Informal Financial Markets and Financial Intermediation. in Four African Countries

Similar documents
Ghana : Financial services for women entrepreneurs in the informal sector

Small Enterprise Responses to Liberalization in Five African Countries

Ghana: Bringing Savers and Investors Together

South Africa: Reducing Financial Constraints To Emerging Enterprises

SECTOR ASSESSMENT (SUMMARY): FINANCE 1

Financial Sector Reform and Economic Growth in Zambia- An Overview

Financial markets in developing countries (rough notes, use only as guidance; more details provided in lecture) The role of the financial system

Chapter 15 Finance and Fiscal Policy for Development

Machiko Nissanke 1 and Ernest Aryeetey 2

DETERMINANTS OF AGRICULTURAL CREDIT SUPPLY TO FARMERS IN THE NIGER DELTA AREA OF NIGERIA

Credit, Intermediation and Poverty Reduction

Role of Financial Markets and Institutions

Thought Paper : The Role of Small and Medium Enterprises in Frontier Capital Markets. #2: Financing Challenges Rachel Yon and Daniel Evans

Ghana: Promoting Growth, Reducing Poverty

THE EURO AREA BANK LENDING SURVEY APRIL 2005

Update on the design of the Smallholder and Small and Medium-Sized Enterprise Investment Finance Fund (SIF) at IFAD

Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized

FUTURE OF BUSINESS SURVEY

Précis WORLD BANK OPERATIONS EVALUATION DEPARTMENT SUMMER 1998 N U M B E R 1 6 6

Financing Small Scale Irrigation in Sub-Sahara. Sahara Africa. Key Results from the Kenya Case Study. Wolfgang Hannover Washington DC, 1 March 2007

Rural Financial Intermediaries

The Strategy for Development of the. Microfinance Sector in Sudan. A Central Bank Initiative

Credit Lecture 23. November 20, 2012

Financial Institutions

The Financial Sector Functions of money Medium of exchange Measure of value Store of value Method of deferred payment

Development Economics 855 Lecture Notes 7

PROJECT INFORMATION DOCUMENT (PID) CONCEPT STAGE Report No.: AB5715 Project Name. Cambodia Agribusiness SME Access to Finance Project Region

Informal Credit Markets and the Development of Micro and Small Scale Enterprises in Nigeria

FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS A WORLD BANK POLICY RESEARCH REPORT

Ghana Country Profile Region: Sub-Saharan Africa Income Group: Low income Population: 23,461,523 GNI per capita: US$590.00

Financial Markets and Institutions, 8e (Mishkin) Chapter 2 Overview of the Financial System. 2.1 Multiple Choice

double-clicking on the box) next to the appropriate response and specify if Other ].

Bringing the Poor into the Export Process: Is Access to Finance the Trigger?

International Agricultural Development Policy AGEC 689 Dr. Roger D. Norton. Module 6. Challenges in Agricultural Financial Policy

Central African Republic Country Profile Region: Sub-Saharan Africa Income Group: Low income Population: 4,505,945 GNI per capita: US$460.

Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov

Enterprise Surveys Country Profile Tanzania 2006

Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets, 11e (Mishkin) Chapter 2 An Overview of the Financial System. 2.1 Function of Financial Markets

Enterprise Surveys Country Profile Namibia 2006

Ghanaian Labor Market. Key Trends and Major Policy Issues

International Bank for Reconstruction and Development

Agricultural Credit Policy

ASSESSING THE EFFECTIVENESS OF CREDIT RISK MAN- AGEMENT TECHNIQUES OF MICROFINANCE FIRMS IN ACCRA.

Ex post evaluation Turkey

11th-edition-jeff-madura-test-bank/

Enterprise Surveys Country Profile Botswana 2006

AN EXAMINATION OF THE DETERMINANTS OF INTEREST RATE SPREADS IN GHANA

KEY COMMON CHALLENGES

OPERATIONS MANUAL BANK POLICIES (BP) These policies were prepared for use by ADB staff and are not necessarily a complete treatment of the subject.

Rural Finance. Prof. Franz Heidhues. Universität Hohenheim, Institut 490a

DOES A BIGGER COMMERCIAL BANKING SECTOR BENEFIT THE POOR?

SECTOR ASSESSMENT (SUMMARY): FINANCE

Innovative measures adopted by petty traders in dealing with challenges of accessing financial credit in Ghana

Finance and Guarantees in Rural Development

Ch. 2 AN OVERVIEW OF THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM

CBA Model Question Paper C04

Mapping of Development Partners Support to Leverage Investment to Africa s infrastructure

Module 028. Policy Highlights. Strengthening Rural Financial Systems

Staff Paper December 1991 USE OF CREDIT EVALUATION PROCEDURES AT AGRICULTURAL. Glenn D. Pederson. RM R Chellappan

Microfinance in India: What do we know?

Microfinance Contribution towards the Savings & Borrowings of the Poor in India

Foreign Finance. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Foreign Finance 1 / 48

F i n a n c i a l & B a n k i n g O p e r a t i o n s in Ghana

Financial Institutions, Markets, and Money, 9 th Edition

Public-private Partnerships in Micro-finance: Should NGO Involvement be Restricted?

Development Economics

Impact Assessment of Microfinance For SIDBI Foundation for Micro Credit (SFMC)

Viet Nam: Microfinance Development Program (Subprograms 1 and 2)

Executive Summary The Supply of Financial Services

Financial Markets and Institutions, 9e (Mishkin) Chapter 2 Overview of the Financial System. 2.1 Multiple Choice

MULTINOMIAL LOGISTIC ANALYSIS OF SUSU CONTRIBUTION IN GHANA

Finance Operations CHAPTER OBJECTIVES. The specific objectives of this chapter are to: identify the main sources and uses of finance company funds,

BOGAZICI UNIVERSITY - DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS FALL 2016 EC 344: MONEY, BANKING AND FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS - PROBLEM SET 2 -

AN ECONOMIC STUDY OF INDEBTEDNESS OF THE CLASS IV EMPLOYEES OF BANGLADESH AGRICULTURAL UNIVERSITY

FINANCIAL MARKETS REPORT SUPPLEMENT

Introduction to Factor Markets in the PAM

LUNCHEON ADDRESS: SMALL BUSINESS ACCESS TO CAPITAL AND CREDIT

5 SAVING, CREDIT, AND FINANCIAL RESILIENCE

Ex ante moral hazard on borrowers actions

The Dreyfus Socially Responsible Growth Fund, Inc.

Chapter 3: Diverse Paths to Growth

EVALUATIONS OF MICROFINANCE PROGRAMS

Analysis of Efficiency of Microfinance Providers in Rural Areas of Maharashtra

Chapter Two. Overview of the Financial System

Saving and Investing. Chapter 11 Section Main Menu

Research Note SEGMENTATION AND INTEREST RATE IN RURAL CREDIT MARKETS: SOME EVIDENCE FROM EASTERN UTTAR PRADESH, INDIA

The Conceptual Framework for General Purpose Financial Reporting by Public Sector Entities

ACCOUNTING STANDARDS BOARD

Road Maintenance Financing in Sub-Saharan Africa: Reforms and progress towards second generation road funds

IFRS 9 Readiness for Credit Unions

NATIONAL MICRO-FINANCE POLICY

Saving, Investment, and the Financial System

ENTERPRISE SURVEYS WHAT BUSINESSES EXPERIENCE. Benin 2016 Country Profile ENTERPRISE SURVEYS

Session 3: Construction Finance and Global Financial Market. Professor Fred Moavenzadeh

TUTORIAL KIT OMEGA SEMESTER PROGRAMME: BANKING AND FINANCE COURSE: BFN 121

MARKET-BASED PROJECT COFINANCING

FINANCIAL POLICY FORUM. Washington, D.C PRIMER REPO OR REPURCHASE AGREEMENTS MARKET

Is the Fed's Seasonal Borrowing Privilege Justified? (p. 9)

Lebanon Country Profile 2013

2 Information provided by Yayasan Swadaya Dian Khatulistiwa (YSDK).

Transcription:

Findings reports on ongoing operational, economic and sector work carried out by the World Bank and its member governments in the Africa Region. It is published periodically by the Knowledge Networks, Information and Technology Center on behalf of the Region. Informal Financial Markets and Financial Intermediation in Four African Countries What role can informal financial institutions play in financial development in African countries? A study of both informal and formal financial markets in Ghana, Malawi, Nigeria and Tanzania, Financial Market Fragmentation and Reform in Sub-Saharan Africa, shows that informal institutions use specialized methods to serve broad segments of the population that lack access to banks. Although they have responded positively in a liberalized environment, fragmentation into isolated market segments persists. Greater efforts are needed to integrate informal institutions into financial development strategies. Framework Costs and risks vary in serving different categories of clients, which constitute different segments of any financial system. Specializa-tion of financial institutions for different segments can be efficient if they are well integrated through flows of funds between them and through access of clients to alternative sources of finance. In such a situation, interest rates differences across segments are determined by differences in cost and risk profiles. Financial systems can be described as fragmented when linkages between segments are weak and wide differences occur in risk-adjusted returns. African financial systems have historically been fragmented into dualistic markets, with little connection between formal banks and informal agents and little overlap in clientele. The resulting inefficiencies inhibit development, as potential household savings go untapped and profitable investments cannot be financed. The study investigated structural problems such as imperfect information and costly contract enforcement and institutional weaknesses in banking systems and the legal framework that

cause wide differences across lenders in the costs of screening, monitoring and enforcing loans. Poor information systems in low-income countries raise the cost to formal institutions of acquiring information on any but the largest clients. In contrast, informal agents utilize personal relationships, social sanctions and various collateral substitutes to serve market segments that remain beyond the reach of formal banks. Background Data were collected on informal financial institutions in Ghana (90 observations), Malawi (70), Nigeria (64) and Tanzania (59) during 1992 and 1993. Questionnaires sought information on the agents themselves, portfolio characteristics, interest rates, risk management, transaction costs, delinquency, and linkages to other institutions. Comparable data were obtained from formal financial institutions, including the major commercial and development banks and a representative sample of rural and community banks. Pre-reform policies in all four countries shared repressive characteristics such as: restriction on market entry, often coupled with public ownership; interest rate ceilings, quantitative controls on credit allocation; and restrictions on capital transactions with the rest of the world. Financial sector reforms emphasized liberalization of these policies along with balance sheet restructuring and strengthened regulatory and supervisory frameworks. Ghana and Malawi pursued reforms more systematically than Nigeria or Tanzania. All of the countries initiated reforms during the period 1985-87, although implementation in Tanzania was slow before 1991. Characteristics of Informal Institutions Informal financial transactions can be defined as financial activities that are not regulated by central bank supervisory authorities. Unlike formal institutions, such transactions rarely use legal documentation or the legal system to enforce contracts. One category of informal agents specializes for either the credit or the savings side of the market. Another bases the financial transaction on personal or business relationships. A third category provides full financial intermediation between savers and borrowers. Organizations that are registered under nonfinancial legislation, for example as cooperatives, businesses or non-governmental organizations (NGOs), are sometimes referred to as 'semi-formal.' Informal financial agents in the sample tended to be well-educated relative to real informal sector workers and were generally in their mid-40s. Overall, about 60% of those sampled had attended secondary or other post-primary school. In Nigeria, savings collectors averaged 7.2 years of school, moneylenders 10.5, leaders of savings and credit cooperatives or associations (SCCs) 14.0, and organizers of rotating savings and credit associations (ROSCAs) 16.8. Individual lenders and savings collectors were predominantly men, while women were more likely to be leading ROSCAs (46% in Ghana, 57% in Tanzania, 80% in Nigeria). Operating on One Side of the Market 'Moneylending' covers a wide range of financial arrangements with interest rates varying from

0-100 % a month. The most common source of informal finance (usually interest-free) is from relatives and friends. This type was not covered in the survey because of its non-commercial character. While a few registered, professional moneylenders exist, most of the commercial moneylending is undertaken as a part-time activity, using surplus funds from other sources such as a trading business. Individuals who operate primarily on the savings side were found only in West Africa. These savings collectors take regular deposits (often daily or weekly) of an amount determined by each client and return the accumulated sum at the end of a stipulated period (usually a month), minus 1 day's deposit as commission. These 'mobile bankers' form a symbiotic relationship with market traders, protecting their daily earnings from competing claims and ensuring working capital to restock supplies at the end of the month. They sometimes extend 'advances' to their clients before the end of the month and occasionally lend to non-clients, though lending is constrained by their lack of a capital base other than monthly collections. Relationship-based ROSCAs were pervasive in all the countries studied. These are known variously as susu in Ghana, esusu or ato in Nigeria, chilemba or chiperegani in Malawi, upatu or mchezo in Tanzania, and tontiniers in francophone countries. ROSCAs are closed membership groups where all members pay set amounts at regular intervals (monthly, weekly, daily) to a common pool, which is handed over to each member in turn (randomly or by bidding). All recipients but the last receive the pooled sum sooner that if they had saved the same amounts alone. Some continue over long periods and develop supplementary insurance, loan and welfare funds or save toward a common objective. Traders often supply inputs or cash advances to farmers, linked to purchase of produce at a discounted price. In Malawi and Tanzania, landlords and estate owners often lend to their tenants. Intermediaries SCCs raise savings from and make loans to members. A variety of membership organizations come under this heading, sometimes raising money from shares as well as deposits. Unlike ROSCAs, they are relatively large and open to new members. They may be legally registered as a cooperative or the savings and credit arm of a cooperative formed for other purposes. Credit unions are registered as such and represent a more formal form of SCCs based on share capital. They are increasingly coming under the regulation of central bank authorities under non-bank financial institution legislation. Other semi-formal institutions have emerged that both mobilize and lend funds to the general public. In Ghana, susu companies were registered businesses that utilized susu collector techniques to mobilize savings by promising credit to those who accumulated over a period of 6 months or more. Nigeria's finance houses-private investment companies registered under the Companies Act-were sometimes used to take advantage of exchange rate controls. In both cases, questionable management practices and pyramid-like schemes led to the collapse of

many of these institutions. In Ghana, a new savings and loan variant has emerged under the 1993 Non-Bank Financial Institutions Law. Most NGOs with credit programs in the sample countries have historically had a welfare orientation with heavy external subsidies, and were excluded from the survey's focus on indigenous commercially-oriented informal finance. A growing number, however, are attempting to operate on a commercial and financially sustainable basis, often using informal techniques such as group-based lending. They may be able to play a growing role in financial intermediation for lower-income households and microenterprises. Informal Methodologies Informal lenders succeed through information based on personal and social networks. They use bilateral, character-based relationships to achieve high repayment rates without relying on formal collateral and project appraisals. They pre-screen clients by focusing on specific groups. By focusing on a narrow niche of known clients, they avoid the high processing and monitoring costs that deter banks. Informal methods yield loan administration costs that are, surprisingly, below those of banks operating much larger loans. Whereas banks reported operating costs on the order of 12% to 19% of amounts lent, informal moneylenders and associations were generally under 3% (partly because they carried little overhead costs). Furthermore, repayment rates tended to be higher for informal lenders. At least 80% of informal agents in Ghana and Nigeria reported no delinquent borrowers, and all expected virtually 100% repayment within three months of the due date. Thus, the data indicated that informal agents bore lower relative costs and losses on their small loans than banks did on larger ones, contrary to the common perception that small loans are costly and risky. With appropriate methods, it is possible to efficiently serve market niches that are excluded by the methods of commercial banks. The principal limitation is that informal agents tend to operate on only one side of the market or within a circumscribed group. Savings collectors' funds come entirely from their clients, while moneylenders use their own funds and do not borrow to increase their loanable funds, even though many are creditworthy. ROSCAs have access only to their own savings. Very little intermediation occurs in terms of mobilizing funds from savers and transmitting them to borrowers in other groups. The isolated, personalized nature of informal relationships can provide substantial monopoly power (especially when the legal framework restricts moneylending), resulting in wide differences in interest rates across different segments within the formal sector. Impact of Financial Sector Reforms The countries studied undertook financial sector liberalization in the late 1980s and early 1990s to introduce market forces, reduce public sector domination of banking assets and liabilities, increase competition, and raise efficiency. These measures were often accompanied by restructuring, recapitalization, and improved regulation to rehabilitate banking systems in

crisis. While banking systems are being strengthened through better supervision, they have so far tended to focus on their best clients to improve portfolio performance, rather than reach out to new, smaller clients. Banks continue to have difficulty with small transactions because of high costs, perceived risks, collateral-based methodologies, and strong incentives to lend to the public sector. Any efficiency gains have not yet been reflected in lower interest spreads, and interest rates often remain high under the pressure of public budget deficit financing. Informal financial institutions have responded more positively, with increases in the number of approvals, as well as applications, in many cases. The assets of informal lenders and savings collectors increased following liberalization because of their linkages with expanding real sectors. For example, moneylenders are often traders with excess short-term liquidity. Nevertheless, many informal agents reported being unable to satisfy demand for loans by clients they considered creditworthy. A financial gap remains for small businesses, which generally need larger loans at lower rates than informal agents can provide but lack the track record and collateral necessary to access bank loans. However, some new financial institutions are beginning to emerge with the potential to respond to excess demand for credit that is being satisfied by neither formal nor informal sectors. In Ghana and Nigeria, in particular, there has been a steady emergence of formal non-bank financial intermediaries-discount houses, leasing companies, finance companies, etc. Conclusion Informal institutions use specialized techniques to address the problems of information, transaction costs and risks in serving households and micro businesses that prevent banks from serving these market segments in African countries. But the high localization of informal agents and lack of access to formal finance limits the extent of financial intermediation by informal agents. Hence it is important both to include informal institutions in financial development strategies and to link them more closely with the formal financial system in order to both increase savings mobilization and make more funds available to high-return investments in informal activities. Based on Discussion Paper No. 356, Financial Market Fragmentation and Reforms in Sub- Saharan Africa by Ernest Aryeetey, Hemamala Hettige, Machiko Nissanke and William Steel, 1996. World Bank, Washington D.C. For further information, please contact William Steel, Room J4-085, World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington D.C. 20433. Tel. no.: (202) 4734831. On the Internet, please contact pmohan@worldbank.org For copies of the report, please contact P.C.Mohan, Rm. J5-171, World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, D.C. 20433. Tel. no.: (202) 474-4114. Internet address: pmohan@worldbank.org