Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios

Similar documents
Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios

Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios

A Multifrequency Theory of the Interest Rate Term Structure

Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing

State Space Estimation of Dynamic Term Structure Models with Forecasts

Forecasting Interest Rates and Exchange Rates under Multi-Currency Quadratic Models

Market Anticipation of Fed Policy Changes and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Statistical Arbitrage Based on No-Arbitrage Models

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16

Decomposing swap spreads

Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution?

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/ / 24

Transmission of Quantitative Easing: The Role of Central Bank Reserves

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting MarketAFA, Disruptions 1/7/ / 14

Term Structure Models with Negative Interest Rates

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns

Macro factors and sovereign bond spreads: aquadraticno-arbitragemodel

A Macro-Finance Model of the Term Structure: the Case for a Quadratic Yield Model

A Note on the Relation Between Principal Components and Dynamic Factors in Affine Term Structure Models *

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Applying stochastic time changes to Lévy processes

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

Market Price of Longevity Risk for A Multi-Cohort Mortality Model with Application to Longevity Bond Option Pricing

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM

Linear-Rational Term-Structure Models

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty

A New Class of Non-linear Term Structure Models. Discussion

Decomposing the Yield Curve

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Imports, Exports, Dollar Exposures, and Stock Returns

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Discussion of No-Arbitrage Near-Cointegrated VAR(p) Term Structure Models, Term Premia and GDP Growth by C. Jardet, A. Monfort and F.

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Expectation Puzzles, Time-varying Risk Premia, and

Analyzing volatility shocks to Eurozone CDS spreads with a multicountry GMM model in Stata

European spreads at the interest rate lower bound

The term structure model of corporate bond yields

A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics

A New Framework for Analyzing Volatility Risk and Premium Across Option Strikes and Expiries

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Nicola Fusari

University of Cape Town

Monetary Economics Portfolios Risk and Returns Diversification and Risk Factors Gerald P. Dwyer Fall 2015

Implied Volatility Surface

LIUREN WU. Option pricing; credit risk; term structure modeling; market microstructure; international finance; asset pricing; asset allocation.

LIUREN WU. FORDHAM UNIVERSITY Graduate School of Business Assistant Professor of Finance

IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Design and Estimation of Quadratic Term Structure Models

dt + ρσ 2 1 ρ2 σ 2 B i (τ) = 1 e κ iτ κ i

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell Midterm 2014

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

The Term Structure of Interest Rates under Regime Shifts and Jumps

Simulated Likelihood Estimation of Affine Term Structure Models from Panel Data

Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve

GRANULARITY ADJUSTMENT FOR DYNAMIC MULTIPLE FACTOR MODELS : SYSTEMATIC VS UNSYSTEMATIC RISKS

Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns

High-Frequency Data Analysis and Market Microstructure [Tsay (2005), chapter 5]

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Modeling Credit Risk

Why are Banks Exposed to Monetary Policy?

SOLUTION Fama Bliss and Risk Premiums in the Term Structure

Joint affine term structure models: Conditioning information in international bond portfolios

Tomi Kortela. A Shadow rate model with timevarying lower bound of interest rates

Is asset-pricing pure data-mining? If so, what happened to theory?

Long and Short Run Correlation Risk in Stock Returns

What is the Expected Return on a Stock?

Predictive Regressions: A Present-Value Approach (van Binsbe. (van Binsbergen and Koijen, 2009)

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

7 th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference 2015

dt+ ρσ 2 1 ρ2 σ 2 κ i and that A is a rather lengthy expression that we may or may not need. (Brigo & Mercurio Lemma Thm , p. 135.

Financial Econometrics

Pricing Default Events: Surprise, Exogeneity and Contagion

The Effectiveness of Alternative Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

Polynomial Models in Finance

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

Wishart spectral dynamics

A Closed-form Solution for Outperfomance Options with Stochastic Correlation and Stochastic Volatility

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Option Pricing Modeling Overview

Vayanos and Vila, A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Stru. the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Common risk factors in currency markets

Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation

Comparing Multifactor Models of the Term Structure

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios

Taxes and the Fed: Theory and Evidence from Equities

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Torben G. Andersen

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Foreca. Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors

Hedging in the Possible Presence of Unspanned Stochastic Volatility: Evidence from Swaption Markets

Transcription:

Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Joint work with Turan Bali and Massoud Heidari July 7, 2007 The Bank of Canada - Rotman School of Management Workshop: Advances in Portfolio Management

The evolution of interest-rate forecasting History: Expectation hypothesis regressions (since 1970s): The current term structure contains useful information about future interest-rate movement. Recent: Multifactor dynamic term structure models (DTSM) Affine (Duffie, Kan, 96; Duffie, Pan, Singleton, 2000) Quadratic (Leippold, Wu, 2002; Ahn, Dittmar, Gallant, 2002) Now: Use DTSM to explain expectation hypothesis regression results. Backus, Foresi, Mozumdar, Wu (2001), Dai, Singleton (2002), Duffee (2002), Leippold, Wu (2003),... Question: Why don t we directly use DTSM to forecast interest rate movements?

Let s try We estimate several three-factor affine DTSM models using 12 interest-rate series. The forecasting performances of these models are no better than the random walk hypothesis! This result is not particularly dependent on model design. The models fit the term structure well on a given day. All three factors are highly persistent and hence difficult to forecast. The pricing errors are much more transient (predictable) than the factors or the raw interest rates.

What do we do now? We use the DTSM not as a forecasting vehicle, but as a decomposition tool. y τ t = f (X t, τ) + e τ t What the DTSM captures (f (X t, τ)) is the persistent component, which is difficult to forecast. What the model misses (the pricing error e) is the more transient and hence more predictable component. We propose to form interest-rate portfolios that neutralize their first-order dependence on the persistent factors. only vary with the transient residual movements. Result: The portfolios are strongly predictable, even though the individual interest-rate series are not. What is left out from the factors can also be economically significant.

Three-factor affine DTSMs Affine specifications: Risk-neutral factor dynamics: dx t = κ (θ X t ) dt + S t dwt, [S t ] ii = α i + βi X t. Short rate function: r(x t ) = a r + br X t Bond pricing: Zero-coupon bond prices : P(X t, τ) = exp ( a(τ) b(τ) X t ). Affine forecasting dynamics: γ(x t ) = S t λ 1 + S t λ 2 X t. Does not matter for bond pricing. Specification is up to identification. Dai, Singleton (2000): A m (3) classification with m = 0, 1, 2, 3. We estimate all four generic specifications.

Data Data: 12 interest rate series on U.S. dollar: 1, 2, 3, 6, and 12-month LIBOR; 2, 3, 5, 7, 10, 15, and 30-year swap rates. Sample periods: Weekly sample (Wednesday), May 11, 1994 December 10, 2003 (501 observations for each series). Quoting conventions: actual/360 for LIBOR; 30/360 with semi-annual payment for swaps. LIBOR(X t, τ) = 100 τ! 1 P(X t, τ) 1 1 P(Xt, τ), SWAP(X t, τ) = 200 P 2τ i=1 P(X t, i/2). Average weekly autocorrelation (φ) is 0.991: Half-life = ln φ/2/ ln φ 78 weeks(1.5years) Interest rates are highly persistent; forecasting is difficult.

Estimation: Maximum likelihood with UKF State propagation (discretization of the forecasting dynamics): X t+1 = A + ΦX t + Q t ε t+1. Measurement equation: [ ] LIBOR(Xt, i) y t = + e SWAP(X t, j) t, i = 1, 2, 3, 6, 12 months j = 2, 3, 5, 7, 10, 15, 30 years. Unscented Kalman Filter (UKF) generates conditional forecasts of the mean and covariance of the state vector and observations. Likelihood is built on the forecasting errors: l t+1 (Θ) = 1 2 log A t+1 1 2 ( (yt+1 y t+1 ) ( At+1 ) 1 ( yt+1 y t+1 ) ).

Estimated factor dynamics: A 0 (3) P : dx t = κx t dt + dw P : dx t = ( b γ κ X t )dt + dw Forecasting dynamics κ 0.002 0 0 (0.02) 0.186 0.480 0 (0.42) (1.19) 0.749 2.628 0.586 (1.80) (3.40) (2.55) Risk-neutral dynamics κ 0.014 0 0 (11.6) 0.068 0.707 0 (1.92) (20.0) 2.418 3.544 1.110 (10.7) (12.0) (20.0) The t-values are smaller for κ than for κ. The largest eigenvalue of κ is 0.586 Weekly autocorrelation 0.989, half life 62 weeks.

Summary statistics of the pricing errors (bps) Maturity Mean MAE Std Max Auto R 2 1 m 1.82 6.89 10.53 60.50 0.80 99.65 3 m 0.35 1.87 3.70 31.96 0.73 99.96 12 m 9.79 10.91 10.22 55.12 0.79 99.70 2 y 0.89 2.93 4.16 23.03 0.87 99.94 5 y 0.20 1.30 1.80 10.12 0.56 99.98 10 y 0.07 2.42 3.12 12.34 0.70 99.91 15 y 2.16 5.79 7.07 22.29 0.85 99.40 30 y 0.53 8.74 11.07 34.58 0.90 98.31 Average 0.79 4.29 5.48 27.06 0.69 99.71 The errors are small. The 3 factors explain over 99%. The average persistence of the pricing errors (0.69, half life 3 weeks) is much smaller than that of the interest rates (0.991, 1.5 years).

4-week ahead forecasting Three strategies: (1) random walk (RW); (2) AR(1) regression (OLS); (3) DTSM. Explained Variation = 100 [1 var(err)/var( R)] Maturity RW OLS DTSM 6 m 0.00 0.53-31.71 2 y 0.00 0.02-7.87 3 y 0.00 0.13-0.88 5 y 0.00 0.44 0.81 10 y 0.00 1.07-3.87 30 y 0.00 1.53-36.64 OLS is not that much better than RW, due to high persistence (max 1.5%). DTSM is the worst! DTSM can be used to fit the term structure (99%), but not forecast interest rates.

Use DTSM as a decomposition tool We linearly decompose the LIBOR/swap rates (y) as yt i Hi X t + et, i H i = y t i X t Xt=0 We form a portfolio (m = [m 1, m 2, m 3, m 4 ] ) of 4 LIBOR/swap rates so that p t = 4 m i yt i i=1 4 4 m i Hi X t + m i et i = i=1 i=1 4 m i et. i i=1 We choose the portfolio weights to hedge away its dependence on the three factors: Hm = 0.

Example: A 4-rate portfolio (2-5-10-30) Portfolio weights: m = [0.0277, 0.4276, 1.0000, 0.6388]. Long 10-yr swap, use 2, 5, and 30-yr swaps to hedge. 15 8 7.5 Interest Rate Portfolio, Bps 20 25 30 35 10 Year Swap, % 7 6.5 6 5.5 5 40 4.5 45 Jan96 Jan98 Jan00 Jan02 4 3.5 Jan96 Jan98 Jan00 Jan02 Hedged 10-yr swap Unhedged 10-yr swap φ (half life): 0.816 (one month) vs. 0.987 (one year). R t+1 = 0.0849 0.2754R t + e t+1, R 2 = 0.14, (0.0096) (0.0306) R 2 = 1.07% for the unhedged 10-year swap rate.

100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 Predictability of 4-rate portfolios Four Instrument Portfolios 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Percentage Explained Variance, % 12 rates can generate 495 4-instrument portfolios. Robust: Improved predictability for all portfolios (against unhedged single rates)

Predictability of 2- and 3-rate portfolios Two Instrument Portfolios Three Instrument Portfolios 100 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Percentage Explained Variance, % 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Percentage Explained Variance, % No guaranteed success for spread (2-rate) and butterfly (3-rate) portfolios. Predictability improves dramatically after the 3rd factor.

A simple buy and hold investment strategy on interest-rate portfolios Form 4-instrument swap portfolios (m). Regard each swap contract as a par bond. Long the portfolio (receive the fixed coupon payments) if the portfolio swap rate is higher than the model value. Short otherwise: [ ] w t = c m (y t SWAP(X t )) Hold each investment for 4 weeks and liquidate. Remark: The (over-simplified) strategy is for illustration only; it is not an optimized strategy.

Profitability of investing in four-instrument swap portfolios 6 200 5 Cumulative Wealth 150 100 50 4 3 2 1 0 Jan96 Jan98 Jan00 Jan02 0 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Annualized Information Ratio

The sources of the profitability Risk and return characteristics The investment returns are not related to traditional stock and bond market factors (the usual suspects): Rm, HML, SMB, UMD, Credit spread, interest rate volatility,... But are positively related to some swap market liquidity measures. Interpretation The first 3 factors relate to systematic economic movements: Inflation rate, output gap, monetary policy,... What is left is mainly due to short-term liquidity shocks. By providing liquidity to the market, one can earn economically significant returns. Duarte, Longstaff, Yu (2005): Compensation for intellectual capital.

Robustness check Other models (A m (3) with m = 1, 2, 3): Better model choice generates higher predictability for the portfolios. Portfolios from all models are more predictable than single interest rates. Out-of-sample: Remains strong. Other currencies: Similar conclusions. Other markets:...

After thoughts: The role of no-arbitrage models No-arbitrage models provide relative valuation across assets, and hence can best used for cross-sectional comparison. If the price of a stock is $100, assuming no interest rate, dividend, or other carrying costs/benefits, no-arbitrage theory dictates that the forward price of the stock is $100. Is $100 the fair forward price? Will the price go up or down? How big is the risk premium on the stock? Is it time varying? No-arbitrage theory does not tell us how to predict the factors, but it does tell us how each instrument is related to the factor risk (factor loading). It is the most useful for hedging: Hedge away the risk, exploit the opportunity.