.5 1.4 1.3 Capital Controls on Inflows and Outflows outflow controls inflow controls 3.5 3 2.5 Reserve Requirements Index 1.2 1.1 % 2 1.5 1 1 0.9 0.5 0.8 3 2 1 0 1 Years after default 0 3 2 1 0 1 Years after default Notes. Own calculations based on data on capital controls from Fernández et al. (2016), left panel, and on data on reserve requirements from Federico, Végh, and Vuletin (2014), right panel. 50

Exchange Rate, Pesos per U.S. Dollar Default, Devaluation, and Unemployment: Argentina 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 Greece 20 2 30 18 16 14 12 10 8 Unemployment Rate, % 0.5 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 6 0 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Exchange Rate, Index 1 20 10 Unemployment Rate, % Exchange Rate, Krona per Euro 200 150 100 50 Iceland 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2 Unemployment Rate 8 6 4 Unemployment Rate, % Exchange Rate, Index 2 1.5 1 0.5 Cyprus 0 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 5 20 15 10 Unemployment Rate, % Nominal Exchange Rate Note. Vertical line indicates the year of default. Own calculations based on data from INDEC (Argentina), EuroStat, and the Central Bank of Iceland. 51

Other Macro Indicators Around Defaults support view that countries default in bad times Consumption Investment 6 20 Percent deviation from trend 4 2 0 2 Percent deviation from trend 10 0 10 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 Years after default 20 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 Years after default 1.5 Trade Balance To Output Ratio 4 Real Exchange Rate Percent deviation from trend 1 0.5 0 0.5 Percent deviation from trend 2 0 2 4 1 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 Years after default 6 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 Years after default Note: Annual log-quadratically detrended variables. The year of default is normalized to 0. Median over 105 default episodes between 1975 and 2014. 52

Observations Consumption contracts by as much as output in the run up to default (about 6 percent). The contraction of investment leading up to default is 3 times as large as that of output. The trade balance is below average up until the year of default. And in the year of default it experiences a reversal of about 2%. The real exchange rate depreciates significantly in the default year (by over 4%), and then begins to gradually appreciate. 53

Calibration Parameter Value Description γ 0.99 Degree of downward nominal wage rigidity σ 2 Inverse of intertemporal elasticity of consumption y T 1 Steady-state tradable output h 1 Labor endowment a 0.26 Share of tradables ξ 0.5 Elasticity of substitution between tradables and nontradables α 0.75 Labor share in nontraded sector β 0.85 Quarterly subjective discount factor r 0.01 World interest rate (quarterly) θ 0.0385 Probability of reentry δ 1-0.35 parameter of output loss function δ 2 0.4403 parameter of output loss function ρ 0.9317 serial correlation of ln yt T σ µ 0.037 std. dev. of innovation µ t Discretization of State Space n y 200 Number of output grid points (equally spaced in logs) n d 200 Number of debt grid points (equally spaced) n w 125 Number of wage grid points (equally spaced in logs) [y T, y T ] [0.6523,1.5330] traded output range [d, d] float [0,1.5] debt range under optimal float [d, d] peg [-1,1.25] debt range under peg [w, w] peg [1.25,4.25] wage range under peg 54

Data and Model Predictions: Optimal Devaluation Policy E(r r ) σ(r r ) corr(r r, y) corr(r r, tb/y) Data 7.4 2.9-0.64 0.72 Model 3.5 3.2-0.54 0.81 Note. Data moments are from Argentina over the inter-default period 1994:1 to 2001:3, except for the default frequency, which is calculated over the period 1824 to 2013. In the theoretical model, all moments are conditional on the country being in good financial standing. 55

Business-Cycle Statistics: Data and Model Predictions Under Optimal Exchange Rate Policy σ(c)/σ(y) σ(tb/y)/σ(y) corr(c, y) corr(tb/y, y) Data Emerging Countries 1.23 0.69 0.72-0.51 Argentina 1.11 0.48 0.75-0.87 Model 1.22 0.57 0.88-0.14 56

Typical Default Episodes With Fixed Exchange Rates 0.65 Debt, d t 0.6 0.55 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 12 8 4 0 4 8 12 peg optimal devaluation 57

Is there wage restraint during booms? Example: Periphery of Europe during the 2000-2008 Boom 58

Boom-Bust Cycle in Peripherical Europe: 2000-2011 2 Current Account / GDP 110 Labor Cost Index, Nominal 14 Unemployment Rate 4 100 13 12 Percent 6 8 10 Index, 2008 = 100 90 80 70 Percent 11 10 9 8 12 60 7 14 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Date 50 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Date 6 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Date Data Source: Eurostat. Data represents arithmetic mean of Bulgaria, Cyprus, Estonia, Greece, Ireland, Lithuania, Latvia, Portugal, Spain, Slovenia, and Slovakia Wages grew by 70 percent between 2000 and 2008! 59

Let s take a closer look at Spain and Ireland... 60

Nominal hourly wages in Spain increase by 44 percent during the 2000-2008 boom 110 Nominal Hourly Wages: Spain Index, 2008 = 100 100 90 80 70 60 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 61

Nominal hourly wages in Ireland increase by 57 percent during the 2000-2008 boom 110 Nominal Hourly Wages: Ireland Index, 2008 = 100 100 90 80 70 60 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 62

... Despite No Growth in Total Factor Productivity 115 Spain Ireland 110 TFP, Index 1995=100 105 100 95 90 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 63

Total Factor Productivity: 2000-2007 (value added based), Index (1995=100) 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Spain 96.2 95.6 94.8 94.1 93.4 92.4 91.9 92.1 Ireland 109.0 111.2 112.6 110.5 110.9 108.6 106.4 107.8 Source: EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts. This database includes measures of output and input growth, and derived variables such as multifactor productivity at the industry level. The input measures include various categories of capital (K), labour (L), energy (E), material (M) and service inputs (S). The measures are developed for 25 individual EU member states, the US and Japan and cover the period from 1970 to 2007. The variables are organized around the growth accounting methodology, a major advantage of which is that it is rooted in neo-classical production theory. It provides a clear conceptual framework within which the interaction between variables can be analyzed in an internally consistent way. The data series are publicly available on http://www.euklems.net. November 2009 release. 64

Average Debt And Default Probability Across Devaluation Policies Optimal Devaluation Currency Policy Peg Debt-to-traded-output ratio (qtr) 60% 20% Number of Defaults per century 2.6 2.0 Country Premium 3.5% 2.5% 65

Calibration of the Long-Maturity Debt Model Parameters specific to the long-maturity debt model: η = 0.05; z = 0.03 Parameters common with the short-maturity debt model that take a different value now: Pick β = 0.969, δ 1 = 0.18319, δ 2 = 0.24558 to match E(d t /yt T ) = 0.6, 2.6 defaults, and 5 percent output cost of default. Debt grid: [d, d] = [0, 1], nd = 200, equally spaced All other parameters are as in the short-maturity debt model, see Table 1. 66