Lecture #2: Notes on Balance of Payments and Exchange Rates

Similar documents
Lecture #2: Notes on Balance of Payments and Exchange Rates

Macroeconomics in an Open Economy

Class Notes. Chapter 5 Saving and Investment in the Open Economy Learning Objectives

Lecture #8: How Scary is the US Trade Deficit?

Final Examination Semester 2 / Year 2012

Econ 340. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Outline: Exchange Rates

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Trade Deficits; Currency Manipulation

Chapter 2 Foreign Exchange Parity Relations

Chapter 5. Saving and Investment in the Open Economy. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Christiano 362, Winter 2006 Lecture #3: More on Exchange Rates More on the idea that exchange rates move around a lot.

National Income & Business Cycles

The Foreign Exchange Market

Chapter 13 (2) National Income Accounting and the Balance of Payments

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics Chapter 6

The Balance of Payments

18 INTERNATIONAL FINANCE* Chapter. Key Concepts

Study Questions. Lecture 15 International Macroeconomics

Macroeconomic Measurement 3: The Accumulation of Value

International Macroeconomics

Assignment 2: Due day. This Friday. Send this answer sheet via . Subject: Assignment 2.

(welly, 2018)

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 15 International Macroeconomics

Chapter 5. Saving and Investment in the Open Economy. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

The Balance of Payments. Balance of Payments. Balance of Payments Accounts. Balance of Payments Accounts. They are composed of the following:

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Definitions. Class 3

Appendix: Analysis of Exchange Rates Pursuant to the Act

Lecture notes 5: Open economy long-run equilibrium

Assignment 13 (Chapter 14)

The Open Economy. Inflation Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER 5

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

1 Question 1. Professor Christiano Economics 311, Winter 2005 Solution to Midterm #1

International Finance

The Balance of Payments

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

Chapter 19 (8) International Monetary Systems: An Historical Overview

Lecture 19: Effects of International Trade

Chapter 12. Preview. National Income Accounts. National Income Accounting and the Balance of Payments. National income accounts

International Monetary Policy

LECTURE XIII. 30 July Monday, July 30, 12

An Overview of World Goods and Services Trade

Macroeconomics, Cdn. 4e (Williamson) Chapter 1 Introduction

Suggested answers to Problem Set 5

World Payments Stresses in

Chapter 5: Saving and Investment in the Open Economy

II. ESTONIAN BALANCE OF PAYMENTS FOR 2001

Productivity and Sustainable Consumption in OECD Countries:

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

Chapter 6. The Open Economy

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Vertical Linkages and the Collapse of Global Trade

Practice Problems 41-44

Chapter 3 Foreign Exchange Determination and Forecasting

The Balance of Payments

Slides for International Finance Macroeconomic Accounting (KO Chapter 12)

To gain more understanding of the sources of saving and investment, we can disaggregate total saving into government (Sav G )

International Finance 407. Balance of Payments. Zhen Huo Teaching Fellow: Max Perez Leon. Yale University. Wednesday 31 st August, 2016

Balance of Payments and Exchange Rates. Ch12/BP&ER 1

OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS: BASIC CONCEPTS

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates

Macroeonomics. 18 this chapter, Open-Economy Macroeconomics: look for the answers to these questions: Introduction. N.

Analyzing Properties of the MC Model 12.1 Introduction

Y = C + I + G + NX Y C G = I + NX S = I + NX

Midterm Exam I: Answer Sheet

Micro versus Macro PP542. National Income Accounts. Micro versus Macro (cont.) National Income Accounts: GNP. National Income Accounts: GNP (cont.

Gross National Expenditure

Macroeconomic Measurement 3: The Accumulation of Value

!!! Current account balance =!!!!!! + (!!!!!! ) Capital account balance =!!!!!!, which is also equal to current account balance when!! =!!!!

Module 41: The Open Economy: International Trade. Duffka School of Economics

CHAPTER 2 Measurement

Slide 1. MACR Unit 12: Open Economy: Exchange Rates. An Open Economy

A Macroeconomic Theory of the Open Economy

ECO 352 Spring 2010 No. 19 Apr. 13 CAPITAL FLOWS, FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND MULTINATIONAL CORPORATIONS

Final Examination Semester 3 / Year 2012

The 2006 Economic Report of the President

The Balance of Payments

EC 205 Lecture 20 04/05/15

Macroeconomic Analysis Econ 6022 Level I

Recaping the effects of both Fiscal policy and Monetary policy in the long run

INTERNATIONAL FINANCE. Objectives. Financing International Trade. Financing International Trade. Financing International Trade CHAPTER

Econ 340. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102

DOES THE TRADE DEFICIT DESTROY AMERICAN JOBS? Russell Roberts George Mason University November 2006

Lecture 13 International Trade: Economics 181 Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and Multinational Corporations (MNCs)

Should We Worry about Trade Imbalances?

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

UNIT 6 1 What is a Mortgage?

International Macroeconomics

Lecture 1b. The open economy. The international flows of capital and goods, balance of payments and exchange rates.

Finland's Balance of Payments. Annual Review 2007

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Time Value of Money Toolbox CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION CASH FLOWS

Investment Insights. International Strategy: Understanding Currency Movements

Econ 98- Chiu Spring 2005 Final Exam Review: Macroeconomics

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 13. Exchange Rates

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Study Questions. Lecture 13. Exchange Rates

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

Is the US current account de cit sustainable? Disproving some fallacies about current accounts

CRS Report for Congress

China might NEVER become the biggest

Transcription:

Christiano Econ 362, Winter, 2006 Lecture #2: Notes on Balance of Payments and Exchange Rates 1. Balance of Payments. Last time, we talked about the current account, CA, and how it can be expressed in two ways by manipulating the national income identity: CA = S I = S private + S public I = Y (C + I + G). If domestic investment exceeds domestic saving, then the current account is negative, that is, net exports are negative. Alternatively, if domestic output is less than total purchases by domestic agents (households, business and government), then net exports are negative. A negative current account means that the flow of goods and services across borders results in more payments from domestic residents to foreigners than the other way around. As a result, on net foreigners are accumulating domestic currency. Foreigners could choose to simply hold on to this currency. Indeed, in large parts of the world foreigners pass US currency around amongst themselves, using it for their transactions. Dollars flowing into most parts of the world as a result of a negative US current account do not just remain there, however. Residents of those countries tend to send their dollars back to the US in exchange for US assets that generate a monetary return: equity, bonds, office buildings, etc. (a) The Current and Financial Accounts Governments keep records of the flow of payments that arise from the international flow of goods and services and of claims on assets. TheserecordsarecalledtheBalanceofPayments. Thecurrent account in the balance of payments records the flow of dollars reflecting the flow of goods, while the financial account reflects the flow of dollars corresponding to the flow of assets. The following Table describes the general structure of the balance of payments. 1

Balance of Payments Current Account Credit Debit (1) Exports + Merchandise and Services + Investment Income Received + (2) Imports - Merchandise and Services - Investment Income Paid - Financial Account (3) Increase in US Holdings - of Assets Located Abroad ( US Assets Held Abroad ) (4) Increase in Foreign Holdings + of Assets Located in US ( Foreign Assets Held in US ) A + indicates a positive number which corresponds to a payment by foreigners to the US. A - indicates a negative number, and corresponds to a payment by US residents to foreigners. For example, suppose that in one year exports were zero, while imports were $100. No investment income flows across borders. Thus, there is an entry of 0 in the Exports row, and its two subcomponents. There is a -$100 in the Imports row and in the subcomponent that corresponds to Merchandise and Services. The current account, which is exports minus imports, is -$100. The financial account records the flow of assets. The extra $100 accumulated by foreigners could be held in currency form, or in the form of foreign holdings of US bank deposits. Or, it could be exchanged for another US asset, one which generates earnings. Either way, there is an entry for $100 in the row corresponding to Increase in Foreign Holdings of Assets Located in the US. Sometimes this entry is abbreviated in the way indicated in parentheses. The abbreviation is somewhat confusing, but it is the one that is adopted in official tables published by the US government. The phrase, current account, sometimes refers to the firstpartoftheabovetable. At other times it is used to refer to a number. In this case, the number is the sum, (1) + (2). Similarly with the phrase, financial account. Sometimes it is used to refer to the second part of the above table. At other times it is used to refer to a number. In this case, it refers to (3) + (4). Obviously, when the table is con- 2

structed correctly, the current account plus the financial account must sum to zero. In practice, since sources for the entries in the financial and current account differ,these two do not sum to zero. The difference is called statistical discrepancy. The statistical discrepancy is usually quite large. The balance of payments in the previous example looks like this: Balance of Payments Current Account Credit Debit (1) Exports 0 Merchandise and Services 0 Investment Income Received 0 (2) Imports -100 Merchandise and Services -100 Investment Income Paid 0 Financial Account (3) Increase in US Holdings 0 of Assets Located Abroad ( US Assets Held Abroad ) (4) Increase in Foreign Holdings 100 of Assets Located in US ( Foreign Assets Held in US ) (b) Investment Income Let s think about the investment income terms in the current account. Investment income received corresponds to earnings on assets (equity, bonds, buildings, etc.) held by domestic residents that are located abroad. We can illustrate this by thinking about the world economy of the previous example in later years. Suppose that in later years merchandise exports and merchandise imports are both zero. Suppose that in the first year, the increase in foreign holdings of assets located in the US corresponds to holdings by foreigners of US government debt that pays 5% per year. Thus, in the next year, the current account is $5, corresponding to the $5 in investment income paid. These $5 flowing abroad correspond to a $5 increase in foreign holdings of assets located in the US. Thus, the balance of payments in the next year looks like this: 3

Balance of Payments Current Account Credit Debit (1) Exports 0 Merchandise and Services 0 Investment Income Received 0 (2) Imports -5 Merchandise and Services 0 Investment Income Paid -5 Financial Account (3) Increase in US Holdings 0 of Assets Located Abroad ( US Assets Held Abroad ) (4) Increase in Foreign Holdings 5 of Assets Located in US ( Foreign Assets Held in US ) (c) Note, again, how the financial and current accounts sum to zero. Notice that eventually there must be a rise in net exports to pay for loan in the first year. Otherwise, the current account will tend to spiral off to minus infinity (think about why this would happen). Examples The lifecycle of a typical person can be used to illustrate the basic ideas in balance of payments. Young people typical run current account deficits: their merchandise imports (i.e., purchases of new homes and consumer durables like cars and appliances) exceed their merchandise exports (i.e., sales of their services). As a result of this negative current account, foreigners (i.e., banks) accumulate claims (e.g., mortgages, car loans) on them, which they have to make payments on (i.e, investment income paid), which adds to the current account deficit. As the person grows older, exports of merchandise increase and they start developing a merchandise trade surplus. Eventually the surplus exceeds the deficit in the current account from investment income paid, and the current account itself turns into a surplus. At this point, the person is starting to accumulate more claims on foreigners than the other way around. Finally, in old age merchandise exports drop to zero when the household retires and income drops to zero. Although at this point there is a huge deficit in net merchandise exports, the 4

current account might nevertheless still be in surplus. This would be the case if the person s investment income exceeded their merchandise imports. For a slightly more detailed treatment of the ideas in this paragraph, see the first set of four figures attached to these notes. This model of the dynamics of the current and financial account is sometimes applied to countries. For example, the US was a young country in the middle of the 19th century when it began its industrial revolution. Merchandise exports were very negative and so was the current account. Foreigners accumulated claims on the US quickly. In the late 19th century, the merchandise trade balance started to go into surplus. However, the current account was still negative because investment income paid to foreigners was large. In the middle 20th century, the US starts to own more assets abroad than foreigners own in the US, so that net investment income is flowing into the country. At that point, the US is able to have a merchandise trade deficitevenwithapositive current account. The attached figures give a sense of the direction of the flow of financial capital in the late 19th century. Note how the rich countries then, Britain, France and Germany, experienced capital outflows (see Figure 58). Domestic absorption in those countries - the amount of domestic output absorbed by domestic consumption, investment and government spending - was less that what was produced. So, goods flowed abroad in the form of positive net exports. The financial counterpart of this is that these countries accumulated financial claims against the countries with which they had export surpluses. That is, these countries experienced a capital outflow. The second set of figures (Figure 59) gives a sense of which countries received those capital inflows: Australia, Sweden, Canada, Norway, US, and Italy. These countries absorbed more goods than they produced and the used the capital inflows to pay for the difference. The bar chart in the third figure (Figure 60) gives a sense of the fraction of investment that was financed by capital inflows in countries that received capital. 1 That this is an interesting statistic is motivated by rewriting the national income identify: I = S CA. When there is a capital inflow, then CA is negative. The left side of the equality indicates how much financing is required. The right side indicates the sources: S is domestic saving and CA(> 0) is foreign saving into domestic financial markets. So, the fraction 1 These figures are taken from the IMF report available on the course website, with the material associated with lecture 1. 5

of investment financed by foreign saving when CA < 0is CA/I. The bar chart in the third set of graphs displays CA/I for several different countries. Note that nearly 25 percent of Australia s investment was financed by capital inflows in the period 1870-1914. In the case of Canada the figure is much higher, nearly 35 percent. Figure 12-2, taken from the text, shows how the net foreign asset positive of the US has moved with the persistently negative current account over the past couple of decades. Thenegativecurrent account has caused the foreign asset position to fall. 2 Exchange Rates (a) Definition: spot exchange rate, s = units of domestic currency needed to buy one unit of foreign currency. Appreciation: s, Depreciation: s. This is the usual definition of s. See the first of the last two attached figures for a graph of the Japanese exchange rate, which emphasizes how volatile the exchange rate is. Although when exchange rates are definedinthe abstract (i.e., without reference to any two particular countries), s always means the domestic currency price of the foreign currency, in practice exceptions are made for individual exchange rates. This is done when, as in the case of the Japanese-Dollar exchange rate, the normal theoretical practice would involve working with tiny numbers. For example, the Japanese-Dollar exchange rate is around 0.008 in the late 1980s, if we use the normal theoretical convention. To avoid having to talk about such difficult-toverbalize numbers, in cases like this the exchange rate is defined as units of the foreign currency per one unit of the domestic currency. This convention is followed in the case of the Japanese exchange rate. So, normally the Japanese exchange rate is presented as it is in the last attached figure. (b) They move around a lot! i. Example 1: US dollar, Japanese Yen 2 During 1982-1985, the exchange rate was roughly s = 250 yen per dollar, after which the dollar depreciated significantly. This is tough on foreigners exporting to the US. Consider a car manufacturer whose costs of making one car is C = 2million yen. Suppose the manufacturer was making 10% profits, i.e., charging 2.2million = (1 + m)c, withm = 0.10. The price in the US of the car is P US =(1+m)C/s =$8, 800. Now, 2 Discussion taken from Backus and Roubini s new book, to be found at http://equity.stern.nyu.edu/ nroubini/notes/chap7.htm#topicx 6

in the (brief!) period, 1985-mid 1986, the dollar depreciated (Yen appreciated) to 150 yen per dollar. The manufacturer has a couple of choices: A. keep the profit margin unchanged and charge (1+m)C/s 0 = $14, 667. In this case, the Japanese car maker can expect to lose a lot of market share in the US. B. keep the US price unchanged. But, then Japanese revenues are $8,800 150 = 1.32million yen. This does not even cover costs, and implies a negative profit margin, as the following algebraic expression shows: sp US C 1=m. Both margins hurt the exporters. As it turned out, the Japanese raised US prices only a little. This did not cost them much market share because US automakers raised prices too. It did notcostalotintermsofprofit margins because of two reasons. First, the Japanese found ways to cut costs. Second, they actually started out the period with very high profit margins(perhapsashighas50%)duetotheeffects of the appreciating dollar that preceded 1982. 7

Current Account (Youth) < 0 (balance on merchandise and services) Credit Debit (1) Exports small Merchandise and Services small Investment Income Received 0 (2) Imports big Merchandise and Services big Investment Income Paid 0 Current Account (Older) < 0 (surplus on mechandise and services) Credit Debit (1) Exports biggest Merchandise and Services biggest Investment Income Received 0 (2) Imports 2big s Merchandise and Services big Investment Income Paid big In Youth, households have small income, but big expenses. Their income is low because this is typical in early career. Expenses are high as they buy a house, purchase furniture, car, higher education, etc. They have no investment income or earnings. When they become a little older their income jumps, say, to biggest > big. They haven t acquired any financial assets, so their investment income is still zero. But, the debts they undertook in youth are catching up to them, so investment income paid is high. Because income from salaries ( exports of services ) is higher than expenditures, households have a surplus on merchandise and services, but still a current account deficit because of the interest on debt that they owe. 6

Current Account (Middle Aged) >0 Credit Debit (1) Exports biggest Merchandise and Services biggest Investment Income Received small (2) Imports 2big s Merchandise and Services Investment Income Paid big small Current Account (Retired) = 0 (big deficit on merchandise and services) Credit Debit (1) Exports big Merchandise and Services 0 Investment Income Received big (2) Imports big Merchandise and Services big Investment Income Paid 0 When households move into middle age, they start to run a positive current account. Part of household debt is paid off, and some assets have been accumulated, which are starting to generate income. Now there are just surpluses. In retirement, the household earns zero on merchandise and services exports but receives a lot on investment income. It still makes big purchases of merchandise and services, but pays out no investment income. This household has a zero current account, and a huge deficit on merchandise and services. In practice, a retired household will actually run a negative current account too, by consuming more than its investment income and running down its assets. This strategy has to be pursued with care. If you live too long and run out of assets, you ve got problems. 7

x 10-3 Fig 1 - Theoretically 'Normal' Way to Represent Exchange Rate: US Dollar Price of One Japanese Yen 11 10 On Average, Dollar Price of Yen Has Gone Up. That is, US Dollar Has Depreciated Since Mid 1990s, US Dollar has Appreciated 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Figure 2 - Customary Way to Present Japanese Exchange Rate: Yen per Dollar 350 Between December, 1975 and October, 1978, Dollar Fell 40 Percent Between February 1985 and March 1988, Value of Dollar Fell 50 Percent 300 250 200 150 100 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005