WHY DON T LOWER-INCOME INDIVIDUALS HAVE PENSIONS?

Similar documents
IS PENSION INEQUALITY GROWING?

DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE?

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION?

NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: HOW MUCH LONGER DO WE NEED TO WORK?

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE

HOW LONG DO UNEMPLOYED OLDER WORKERS SEARCH FOR A JOB?

WHY DID POVERTY DROP FOR THE ELDERLY?

WHY ARE OLDER WORKERS AT GREATER RISK OF DISPLACEMENT?

HOW HAVE WORKERS RESPONDED TO OREGON S AUTO-IRA?

MODERNIZING SOCIAL SECURITY: HELPING THE OLDEST OLD

HOW DO INHERITANCES AFFECT THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX?

ESTIMATING PENSION COVERAGE USING DIFFERENT DATA SETS

HOUSEHOLDS AT RISK : A CLOSER LOOK AT THE BOTTOM THIRD

HOW IMPORTANT IS MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY IN THE TIMING OF RETIREMENT?

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATES ON THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX

ARE PEOPLE CLAIMING SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS LATER?

HOW IMPORTANT ARE INHERITANCES FOR BABY BOOMERS?

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

SHOULD YOU CARRY A MORTGAGE INTO RETIREMENT?

USING PARTICIPANT DATA TO IMPROVE 401(k) ASSET ALLOCATION

IS WORKING LONGER A GOOD PRESCRIPTION FOR ALL?

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

DOG BITES MAN: AMERICANS ARE SHORTSIGHTED ABOUT THEIR FINANCES

THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATES ON THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX

PENSION WEALTH AND INCOME: 1992,

THE IMPACT OF AGING BABY BOOMERS ON LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

EMPIRICAL REGULARITY SUGGESTS RETIREMENT RISKS

HOW MUCH DOES HOUSING AFFECT RETIREMENT SECURITY? AN NRRI UPDATE

401(k) PLANS AND RACE

MEDICARE COSTS AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

THE IMPACT OF INFLATION ON SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

THE STRUCTURE OF 401(k) FEES

JOB TENURE AND THE SPREAD OF 401(K)S

THE IMPACT OF RAISING CHILDREN ON RETIREMENT SECURITY

DO INCOME PROJECTIONS AFFECT RETIREMENT SAVING?

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2006 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

DOES SOCIOECONOMIC STATUS LEAD PEOPLE TO RETIRE TOO SOON?

DO YOUNG ADULTS WITH STUDENT DEBT SAVE LESS FOR RETIREMENT?

IS ADVERSE SELECTION IN THE ANNUITY MARKET A BIG PROBLEM?

REDUCING DEFAULT RATES OF REVERSE MORTGAGES

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2007 REPORT IN PERSPECTIVE

EMPLOYERS (LACK OF) RESPONSE TO THE RETIREMENT INCOME CHALLENGE

401(k) PLANS ARE STILL COMING UP SHORT

THE U.K. S AMBITIOUS NEW RETIREMENT SAVINGS INITIATIVE

THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: AFTER THE CRASH

HOW HAS THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECTED THE CONSUMPTION OF RETIREES?

NRRI UPDATE SHOWS HALF STILL FALLING SHORT

IMPACT OF PUBLIC SECTOR ASSUMED RETURNS ON INVESTMENT CHOICES

NADIA KARAMCHEVA. Labor Economics, Applied Econometrics, Pension Economics and Retirement

A NUDGE ISN T ALWAYS ENOUGH

THE STATE OF PRIVATE PENSIONS: CURRENT 5500 DATA

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2014 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

WILL THE FINANCIAL FRAGILITY OF RETIREES INCREASE?

A Look at the End-of-Life Financial Situation in America, p. 2

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2011 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

THE IMPACT OF LEAKAGES ON 401(K)/IRA ASSETS

HOW RETIREMENT PROVISIONS AFFECT TENURE OF STATE AND LOCAL WORKERS

WORKERS RESPONSE TO THE MARKET CRASH: SAVE MORE, WORK MORE?

GEOFFREY T. SANZENBACHER

Retirements At Risk: The Outlook for the United States

center for retirement research

PENSION COVERAGE AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

DO LATE-CAREER WAGES BOOST SOCIAL SECURITY MORE FOR WOMEN THAN MEN? Matthew S. Rutledge and John E. Lindner. CRR WP November 2016

DO STATE ECONOMICS OR INDIVIDUAL CHARACTERISTICS DETERMINE WHETHER OLDER MEN WORK?

Keeping Older People in the Labor Force

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2018 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

WHAT FINANCIAL RISKS DO RETIREES FACE IN LATE LIFE?

Research Report. The Population of Workers Covered by the Auto IRA: Trends and Characteristics. AARP Public Policy Institute.

FINANCIAL WELL-BEING OF RESIDENTS IN SENIORS HOUSING AND CARE COMMUNITIES: EVIDENCE FROM THE RESIDENTS FINANCIAL SURVEY

Prepared remarks for testimony before the Maryland Joint Committee on Pensions

MAKING YOUR NEST EGG LAST A LIFETIME

PUBLIC SECTOR WORKERS AND JOB SECURITY

MAKING MAXIMUM USE OF TAX-DEFERRED RETIREMENT ACCOUNTS. Janette Kawachi, Karen E. Smith, and Eric J. Toder

HOW THE INCOME TAX TREATMENT OF SAVING AND SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS MAY AFFECT BOOMERS RETIREMENT INCOMES

How Is the Economic Turmoil Affecting Older Americans?

Falling Short: The Coming Retirement Crisis and What to Do About It

FIGURE 1: NATIONAL SAVING HAS PLUMMETED OVER PAST QUARTER CENTURY

NRTA PENSION. The Importance of Your Pension EDUCATION TOOLKIT. The Current State of Retirement Security in America

2017 Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government Ph.D. in Public Policy Research Fields: Labor Economics, Public Finance

HOW SECURE ARE RETIREMENT NEST EGGS?

Is Debt Good or Bad for a Comfortable Retirement? Exploring the Relationship between Consumer Debt and Retirement Preparedness

Are Early Withdrawals from Retirement Accounts a Problem?

DO OLDER WORKERS FACE GREATER RISK OF DISPLACEMENT?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

HOW SENSITIVE IS PUBLIC PENSION FUNDING TO INVESTMENT RETURNS?

U.S. Household Savings for Retirement in 2010

HOW MUCH DO OLDER WORKERS VALUE EMPLOYEE HEALTH INSURANCE?

CAN PBGC SAVE MULTIEMPLOYER PLANS?

DO PEOPLE PLAN TO TAP THEIR HOME EQUITY IN RETIREMENT?

STATE AND LOCAL PENSION COSTS: PRE- CRISIS, POST-CRISIS, AND POST-REFORM

THE DISAPPEARING DEFINED BENEFIT PENSION AND ITS POTENTIAL IMPACT ON THE RETIREMENT INCOMES OF BOOMERS

Dodged a bullet? "Rothification" likely to reduce retirement saving

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

GUARDIANSHIP AND THE REPRESENTATIVE PAYEE PROGRAM. Anek Belbase and Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher. CRR WP August 2017

THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND STATE/LOCAL DEFINED BENEFIT PLANS

Demographic Change, Retirement Saving, and Financial Market Returns

REDUCING COSTS OF 401(k) PLANS WITH ETFs AND COMMINGLED TRUSTS

WHY DO WOMEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY?

Transcription:

April 2014, Number 14-8 RETIREMENT RESEARCH WHY DON T LOWER-INCOME INDIVIDUALS HAVE PENSIONS? By April Yanyuan Wu, Matthew S. Rutledge, and Jacob Penglase* Introduction About half of U.S. private sector workers do not participate in a retirement plan at their current job. 1 Not surprisingly, non-participants are more likely to have lower incomes. Low participation is becoming a more serious concern as individuals will need more retirement savings due to declining Social Security replacement rates and longer lifespans. In response, policy experts have proposed ways to expand participation in 401(k)s and similar employer-based savings plans. Assessing the potential of these options requires a precise understanding of why individuals, particularly those with lower incomes, do not have pensions, which is the topic of this brief. 2 The discussion is organized as follows. The first section introduces the four links in the pension participation chain: having a job; working for an employer with a plan; being eligible for the plan; and taking up the plan. The second section describes the data and sample. The third section pinpoints the weakest links in the chain; and the fourth section assesses the potential of policy reforms. The final section concludes that the key reasons for the lack of pension participation among lower-income individuals are a lower likelihood of being employed and, if employed, of working for a firm that offers a plan. Take-up rates are less of a factor for today s older workers, but will become increasingly important as voluntary 401(k) plans continue to replace mandatory defined benefit plans. Thus, the most effective way to increase participation would be to provide all workers with access to a plan and automatically enroll them. Mechanics of Pension Participation Obtaining an employer pension involves four steps. First, to be associated with a plan, an individual must work regularly. Lower-income individuals, perhaps due to a lack of education and job skills, have weak labor force attachment and higher unemployment rates. 3 Second, a worker must work for an employer that offers a pension to at least some of its employees; that is, the worker needs a good job with the prospect of fringe benefits. Previous research finds that lowerincome workers are less likely to be at firms offering fringe benefits like health insurance, paid time off, * April Yanyuan Wu and Matthew S. Rutledge are senior economists and Jacob Penglase is a graduate research assistant at the at Boston College.

2 and disability insurance. 4 But less is known about their likelihood of working for a firm offering a pension. Third, if a pension is offered by the employer, the worker must be eligible for coverage. Many firms make pension plans available only to workers with sufficient tenure and hours worked. Though the concept of vesting accumulating enough tenure to be eligible for a pension is more common in traditional defined benefit plans, some defined contribution plans make eligibility for an employer match conditional on a minimum tenure length. In addition, part-time workers are less likely to be eligible for any type of plan. Finally, to participate in a pension plan, the eligible worker must take up the employer s offer. This issue is not relevant for defined benefit plans, which typically require participation. But, in recent decades, pension coverage in the private sector has rapidly shifted to defined contribution plans, primarily 401(k)s. Participation in a 401(k) is voluntary, and many of the factors that limit 401(k) participation among workers at all income levels are particularly relevant for those with lower incomes. The net effect is that lower-income people are much less likely than their higher-income counterparts to participate in a retirement plan. The question is where are the weak links in the participation chain? 5 Data and Sample The data are from the 1992-2010 waves of the Health and Retirement Study (HRS), a longitudinal survey covering households with members over age 50. The HRS contains data on an array of household characteristics, including labor force attachment, earnings, and pension coverage. 6 With respect to pensions, the HRS asks whether the respondent is participating in a plan. For non-participants, it asks whether their employer offers a plan, whether they are eligible to participate, and whether eligibility depends on fulltime status. The main sample consists of respondents age 50-58 who answered the pension questions and whose household income is less than 300 percent of the poverty line. While this level may be higher than the typical threshold for defining lower-income, it is necessary to capture a sufficient share of individuals who are working and who have jobs that offer pensions. 7 The analysis compares older lower-income individuals to older individuals with household incomes of more than 300 percent of the poverty line. For the core sample of lower-income individuals, the average pension participation rate at a current job was just 22 percent over the 1992-2010 period, well below the 59-percent rate for higher-income individuals (see Figure 1). Within the lower-income sample, those with pensions are substantially better educated, more likely to own their homes, have higher incomes and are more likely to have had a pension in their previous job. They are also more likely to work for a large employer, have a longer job tenure, and be in a white-collar job. Figure 1. Average Pension Participation Rates for Individuals Age 50-58, by Household Income, 1992-2010 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 22% Under 300% of poverty Source: Wu and Rutledge (2014). 59% Over 300% of poverty Weak Links in the Chain What is the relative importance of the four links in the pension participation chain: employment, employer offer, eligibility, and take-up? The question is addressed using a decomposition procedure that follows a technique previously used to analyze health insurance coverage. 8 The percentage of the sample employed is an unconditional probability; the remaining three elements are all conditional probabilities that rely on meeting the previous condition (e.g.

Issue in Brief 3 Figure 2. Pension Participation Chain = Probability Working Firm offers Eligible if plan if firm offers Take up if eligible = working plan Pension participation rate Source: Authors illustration. conditional on being employed, does the employer offer a pension plan to any of its workers). The four probabilities multiplied together equal the percent who participate in pensions (see Figure 2). The results of the decomposition show that the low participation rates of lower-income respondents are driven primarily by weak labor force attachment and working for a firm without a pension (see Table 1). Only about half of the lower-income individuals are working and, among those who are working, only about 60 percent work for firms that offer a pension. These figures indicate serious trouble spots for participation. Eligibility and take-up rates among the lower income also help to explain their low participation, but these factors are considerably less important as both are between 85-90 percent. Table 1. Pension Participation Rate and Its Components, Individuals Age 50-58, 1992-2010 Condition Individual is working 49% 79% Firm offers pension if working 59% 82% Worker is eligible if firm offers 89% 95% Worker takes up if eligible 86% 95% Pension participation = 22% = 59% Source: Wu and Rutledge (2014). Under 300% of poverty line How Much Could Policy Changes Help? Over 300% of poverty line In considering how policy changes could expand pension participation, it is important to exclude the individuals in the sample who work for firms that offer defined benefit coverage. 9 The reason is threefold. First, as these plans are in the process of disappearing from the private sector, today s older workers are much more likely to be covered by defined benefit plans than tomorrow s older workers. Second, because defined benefit plans are not voluntary meaning that take-up rates are essentially 100 percent including them in the sample overstates the take-up rate. Third, policy options to expand coverage generally involve some type of defined contribution plan. So, defined benefit plans are simply not relevant to the reform discussion. When the defined benefit workers are excluded from the sample, the take-up rate for lower-income workers drops from 86 percent to 78 percent (see Table 2). Therefore, from this vantage point, take-up rates are a weaker link than is apparent from looking at the full sample. The overall participation rate also drops because each link in the chain is weaker. To assess the implications of policy reforms, the conditional probabilities for each link in the participation chain can be used for a back-of-the envelope Table 2. 401(k) Participation Rate and Its Components, Lower-Income Individuals Age 50-58, 1992-2010 Condition Individual is working 42% Firm offers 401(k) if working 44% Worker is eligible for 401(k) if firm offers 84% Worker takes up 401(k) if eligible 78% 401(k) pension participation = 12% Source: Authors calculations. Under 300% of poverty line

4 calculation. For example, if all existing 401(k)s offered full-scale auto-enrollment applied both to new hires and to current workers on an annual basis it could increase the potential take up among eligible lower income individuals from 78 percent to as much as 100 percent. The 100 percent is an upper bound as individuals would still be able to opt out. To calculate the participation rate under such a policy change, the four probabilities in Table 2 are multiplied together. The participation rate would be, at maximum,.42 (working) x.44 (firm offer) x.84 (eligible) x 1.0 (takeup rate) = 16 percent (see Figure 3). Compared to the baseline rate of 12 percent, this type of auto-enrollment policy is an improvement but it only helps those who already have access to a plan. Figure 3. Potential Upper-Bound Effects of Policy Alternatives on 401(k) Participation Rates of Lower-Income Individuals Age 50-58 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 12% 16% Current Auto-enroll participation all current rate plans Source: Authors calculations. 33% All employers offer plan 42% All employers offer plan + auto-enroll A more ambitious proposal would be to require all employers to offer pensions to their workers, similar to a universal IRA. In this case, both the offer rates and eligibility rates are assumed to rise to 100 percent. If the take-up rate remains unchanged from the baseline of 78 percent, the potential participation rate would increase to 33 percent (.42 x 1 x 1 x.78). 10 Taking it one step further, if all workers were eligible and they were auto-enrolled, the participation rate would be, at most, 42 percent (.42 x 1 x 1 x 1). 11 These policies could also be paired with features like automatic-escalation in the saving rates to help ensure that participants are putting enough aside. Of course, providing universal pension coverage in the workplace would still leave a large fraction of lowerincome individuals without coverage due to their low employment rates. Thus, the only way to further expand participation would be through measures to boost employment. Conclusion Among today s older lower-income individuals, the most important reasons for low pension participation rates are a lack of employment and employment with firms that do not offer any pensions. Going forward, as defined benefit plans disappear from the private sector, low take-up rates will also become a significant contributor to low coverage rates among older workers. Overall, these findings suggest that the most potent approach for boosting pension participation would be requiring employers to offer all workers access to a retirement saving plan that includes autoenrollment. Such a policy would, however, not help lower-income individuals of working age who are not employed. Tackling this thornier issue would require measures to boost employment.

Issue in Brief 5 Endnotes 1 Munnell and Bleckman (2014). 2 This brief is adapted from a recent study by Wu and Rutledge (2014). 3 Holzer and Martinson (2005). 4 Farber and Levy (2000); Phillips (2004); and Levy (2004). 5 Previous research has confirmed that lower-income people have lower 401(k) participation rates, but the exact reasons are less clear. See Bassett, Fleming, and Rodrigues (1998); Huberman, Iyengar, and Jiang (2007); Munnell et al. (2009); Butrica et al. (2009); and Poterba, Venti, and Wise (2010). Karamcheva and Sanzenbacher (2014) focus on pension participation decisions among lower-income workers; they conclude that those most likely to participate tend to seek out jobs that offer coverage. 6 Throughout this brief, household refers to the individual and his spouse, if present, ignoring the characteristics of any other household member. 7 For more details on the data and sample, see Wu and Rutledge (2014). 8 Buchmueller et al. (2007). 9 Some workers are covered under both defined benefit and 401(k) plans. These workers are excluded in the analysis discussed in this section. 10 Karamcheva and Sanzenbacher (2014) suggest that lower-income workers who are not currently eligible for a pension plan would be more likely to opt out than the lower-income workers who are currently eligible. In other words, their take-up rate could be considerably less than 78 percent. 11 This example is similar to the Automatic IRA proposal offered by President Obama that was never adopted. President Obama s new MyRA program differs in that it is a strictly voluntary plan; employers can choose whether to offer it.

6 References Bassett, William. F., Michael J. Fleming, and Anthony P. Rodrigues. 1998. How Workers Use 401(k) Plans: The Participation, Contribution, and Withdrawal Decisions. National Tax Journal 51: 263-89. Buchmueller, Thomas C., Anthony T. Lo Sasso, Ithai Lurie, and Sarah Dolfin. 2007. Immigrants and Employer-Sponsored Health Insurance. Health Services Research 42(1, Part 1): 286-310. Butrica, Barbara A., Howard M. Iams, Karen E. Smith, and Eric J. Toder. 2009. The Disappearing Defined Benefit Pension and Its Potential Impact on the Retirement Incomes of Baby Boomers. Social Security Bulletin 69(3): 1-27. Farber, Henry S. and Helen Levy. 2000. Recent Trends in Employer-Sponsored Health Insurance Coverage: Are Bad Jobs Getting Worse? Journal of Health Economics 19: 93-119. Holzer Harry J. and Karin Martinson. 2005. Can We Improve Job Retention and Advancement Among Low-Income Working Parents? Low-Income Working Families Paper 3. Washington, DC: Urban Institute. Munnell, Alicia. H., Richard Kopcke, Francesca N. Golub-Sass, and Dan Muldoon. 2009. An Update on 401(k) Plans: Insights from the 2007 Survey of Consumer Finances. Working Paper 2009-26. Chestnut Hill, MA: at Boston College. Poterba, James M., Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise. 2010. The Rise of 401(k) Plans, Lifetime Earnings, and Wealth at Retirement. In Research Findings in the Economics of Aging, ed. David A. Wise. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Phillips, Katherine Ross. 2004. Getting Time Off: Access to Leave Among Working Parents. Working Paper B-57. Washington, DC: Urban Institute. Wu, April Yanyuan and Matthew S. Rutledge. 2014. Lower-Income Individuals Without Pensions: Who Misses Out and Why? Working Paper 2014-2. Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College. Huberman, Gur, Shena S. Iyengar, and Wei Jiang. 2007. Defined Contribution Pension Plans: Determinants of Participation and Contribution Rates. Journal of Financial Services Research 31:1-32. Karamcheva, Nadia S. and Geoffrey Sanzenbacher. 2014. Bridging the Gap in Pension Participation: How Much Can Universal Tax-Deferred Pension Coverage Hope to Achieve? Journal of Pension Economics and Finance. Available at: http://bit. ly/1plhqat. Levy, Helen. 2004. Employer-Sponsored Disability Insurance: Where Are the Gaps in Coverage? Working Paper 10382. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Munnell, Alicia H. and Dina Bleckman. 2014. Is Pension Coverage a Problem in the Private Sector? Issue in Brief 14-7. Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College.

RETIREMENT RESEARCH About the Center The mission of the at Boston College is to produce first-class research and educational tools and forge a strong link between the academic community and decision-makers in the public and private sectors around an issue of critical importance to the nation s future. To achieve this mission, the Center sponsors a wide variety of research projects, transmits new findings to a broad audience, trains new scholars, and broadens access to valuable data sources. Since its inception in 1998, the Center has established a reputation as an authoritative source of information on all major aspects of the retirement income debate. Affiliated Institutions The Brookings Institution Massachusetts Institute of Technology Syracuse University Urban Institute Contact Information Boston College Hovey House 140 Commonwealth Avenue Chestnut Hill, MA 02467-3808 Phone: (617) 552-1762 Fax: (617) 552-0191 E-mail: crr@bc.edu Website: http://crr.bc.edu 2014, by Trustees of Boston College, Center for Retirement Research. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that the authors are identified and full credit, including copyright notice, is given to Trustees of Boston College,. The research reported herein was supported by the Ford Foundation. The findings and conclusions expressed are solely those of the authors and do not represent the opinions or policy of the Ford Foundation or the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College.