Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Similar documents
Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Optimal Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a Liquidity Trap

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Optimal Inflation Targeting Under Alternative Fiscal Regimes

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Reserve Requirements and Optimal Chinese Stabilization Policy 1

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Unconventional Monetary Policy

The science of monetary policy

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

A Model of Financial Intermediation

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Nobel Symposium Money and Banking

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

The New Keynesian Model

A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Inflation in the Great Recession and New Keynesian Models

Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom? Martin Uribe and Vivian Yue (JIE, 2006)

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Fiscal Policy Stabilization: Purchases or Transfers?

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Monetary Macroeconomics & Central Banking Lecture /

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL MONETARY STABILIZATION POLICY. Michael Woodford. Working Paper

Uninsured Unemployment Risk and Optimal Monetary Policy

Optimality of Inflation and Nominal Output Targeting

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

Loan Securitization and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

Recently the study of optimal monetary policy has shifted from an

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Escaping the Great Recession 1

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Optimal Interest-Rate Rules: I. General Theory

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Advanced Topics in Monetary Economics II 1

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

Strategic Complementarities and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SIMPLE ANALYTICS OF THE GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIER. Michael Woodford

Macroeconomic Models. with Financial Frictions

Monetary policy and the asset risk-taking channel

1. Borrowing Constraints on Firms The Financial Accelerator

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

Learning and the Effectiveness of Central Bank Forward Guidance

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

Changes in the Inflation Target and the Comovement between Inflation and the Nominal Interest Rate

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

Household Leverage, Housing Markets, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Reserve Requirements and Optimal Chinese Stabilization Policy 1

Strategic Complementarities and Optimal Monetary Policy

DISCUSSION OF NON-INFLATIONARY DEMAND DRIVEN BUSINESS CYCLES, BY BEAUDRY AND PORTIER. 1. Introduction

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

3 Optimal Inflation-Targeting Rules

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Transcription:

MACRO-LINKAGES, OIL PRICES AND DEFLATION WORKSHOP JANUARY 6 9, 2009 Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University IMF Research Department Macro-Modeling Workshop Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 1 / 39

Motivation New Keynesian monetary models often abstract entirely from financial intermediation and hence from financial frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 2 / 39

Motivation New Keynesian monetary models often abstract entirely from financial intermediation and hence from financial frictions Representative household Complete (frictionless) financial markets Single interest rate (which is also the policy rate) relevant for all decisions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 2 / 39

Motivation New Keynesian monetary models often abstract entirely from financial intermediation and hence from financial frictions Representative household Complete (frictionless) financial markets Single interest rate (which is also the policy rate) relevant for all decisions But in actual economies (even financially sophisticated), there are different interest rates, that do not move perfectly together Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 2 / 39

3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 Spreads (Sources: FRB) Q4:1986 Q2:1987 Q4:1987 Q2:1988 Q4:1988 Q2:1989 Q4:1989 Q2:1990 Q4:1990 Q2:1991 Q4:1991 Q2:1992 Q4:1992 Q2:1993 Q4:1993 Q2:1994 Q4:1994 Q2:1995 Q4:1995 Q2:1996 Q4:1996 Q2:1997 Q4:1997 Q2:1998 Q4:1998 Q2:1999 Q4:1999 Q2:2000 Q4:2000 Q2:2001 Q4:2001 Q2:2002 Q4:2002 Q2:2003 Q4:2003 Q2:2004 Q4:2004 Q2:2005 Q4:2005 Q2:2006 Q4:2006 Q2:2007 Q4:2007 Q2:2008 Q4:2008 % Prime Spread to FF C&I Spread to FF

380 360 340 320 300 280 260 240 220 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 USD LIBOR-OIS Spreads (Source: Bloomberg) 01/04/05 03/04/05 05/04/05 07/04/05 09/04/05 11/04/05 01/04/06 03/04/06 05/04/06 07/04/06 09/04/06 11/04/06 01/04/07 03/04/07 05/04/07 07/04/07 09/04/07 11/04/07 01/04/08 03/04/08 05/04/08 07/04/08 09/04/08 11/04/08 basis points 1M 3M 6M

7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 LIBOR 1m vs FFR target (source: Bloomberg and Federal Reserve Board) % 1/2/2007 2/2/2007 3/2/2007 4/2/2007 5/2/2007 6/2/2007 7/2/2007 8/2/2007 9/2/2007 10/2/2007 11/2/2007 12/2/2007 1/2/2008 2/2/2008 3/2/2008 4/2/2008 5/2/2008 6/2/2008 7/2/2008 8/2/2008 9/2/2008 10/2/2008 11/2/2008 12/2/2008 LIBOR 1m FFR target

Motivation Questions: How much is monetary policy analysis changed by recognizing existence of spreads between different interest rates? How should policy respond to financial shocks that disrupt financial intermediation, dramatically widening spreads? Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 3 / 39

Motivation John Taylor (Feb. 2008) has proposed that Taylor rule for policy might reasonably be adjusted, lowering ff rate target by amount of increase in LIBOR-OIS spread Essentially, Taylor rule would specify operating target for LIBOR rate rather than ff rate Would imply automatic adjustment of ff rate in response to spread variations, as under current SNB policy Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 4 / 39

3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 SNB Interest rates (source: SNB) % 1/3/2007 2/3/2007 3/3/2007 4/3/2007 5/3/2007 6/3/2007 7/3/2007 8/3/2007 9/3/2007 10/3/2007 11/3/2007 12/3/2007 1/3/2008 2/3/2008 3/3/2008 4/3/2008 5/3/2008 6/3/2008 7/3/2008 8/3/2008 9/3/2008 10/3/2008 11/3/2008 12/3/2008 Repo O/N Index LIBOR 3m LIBOR Target Lower Bound LIBOR Target Upper Bound

Motivation John Taylor (Feb. 2008) has proposed that Taylor rule for policy might reasonably be adjusted, lowering ff rate target by amount of increase in LIBOR-OIS spread Essentially, Taylor rule would specify operating target for LIBOR rate rather than ff rate Would imply automatic adjustment of ff rate in response to spread variations, as under current SNB policy Is a systematic response of that kind desirable? Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 5 / 39

The Model Generalizes basic (representative household) NK model to include Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 6 / 39

The Model Generalizes basic (representative household) NK model to include heterogeneity in spending opportunities costly financial intermediation Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 6 / 39

The Model Generalizes basic (representative household) NK model to include heterogeneity in spending opportunities costly financial intermediation Each household has a type τ t (i) {b, s}, determining preferences 1 ] E 0 β [u t τt(i) (c t (i); ξ t ) v τt(i) (h t (j; i) ; ξ t ) dj, t=0 0 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 6 / 39

The Model Generalizes basic (representative household) NK model to include heterogeneity in spending opportunities costly financial intermediation Each household has a type τ t (i) {b, s}, determining preferences 1 ] E 0 β [u t τt(i) (c t (i); ξ t ) v τt(i) (h t (j; i) ; ξ t ) dj, t=0 0 Each period type remains same with probability δ < 1; when draw new type, always probability π τ of becoming type τ Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 6 / 39

The Model 5 4 3 λ b 2 λ s u b c (c) 1 u s c (c) 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2 c c s b Marginal utilities of the two types Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 7 / 39

The Model Aggregation simplified by assuming intermittent access to an insurance agency Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 8 / 39

The Model Aggregation simplified by assuming intermittent access to an insurance agency State-contingent contracts enforceable only on those occasions Other times, can borrow or lend only through intermediaries, at a one-period, riskless nominal rate, different for savers and borrowers Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 8 / 39

The Model Aggregation simplified by assuming intermittent access to an insurance agency State-contingent contracts enforceable only on those occasions Other times, can borrow or lend only through intermediaries, at a one-period, riskless nominal rate, different for savers and borrowers Consequence: long-run marginal utility of income same for all households, regardless of history of spending opportunities Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 8 / 39

The Model Aggregation simplified by assuming intermittent access to an insurance agency State-contingent contracts enforceable only on those occasions Other times, can borrow or lend only through intermediaries, at a one-period, riskless nominal rate, different for savers and borrowers Consequence: long-run marginal utility of income same for all households, regardless of history of spending opportunities MUI and expenditure same each period for all households of a given type: hence only increase state variables from 1 to 2 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 8 / 39

The Model Euler equation for each type τ {b, s}: { 1 + i λt τ τ } = βe t t [δλt+1 τ + (1 δ)λ t+1 ] Π t+1 where λ t π b λ b t + π s λ s t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 9 / 39

The Model Euler equation for each type τ {b, s}: { 1 + i λt τ τ } = βe t t [δλt+1 τ + (1 δ)λ t+1 ] Π t+1 where λ t π b λ b t + π s λ s t Aggregate demand relation: Y t = π τ c τ (λt τ ; ξ t ) + G t + Ξ t τ where Ξ t denotes resources used in intermediation Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 9 / 39

Log-Linear Equations Intertemporal IS relation: Ŷ t = E t Ŷ t+1 σ[î avg t π t+1 ] E t [ g t+1 + ˆΞ t+1 ] where σs Ω ˆΩ t + σ(s Ω + ψ Ω )E t ˆΩ t+1, î avg t π b î b t + π s î d t, ˆΩ t ˆλ b t ˆλ s t, g t is a composite exogenous disturbance to expenditure of type b, type s, and government, σ π b s b σ b + π s s s σ s > 0, and s Ω, ψ Ω depend on asymmetry Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 10 / 39

Log-Linear Equations Determination of the marginal-utility gap: where ˆδ < 1 and ˆΩ t = ˆω t + ˆδE t ˆΩ t+1, ˆω t î b t î d t measures deviation of the credit spread from its steady-state value Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 11 / 39

The Model Financial intermediation technology: in order to supply loans in (real) quantity b t, must obtain (real) deposits d t = b t + Ξ t (b t ), where Ξ t (0) = 0, Ξ t (b) 0, Ξ t(b) 0, Ξ t (b) 0 for all b 0, each date t. Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 12 / 39

The Model Financial intermediation technology: in order to supply loans in (real) quantity b t, must obtain (real) deposits d t = b t + Ξ t (b t ), where Ξ t (0) = 0, Ξ t (b) 0, Ξ t(b) 0, Ξ t (b) 0 for all b 0, each date t. Competitive banking sector would then imply equilibrium credit spread ω t (b t ) = Ξ bt (b t ) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 12 / 39

The Model Financial intermediation technology: in order to supply loans in (real) quantity b t, must obtain (real) deposits d t = b t + Ξ t (b t ), where Ξ t (0) = 0, Ξ t (b) 0, Ξ t(b) 0, Ξ t (b) 0 for all b 0, each date t. Competitive banking sector would then imply equilibrium credit spread ω t (b t ) = Ξ bt (b t ) More generally, we allow 1 + ω t (b t ) = µ b t (b t )(1 + Ξ bt (b t )), where {µ b t } is a markup in the banking sector (perhaps a risk premium) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 12 / 39

BGG Example Example of a (microfounded) intermediation technology of this general form: CSV model as in Bernanke-Gertler-Gilchrist (1999) but with the financial contracting between savers and intermediaries, rather than households and entrepreneurs Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 13 / 39

BGG Example Example of a (microfounded) intermediation technology of this general form: CSV model as in Bernanke-Gertler-Gilchrist (1999) but with the financial contracting between savers and intermediaries, rather than households and entrepreneurs Key relation of this model: k t = ψ(s t ; µ t ) where k t = leverage ratio of banks = b t /n t n t = net worth of banks; s t = external finance premium = 1 + ω t µ t = (exogenously varying) bankruptcy costs Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 13 / 39

BGG Example Can alternatively write: 1 + ω t = ψ 1 (b t /n t ; µ t ) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 14 / 39

BGG Example Can alternatively write: 1 + ω t = ψ 1 (b t /n t ; µ t ) Resources used in intermediation: bankruptcy costs also a function of µ t and b t /n t (which determine fraction of states in which bankruptcy occurs) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 14 / 39

BGG Example Can alternatively write: 1 + ω t = ψ 1 (b t /n t ; µ t ) Resources used in intermediation: bankruptcy costs also a function of µ t and b t /n t (which determine fraction of states in which bankruptcy occurs) Purely financial disturbances: exogenous variation in n t, µ t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 14 / 39

Log-Linear Equations Monetary policy: central bank can effectively control deposit rate i d t, which in the present model is equivalent to the policy rate (interbank funding rate) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 15 / 39

Log-Linear Equations Monetary policy: central bank can effectively control deposit rate i d t, which in the present model is equivalent to the policy rate (interbank funding rate) Lending rate then determined by the ω t (b t ): in log-linear approximation, î b t = î d t + ˆω t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 15 / 39

Log-Linear Equations Monetary policy: central bank can effectively control deposit rate i d t, which in the present model is equivalent to the policy rate (interbank funding rate) Lending rate then determined by the ω t (b t ): in log-linear approximation, î b t = î d t + ˆω t Hence the rate î avg t that appears in IS relation is determined by î avg t = î d t + π b ˆω t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 15 / 39

The Model Supply side of model: same as in basic NK model, except must aggregate labor supply of two types Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 16 / 39

The Model Supply side of model: same as in basic NK model, except must aggregate labor supply of two types Only difference: labor supply depends on both MUI: λ b t, λ s t, or alternatively on Ω t as well as λ t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 16 / 39

Log-Linear Equations Log-linear AS relation: generalizes NKPC: π t = κ(ŷ t Ŷt n ) + u t + ξ(s Ω + π b γ b ) ˆΩ t ξ σ 1 ˆΞ t +βe t π t+1 where ( λ γ b b ) 1/ν π b λ depends on Ω Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 17 / 39

Log-Linear Equations Log-linear AS relation: generalizes NKPC: π t = κ(ŷ t Ŷt n ) + u t + ξ(s Ω + π b γ b ) ˆΩ t ξ σ 1 ˆΞ t +βe t π t+1 where ( λ γ b b ) 1/ν π b λ depends on Ω other coefficients, and disturbance terms Ŷ n t, u t, defined as in basic NK model, using σ in place of the rep hh s elasticity Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 17 / 39

Optimal Policy Natural objective for stabilization policy: average expected utility: where E 0 t=0 βu(y t, λ b t, λ s t, t ; ξ t ) U(Y t, λ b t, λ s t, t ; ξ t ) π b u b (c b (λ b t ; ξ t ); ξ t ) + π s u s (c s (λ s t; ξ t ); ξ t ) ψ ( ) 1+ν ( ) λ ν 1+ω t H t 1 + ν Λ Yt t, t and λ t / Λ t is a decreasing function of λ b t /λ s t, so that total disutility of producing given output is increasing function of the MU gap A t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 18 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Compute a quadratic approximation to this welfare measure, in the case of small fluctuations around the optimal steady state Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 19 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Compute a quadratic approximation to this welfare measure, in the case of small fluctuations around the optimal steady state Results especially simple in special case: No steady-state distortion to level of output (P = MC, W/P = MRS)(Rotemberg-Woodford, 1997) No steady-state credit frictions: ω = Ξ = Ξ b = 0 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 19 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Compute a quadratic approximation to this welfare measure, in the case of small fluctuations around the optimal steady state Results especially simple in special case: No steady-state distortion to level of output (P = MC, W/P = MRS)(Rotemberg-Woodford, 1997) No steady-state credit frictions: ω = Ξ = Ξ b = 0 Note, however, that we do allow for shocks to the size of credit frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 19 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Approximate objective: max of expected utility equivalent (to 2d order) to minimization of quadratic loss function β t [πt 2 + λ y (Ŷ t Ŷt n ) 2 + λ Ω ˆΩ 2 t + λ Ξ Ξ bt ˆb t ] t=0 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 20 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Approximate objective: max of expected utility equivalent (to 2d order) to minimization of quadratic loss function β t [πt 2 + λ y (Ŷ t Ŷt n ) 2 + λ Ω ˆΩ 2 t + λ Ξ Ξ bt ˆb t ] t=0 Weight λ y > 0, definition of natural rate Ŷt n NK model same as in basic Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 20 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Approximate objective: max of expected utility equivalent (to 2d order) to minimization of quadratic loss function β t [πt 2 + λ y (Ŷ t Ŷt n ) 2 + λ Ω ˆΩ 2 t + λ Ξ Ξ bt ˆb t ] t=0 Weight λ y > 0, definition of natural rate Ŷt n NK model New weights λ Ω, λ Ξ > 0 same as in basic Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 20 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Approximate objective: max of expected utility equivalent (to 2d order) to minimization of quadratic loss function β t [πt 2 + λ y (Ŷ t Ŷt n ) 2 + λ Ω ˆΩ 2 t + λ Ξ Ξ bt ˆb t ] t=0 Weight λ y > 0, definition of natural rate Ŷt n NK model New weights λ Ω, λ Ξ > 0 same as in basic LQ problem: minimize loss function subject to log-linear constraints: AS relation, IS relation, law of motion for ˆb t, relation between ˆΩ t and expected credit spreads Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 20 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Consider special case: No resources used in intermediation (Ξ t (b) = 0) Financial markup {µ b t } an exogenous process Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 21 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Consider special case: No resources used in intermediation (Ξ t (b) = 0) Financial markup {µ b t } an exogenous process Result: optimal policy is characterized by the same target criterion as in basic NK model: Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 21 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Consider special case: No resources used in intermediation (Ξ t (b) = 0) Financial markup {µ b t } an exogenous process Result: optimal policy is characterized by the same target criterion as in basic NK model: π t + (λ y /κ)(x t x t 1 ) = 0 ( flexible inflation targeting ) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 21 / 39

Optimal Policy: LQ Approximation Consider special case: No resources used in intermediation (Ξ t (b) = 0) Financial markup {µ b t } an exogenous process Result: optimal policy is characterized by the same target criterion as in basic NK model: π t + (λ y /κ)(x t x t 1 ) = 0 ( flexible inflation targeting ) However, state-contingent path of policy rate required to implement the target criterion is not the same Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 21 / 39

Implementing Optimal Policy: Interest-Rate Rule Instrument rule to implement the above target criterion: Given lagged variables, current exogenous shocks, and observed current expectations of future inflation and output, solve the AS and IS relations for target it d that would imply values of π t and x t projected to satisfy the target relation Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 22 / 39

Implementing Optimal Policy: Interest-Rate Rule Instrument rule to implement the above target criterion: Given lagged variables, current exogenous shocks, and observed current expectations of future inflation and output, solve the AS and IS relations for target it d that would imply values of π t and x t projected to satisfy the target relation What Evans-Honkapohja (2003) call expectations-based rule for implementation of optimal policy Desirable properties: ensures that there are no REE other than those in which the target criterion holds hence ensures determinacy of REE in this example, also implies E-stability of REE, hence convergence of least-squares learning dynamics to REE Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 22 / 39

Implementing Optimal Policy: Interest-Rate Rule i d t = r n t + φ u u t + [1 + βφ u ]E t π t+1 + σ 1 E t x t+1 φ x x t 1 [π b + ˆδ 1 s Ω ] ˆω t + [( ˆδ 1 1) + φ u ξ]s Ω ˆΩ t where φ u κ σ(κ 2 +λ y ) > 0, φ x λ y σ(κ 2 +λ y ) > 0 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 23 / 39

Implementing Optimal Policy: Interest-Rate Rule i d t = r n t + φ u u t + [1 + βφ u ]E t π t+1 + σ 1 E t x t+1 φ x x t 1 [π b + ˆδ 1 s Ω ] ˆω t + [( ˆδ 1 1) + φ u ξ]s Ω ˆΩ t where φ u κ σ(κ 2 +λ y ) > 0, φ x λ y σ(κ 2 +λ y ) > 0 a forward-looking Taylor rule, with adjustments proportional to both the credit spread and the marginal-utility gap Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 23 / 39

Implementing Optimal Policy: Interest-Rate Rule Note that if s b σ b >> s s σ s, then s Ω π s, so that if in addition δ 1, the rule becomes approximately i d t =... ˆω t + φ Ω ˆΩ t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 24 / 39

Implementing Optimal Policy: Interest-Rate Rule Note that if s b σ b >> s s σ s, then s Ω π s, so that if in addition δ 1, the rule becomes approximately i d t =... ˆω t + φ Ω ˆΩ t Since for our calibration, φ Ω is also quite small (.03), this implies that a 100 percent spread adjustment would be close to optimal, except in the case of very persistent fluctuations in the credit spread Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 24 / 39

Implementing Optimal Policy: Interest-Rate Rule Essentially, in the case that s b σ b >> s s σ s, it is really only i b t that matters much to the economy, and the simple intuition for the spread adjustment is reasonably accurate. Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 25 / 39

Implementing Optimal Policy: Interest-Rate Rule Essentially, in the case that s b σ b >> s s σ s, it is really only i b t that matters much to the economy, and the simple intuition for the spread adjustment is reasonably accurate. But for other parameterizations that would not be true. For example, if s b σ b = s s σ s, the optimal rule is i d t =... π b ˆω t which is effectively an instrument rule in terms of it avg than either it d or it b rather Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 25 / 39

Optimal Policy: Numerical Results Above target criterion no longer an exact characterization of optimal policy, in more general case in which ω t and/or Ξ t depend on the evolution of b t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 26 / 39

Optimal Policy: Numerical Results Above target criterion no longer an exact characterization of optimal policy, in more general case in which ω t and/or Ξ t depend on the evolution of b t But numerical results suggest still a fairly good approximation to optimal policy Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 26 / 39

Calibrated Model Calibration of preference heterogeneity: assume equal probability of two types, π b = π s = 0.5, and δ = 0.975 (average time that type persists = 10 years) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 27 / 39

Calibrated Model Calibration of preference heterogeneity: assume equal probability of two types, π b = π s = 0.5, and δ = 0.975 (average time that type persists = 10 years) Assume C b /C s = 1.27 in steady state (given G /Y = 0.3, this implies C s /Y 0.62, C b /Y 0.78) implied steady-state debt: b/ȳ = 0.8 years (avg non-fin, non-gov t, non-mortgage debt/gdp) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 27 / 39

Calibrated Model Calibration of preference heterogeneity: assume equal probability of two types, π b = π s = 0.5, and δ = 0.975 (average time that type persists = 10 years) Assume C b /C s = 1.27 in steady state (given G /Y = 0.3, this implies C s /Y 0.62, C b /Y 0.78) implied steady-state debt: b/ȳ = 0.8 years (avg non-fin, non-gov t, non-mortgage debt/gdp) Assume relative disutility of labor for two types so that in steady state H b /H s = 1 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 27 / 39

Calibrated Model Assume σ b /σ s = 5 implies credit contracts in response to monetary policy tightening (consistent with VAR evidence [esp. credit to households]) Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 28 / 39

Calibrated Model Calibration of financial frictions: Resource costs Ξ t (b) = Ξ t b η, exogenous markup µ b t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 29 / 39

Calibrated Model Calibration of financial frictions: Resource costs Ξ t (b) = Ξ t b η, exogenous markup µ b t Zero steady-state markup; resource costs imply steady-state credit spread ω = 2.0 percent per annum (follows Mehra, Piguillem, Prescott) implies λ b / λ s = 1.22 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 29 / 39

Calibrated Model Calibration of financial frictions: Resource costs Ξ t (b) = Ξ t b η, exogenous markup µ b t Zero steady-state markup; resource costs imply steady-state credit spread ω = 2.0 percent per annum (follows Mehra, Piguillem, Prescott) implies λ b / λ s = 1.22 Calibrate η in convex-technology case so that 1 percent increase in volume of bank credit raises credit spread by 1 percent (ann.) implies η 52 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 29 / 39

Numerical Results: Alternative Policy Rules Compute responses to shocks under optimal (i.e., Ramsey) policy, compare to responses under 3 simple rules: Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 30 / 39

Numerical Results: Alternative Policy Rules Compute responses to shocks under optimal (i.e., Ramsey) policy, compare to responses under 3 simple rules: simple Taylor rule: î d t = φ π π t + φ y Ŷ t Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 30 / 39

Numerical Results: Alternative Policy Rules Compute responses to shocks under optimal (i.e., Ramsey) policy, compare to responses under 3 simple rules: simple Taylor rule: î d t = φ π π t + φ y Ŷ t strict inflation targeting: π t = 0 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 30 / 39

Numerical Results: Alternative Policy Rules Compute responses to shocks under optimal (i.e., Ramsey) policy, compare to responses under 3 simple rules: simple Taylor rule: î d t = φ π π t + φ y Ŷ t strict inflation targeting: π t = 0 flexible inflation targeting: π t + (λ y /κ)(x t x t 1 ) = 0 Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 30 / 39

Numerical Results: Optimal Policy Y 0 2 0.2 1 0.4 π 0 0 4 8 12 16 0.6 0 4 8 12 16 0 i d 0 i b 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.2 0.4 0 4 8 12 16 0 4 8 12 16 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 4 8 12 16 b Optimal PiStab Taylor FlexTarget Responses to technology shock, under 4 monetary policies Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 31 / 39

Numerical Results: Optimal Policy 0 0.5 1 1.5 0 4 8 12 16 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 Y i d 0 0 4 8 12 16 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0.3 0.2 0.1 π 0 4 8 12 16 i b 0 0 4 8 12 16 b 0 0.05 Optimal PiStab Taylor FlexTarget 0.1 0 4 8 12 16 Responses to wage markup shock, under 4 monetary policies Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 32 / 39

Numerical Results: Optimal Policy 0.3 0.2 0.1 Y 0 0 4 8 12 16 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 i d 0 0 4 8 12 16 0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0 4 8 12 16 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 4 8 12 16 π i b b 0 0.02 0.04 Optimal PiStab Taylor FlexTarget 0 4 8 12 16 Responses to shock to government purchases, under 4 monetary policies Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 33 / 39

Numerical Results: Optimal Policy 0.1 Y 0.01 0.005 π 0.05 0 0 4 8 12 16 0 0.005 0.01 0 4 8 12 16 0.1 i d 0.06 i b 0.05 0.04 0.02 0 0.01 0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0 4 8 12 16 0.04 0 4 8 12 16 b 0 0 4 8 12 16 Optimal PiStab Taylor FlexTarget Responses to shock to demand of savers, under 4 monetary policies Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 34 / 39

Numerical Results: Optimal Policy 0.1 0.05 Y 0 0 4 8 12 16 π 0.01 0.005 0 0.005 0.01 0 4 8 12 16 0.04 0.02 0 0.02 0.01 0 i d 0 4 8 12 16 b 0.04 0.02 0 i b 0 4 8 12 16 Optimal PiStab Taylor FlexTarget 0.01 0 4 8 12 16 Responses to shock to demand of borrowers, under 4 monetary policies Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 35 / 39

Numerical Results: Optimal Policy Y 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0 4 8 12 16 i d 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0 4 8 12 16 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0 4 8 12 16 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 π i b 0 4 8 12 16 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 b 0 4 8 12 16 Optimal PiStab Taylor FlexTarget Responses to financial shock, under 4 monetary policies Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 36 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Time-varying credit spreads do not require fundamental modification of one s view of monetary transmission mechanism Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 37 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Time-varying credit spreads do not require fundamental modification of one s view of monetary transmission mechanism In a special case: the same 3-equation model continues to apply, simply with additional disturbance terms Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 37 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Time-varying credit spreads do not require fundamental modification of one s view of monetary transmission mechanism In a special case: the same 3-equation model continues to apply, simply with additional disturbance terms More generally, a generalization of basic NK model that retains many qualitative features of that model of the transmission mechanism Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 37 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Time-varying credit spreads do not require fundamental modification of one s view of monetary transmission mechanism In a special case: the same 3-equation model continues to apply, simply with additional disturbance terms More generally, a generalization of basic NK model that retains many qualitative features of that model of the transmission mechanism For example, recognizing importance of credit frictions does not require reconsideration of the de-emphasis of monetary aggregates in NK models Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 37 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Spread-adjusted Taylor rule can improve upon standard Taylor rule under some circumstances Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 38 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Spread-adjusted Taylor rule can improve upon standard Taylor rule under some circumstances However, full adjustment to spread increase not generally optimal, and optimal degree of adjustment depends on expected persistence of disturbance to spread Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 38 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Spread-adjusted Taylor rule can improve upon standard Taylor rule under some circumstances However, full adjustment to spread increase not generally optimal, and optimal degree of adjustment depends on expected persistence of disturbance to spread And desirability of spread adjustment depends on change in deposit rate being passed through to lending rates Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 38 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Spread-adjusted Taylor rule can improve upon standard Taylor rule under some circumstances However, full adjustment to spread increase not generally optimal, and optimal degree of adjustment depends on expected persistence of disturbance to spread And desirability of spread adjustment depends on change in deposit rate being passed through to lending rates General principle can be expressed more robustly in terms of a target criterion Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 38 / 39

Provisional Conclusions Simple guideline for policy: base policy decisions on a target criterion relating inflation to output gap (optimal in absence of credit frictions) Take account of credit frictions only in model used to determine policy action required to fulfill target criterion Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions IMF January 2009 39 / 39