Credit derivatives pricing using the Cox process with shot noise intensity. Jang, Jiwook

Similar documents
Pricing of catastrophe reinsurance and derivatives using the Cox process with shot noise intensity

Current Version: May 15, Introduction. classical risk theory one assumes (often implicitly) that interest rates equal zero, Y (i) C (t) =

Unified Credit-Equity Modeling

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

A Cox process with log-normal intensity

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

Introduction Credit risk

AN INFORMATION-BASED APPROACH TO CREDIT-RISK MODELLING. by Matteo L. Bedini Universitè de Bretagne Occidentale

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Actuarially Consistent Valuation of Catastrophe Derivatives

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Modeling Credit Risk with Partial Information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Capital Allocation in Insurance: Economic Capital and the Allocation of the Default Option Value

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Pricing and Hedging of Credit Derivatives via Nonlinear Filtering

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

SOME APPLICATIONS OF OCCUPATION TIMES OF BROWNIAN MOTION WITH DRIFT IN MATHEMATICAL FINANCE

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

Introduction to Affine Processes. Applications to Mathematical Finance

Credit-Equity Modeling under a Latent Lévy Firm Process

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Risk-Neutral Valuation

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE. A Modern View on Merton s Jump-Diffusion Model Gerald H. L. Cheang and Carl Chiarella

Valuing power options under a regime-switching model

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Large Deviations and Stochastic Volatility with Jumps: Asymptotic Implied Volatility for Affine Models

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Interest rate models in continuous time

Financial and Actuarial Mathematics

Pension Risk Management with Funding and Buyout Options

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Credit Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 7, Credit Risk. John Dodson. Introduction.

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Research Article The European Vulnerable Option Pricing with Jumps Based on a Mixed Model

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

A GENERAL FORMULA FOR OPTION PRICES IN A STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODEL. Stephen Chin and Daniel Dufresne. Centre for Actuarial Studies

Enlargement of filtration

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Credit Risk. June 2014

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Homework Assignments

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Basic Stochastic Processes

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

MORNING SESSION. Date: Wednesday, April 30, 2014 Time: 8:30 a.m. 11:45 a.m. INSTRUCTIONS TO CANDIDATES

1.1 Implied probability of default and credit yield curves

SADDLEPOINT APPROXIMATIONS TO OPTION PRICES 1. By L. C. G. Rogers and O. Zane University of Bath and First Chicago NBD

Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Law of the Minimal Price

Risk Neutral Measures

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

Universität Regensburg Mathematik

European call option with inflation-linked strike

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Valuing volatility and variance swaps for a non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck stochastic volatility model

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Non-semimartingales in finance

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

A Bivariate Shot Noise Self-Exciting Process for Insurance

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Risk Measures for Derivative Securities: From a Yin-Yang Approach to Aerospace Space

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

The stochastic calculus

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Valuation of Defaultable Bonds Using Signaling Process An Extension

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Transcription:

Credit derivatives pricing using the Cox process with shot noise intensity Jang, Jiwook Actuarial Studies, University of New South Wales, Sydney, NSW 252, Australia, Tel: +61 2 9385 336, Fax: +61 2 9385 1883, e-mail: J.Jang@unsw.edu.au Abstract As the building blocks for credit derivatives pricing, we need the price of the default-free zero-coupon bond, the price of the defaultable zero-coupon bonds with zero recovery and the value of a deterministic (or non-deterministic) payoff at recovery, which is some time after the default. In order to price the nondefaultable zero-coupon bond, we use a generalised Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) model (1985). We employ the Cox process with shot noise intensity to model the default time and derive the survival probability to price the defaultable zero-coupon bonds with zero recovery and the value of a deterministic payoff at recovery. In order to obtain the explicit expressions of three building blocks for credit derivatives pricing, we assume that the instantaneous rate of interest and the default intensity rate are independent each other. We also assume that the jump size of shot noise intensity follows an exponential distribution and the asymptotic distribution of the shot noise intensity is used not to have its initial value. As examples of credit derivatives pricing using these building blocks, we calculate the price of defaultable fixed-coupon bond and the market credit default swaps (CDS) rate numerically. Keywords: The Cox process with shot noise process; Default time and survival probability; A generalised CIR model; Piecewise deterministic Markov process; Defaultable fixed-coupon bond; Market credit default swaps (CDS) rate. 1. Introduction Since Merton (1974), one of the credit risk modelling developed is based on the default intensity of a counting process. Jarrow and Turnbull (1995) proposed to use the Poisson process and extended it further employing a discrete state space Markov chain in credit rating with Lando (1997). Lando (1998) examined it deeper introducing the Cox process where its intensity has finite state space. Similar approach was used by Duffie and Singleton (1999), where they considered the fractional reduction in market value that occurs at default with respect to risk neutral probability measure. The comparison between the classical approach proposed in Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1974) and the intensity-based approach can be found in Cooper and Martin (1996). Other works relating to credit risk we refer you Artzner and Delbaen (1995), Madan and Unal (1998), Bielecki and Rutkowski (2), Elliot et al. (2) and Schönbucher (23). In this paper we also employ the Cox process (Cox 1955; Grandell, 1976 and Brémaud 1981) to model the default time. Under a doubly stochastic Poisson process, or the Cox process, the intensity function is assumed to be stochastic. The doubly stochastic Poisson process provides flexibility by letting the intensity not only depend on time but also allowing it to be a stochastic process. Therefore the doubly stochastic Poisson process can be viewed as a two step randomisation procedure. A process λ t is used to generate another process N t by acting as its intensity. That is, N t is a Poisson process conditional on λ t which itself is a stochastic process (if λ t is deterministic then N t is a Poisson process). Many alternative definitions of a doubly stochastic Poisson process can be given. We will offer the one used by Dassios and Jang (23). Definition 1.1 Let (Ω,F,P) be a probability space with information structure given by F = {= t,t [,T]}. Let N t be a point process adapted to F.Letλ t be a non-negative process adapted to F such that If for all t 1 t 2 and u < λ s ds < almost surely (no explosions). o E ne iu(nt 2 Nt 1) = λ t2 =exp e iu 1 Z t2 λ s ds t 1 (1.1) 1

then N t is call a = t -doubly stochastic Poisson process with intensity λ t where = λ t = σ {λ s ; s t}. Equation (1.1) gives us and Ã!Ã Rt 2 R t2 exp λ s ds λ s ds t 1 t 1 Pr {N t2 N t1 = k λ s ; t 1 s t 2 } = k! Pr {τ 2 >t λ s ; t 1 s t 2 } =Pr{N t2 N t1 = λ s ; t 1 s t 2 } =exp where τ k denotes the length of the time interval between the (k 1) th and k th point. R process Λ t = t λ s ds (the aggregated process), then from (1.2) we can easily find that! k. (1.2) 2 t 1 λ s ds (1.3) Now consider the ³ n E θ Nt 2 Nt 1 = E e (1 θ)(λ t 2 Λ t1 ) o. (1.4) Equation (1.4) suggests that the problem of finding the distribution of N t, the point process, is equivalent to the problem of finding the distribution of Λ t, the aggregated process. It means that we just have to find the p.g.f. (probability generating function) of N t to retrieve the m.g.f. (moment generating function) of Λ t and vice versa. From the Cox process of N t, the survival probability is given by Pr (τ 1 >t λ )=E exp λ s ds λ = E e Λt λ (1.5) where τ 1 inf {t : N t =1 N =} is the default arrival time that is equivalent to the first jump arrival time of the Cox process N t and the expectation is calculated under an appropriate probability measure. If we assume that the interest rate process for a zero-coupon default-free bond, r t follows a generalised Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) model (1985), i.e. dr t = c(b ar t )dt + σ r t db t, (1.6) where a>, b> and c>, its price at time, paying1 at time t is given by B(,t)=E exp r s ds r = E e R t r (1.7) where B(,t) denotes the price of a default -free zero-coupon bond, R t = r s ds, = r t = σ {r s ; s t} and the expectation is calculated under an appropriate probability measure. Assuming that r t and λ t are independent, the price of a zero-coupon defaultable bond paying 1 (τ 1 >t) at time t is given by R t B(,t) = E exp = E e Rt e Λt r, λ = E e R t r E e Λ t λ r s ds 1 (τ 1>t) r, λ = E exp (r s + λ s ) ds r, λ (1.8) where B(,t) denotes the price of a defaultable zero-coupon bond and the expectation is calculated under an appropriate probability measure. 2

In reality, the lenders (i.e. the buyers of defaultable bonds) can receive the part (or whole) of coupon payments and principle after the liquidation of borrowers assets. So we simply consider the recovery of par model introduced by Duffie (1998). For fractional recovery, we refer you Duffie and Singleton (23). The value of a deterministic payoff, 1 that is paid at t k+1 if and only if a default happens in ]t k,t k+1 ], denoted by e(,t k,t k+1 ),isgivenby t k+1 Z e(,t k,t k+1 ) = E exp r s ds ³ 1 {Ntk =} 1 {N tk+1 =} r, λ t k+1 Z k Z = E exp r s ds exp λ s ds exp = E ³e R t k+1 r ne e Λt k λ E ³e Λ t k+1 λ o t k+1 λ s ds r, λ where =t <t k <t k+1 and the expectation is calculated under an appropriate probability measure. Now using (1.7), (1.8) and (1.9), that are building blocks for credit derivatives pricing, we can price a defaultable fixed-coupon bond at time, denoted by C(), as C() = NX c n B(,t kn )+B(,t kn )+π k N X (1.9) e(,t k 1,t k ) (1.1) where c n = c (t kn t kn 1 ) are coupon payments at t kn (n =1, 2,,N), t k1 <t k2 < <t kn and π is a deterministic recovery rate. We can also calculate the market credit default swaps (CDS) rate, denoted by s,as s =(1 π) k n P e(,t k 1,t k ). (1.11) NP (t kn+1 t kn )B(,t kn ) The paper is structured as follows. In section 2, we introduce the shot noise process as an default intensity of the Cox process. We derive the Laplace transform of shot noise process, λ t and aggregated process, Λ t by piecewise deterministic Markov processes (PDMP) theory. All proofs are referred to Dassios and Jang (23) where they used the Cox process with shot noise intensity for the pricing of reinsurance contract. Section 3 deals with risk neutrality. We examine how the dynamics of process λ t and Λ t change after changing probability measure obtained via the Esscher transform. For simplicity, we use zero-coupon default-free bond price with respect to the original measure. In section 4, we illustrate the calculations of defaultable fixed-coupon bond prices and the market credit default swaps (CDS) rates using the asymptotic distribution of shot noise process and exponential jump size distribution. Section 5 concludes. 2. Shot noise process and aggregated process In practice, there are primary events such as the governments fiscal and monetary policies, the release of corporate financial reports, the political and social decisions, the romours of mergers and acquisitions among firms and September 11 WTC catastrophe etc. that affect the value of the firm s risky debt and may lead to the default as the worst case. We can assume that the number of defaults out of primary events follows the Poisson process. However it is inadequate as it has deterministic intensity, where the survival probability follows an exponential distribution. Therefore an alternative default intensity process needs to be used to generate the default arrival process. One of the processes that can be used to measure the impact of primary events is the shot noise process (Cox & Isham 198, 1986; Klüppelberg and Mikosch 1995 and Dassios and Jang 23). The shot noise process is particularly useful in the default arrival process as it measures the frequency, magnitude and time period needed to go back to the previous level of intensity immediately after primary events occur. As time passes, the shot noise process decreases as all firms in the market do their best to avoid being in bankruptcy after the arrival of one of the primary events. This decrease continues until another event occurs which 3

will result in a positive jump in the shot noise process. Therefore the shot noise process can be used as the parameter of the doubly stochastic Poisson process to measure the time to default due to primary events, i.e. we will use it as an intensity function to generate the Cox process. We will adopt the shot noise process used by Cox & Isham (198): λ t Figure 1. Graph illustrating a shot noise process t XM t λ t = λ e t + Y i e (t Si) where: λ is the initial value of λ t. {Y i } i=1,2, is a sequence of independent and identically distributed random variables with distribution function G (y) (y>) and E (Y )=µ 1. {S i } i=1,2, is the sequence representing the event times of a Poisson process with constant intensity ρ. is the rate of exponential decay. We also make the additional assumption that the Poisson process M t and the sequences {Y i } i=1,2, are independent of each other. Some works of insurance application using shot noise process can be found in Klüppelberg and Mikosch (1995), Dassios and Jang (23), Jang (24) and Jang and Krvavych (24). The piecewise deterministic Markov processes (PDMP) theory developed by Davis (1984) is a powerful mathematical tool for examining non-diffusion models. From now on, we present definitions and important properties of shot noise and aggregated processes with the aid of piecewise deterministic processes theory (Dassios 1987; Dassios and Embrechts 1989; Dassios and Jang 23 and Rolski et al. 1998). This theory is used to derive the Laplace transform of shot noise process, λ t and aggregated process, Λ t. The three parameters of the shot noise process described are homogeneous in time. We are now going to generalise the shot noise process by allowing the parameters to depend on time. The rate of jump arrivals, ρ (t), is bounded on all intervals [,t) (no explosions). (t) is the rate of decay and the distribution function R of jump sizes at any time t is G (y; t) (y>) with E (Y ; t) =µ 1 (t) = ydg(y; t). Weassumethat (t), ρ (t) and G (y; t) are all Riemann integrable functions of t and are all positive. The generator of the process (Λ t,n t, λ t,t) acting on a function f (Λ,n,λ,t) belonging to its domain is given by i=1 Af(Λ,n,λ,t)= f t + λ f + λ [f(λ,n+1, λ,t) f (Λ,n,λ,t)] (t) λ f Λ λ Z + ρ (t) f (Λ,n,λ + y, t) dg (y; t) f (Λ,n,λ,t). (2.4) 4

For f (Λ,n,λ,t) to belong to the domain of the generator A, it is sufficient that f (Λ,n,λ,t) is differentiable w.r.t. Λ, λ, tfor all Λ, n,λ, tand that Z f (,, λ + y, ) dg (y; t) f (,, λ, ) <. Let us find a suitable martingale in order to derive the Laplace transforms of the distribution of Λ t and λ t. Lemma 2.2 Considering constants k and v such that k and v, exp ( vλ t ) exp ket ve t exp ρ 1 ĝ kes ve t R is a martingale where ĝ (u; s) = e uy dg (y; s) and 4 (t) = Proof. See Dassios and Jang (23). Let us assume that (t) = throughout the rest of this paper. Corollary 2.3 Let v 1 and v 2. Then o E ne v1(λt 2 Λt 1) e v 2 λ t2 Λt1, λ t1 h n v1 ³ = exp + v 2 v o i 1 e (t 2 t 1 ) λ t1 exp 2 t 1 h n v1 ³ ρ (s) 1 ĝ + Z s e r dr λ t e r dr; s ds (2.5) R t v 2 v 1 (s) ds. oi e (t2 s) ; s ds. (2.6) Proof. See Dassios and Jang (23). Now we can easily obtain the Laplace transforms of the distribution of λ t, Λ t. Corollary 2.4 The Laplace transforms of the distribution of λ t and Λ t are given by E e vλ t 2 λt1 ª = exp h ve (t 2 t 1 ) λ t1 i exp 2 h n oi ρ (s) 1 ĝ ve (t2 s) ; s ds, (2.7) t 1 o E ne v(λt 2 Λt 1) λt1 h = exp v n1 o i e (t 2 t 1 ) λ t1 2 h n v exp ρ (s) 1 ĝ ³1 (t2 s) oi e ; s ds. (2.8) t 1 Proof. See Dassios and Jang (23). Let us obtain the asymptotic distributions of λ t at time t from (2.8), provided that the process started sufficiently far in the past. In this context we interpret it as the limit when t. In other words, if we know λ at and no information between to present time t, asymptotic distribution of λ t can be used as the distribution of λ t. 5

Lemma 2.5 Assume that of λ t has Laplace transform lim ρ (t) =ρ and lim t E e vλ t 1 =exp 1 µ 1 (t) =µ 1. Then the asymptotic distribution t h n oi ρ (s) 1 ĝ ve (t1 s) ; s ds. (2.9) Proof. See Dassios and Jang (23). It will be interesting to find the Laplace transforms of the distribution of λ t and Λ t at time t, using a specific jump size distribution of G (y; t) (y > ). We use an exponential jump size distribution, i.e. g (y; t) = α + γe t e (α+γet )y,y>, αe t α < γ. Let us assume that ρ (t) =ρ. The reason α+γe t for this particular assumption will become apparent later when we change the probability measure. Theorem 2.6 Let the jump size distribution be exponential, i.e. g (y; t) = α + γe t exp α + γe t y ª, y>, αe t α < γ, and assume that ρ (t) =ρ. Then α+γe t E e vλ ª t 1 λt = exp n vλ o µ t e (t 1 t ) γe t + αe (t 1 t ) ρ γe t + α µ γe t + ve (t 1 t ) + α ρ, (2.1) γe t +(v + α) e (t1 t) o E ne v(λt 2 Λt 1) λt1 h = exp v n1 e (t2 t1)o i λ t1 µ γe t 1 + αe (t 2 t 1 ) ρ γe t1 + α 1 e (t 2 t 1) Ã γe t 1 + α + v γe t1 + αe (t2 t1)! αρ α+v (2.11) If λ t is asymptotic, E µ e vλ t γ + αe t 1 ρ 1 =, (2.12) γ +(v + α) e t1 n E e v(λ t 2 Λ t1 ) o = Proof. See Dassios and Jang (23). Ã! ρ γe t1 + αe (t2 t1) γe t 1 + α + v 1 e (t 2 t 1 ) 1 e (t 2 t 1 ) Ã γe t 1 + α + v γe t 1 + αe (t 2 t 1 )! αρ α+v (2.13) 3. No-arbitrage, the Esscher transform and change of probability measure In general, the Esscher transform is defined as a change of probability measure for certain stochastic processes. An Esscher transform of such a process induces an equivalent probability measure on the process. The parameters involved for the Esscher transform are determined so that the process is a martingale under the new probability measure. We will examine an equivalent martingale probability measure obtained via the Esscher transform (Gerber and Shiu 1996 and Dassios and Jang 23). If the market is complete, the fair price of a contingent claim is the expectation with respect to exactly one equivalent martingale probability measure, i.e. by assuming that there is an absence of arbitrage opportunities in the market. For example, when the underlying stochastic process follows geometric Brownian motion or homogeneous Poisson process, we can obtain the fair price with respect to a unique equivalent martingale probability measure. However, as the underlying stochastic process for default arrival process 6

is the Cox process with shot noise intensity, we will have infinitely many equivalent martingale probability measures. In other words, we will have several choices of equivalent martingale probability measures to decide credit derivatives prices as the market is incomplete. It is not the purpose of this paper to decide which is the appropriate one to use. The attractive thing about the Esscher transform is that it provides us with at least one equivalent martingale probability measure in incomplete market situations. We here offer the definition of the Esscher transform that is adopted from Gerber & Shiu (1996). Definition 3.1 Let X t be a stochastic process and h a real number. For a measurable function f, the expectation of the random variable f(x t ) with respect to the equivalent martingale probability measure is E e h X t [f (X t )] = E f (X t ) E (e h X t) = E f (X t ) e h X t E [e h X t], (3.1) where the process e h X t is a martingale and E e h X t <. From definition 3.1, we need to obtain a martingale that can be used to define a change of probability measure, i.e. it can be used to define the Radon-Nikodym derivative dp dp where P is the original probability measure and P is the equivalent martingale probability measure with parameters involved. Assuming that default and primary events do not occur at the same time, the generator of the process (Λ t,n t, λ t,m t,t) acting on a function f(λ,n,λ,m,t) belonging to its domain is given by Af(Λ,n,λ,m,t) = f t + λ f + λ [f (Λ,n+1, λ,m,t) f (Λ,n,λ,m,t)] Λ λ f Z λ + ρ f (Λ,n,λ + y, m +1,t) dg (y) f (Λ,n,λ,m,t). (3.2) Clearly, for f (Λ,n,λ,m,t) to belong to the domain of the generator A, it is essential that f (Λ,n,λ,m,t) is differentiable w.r.t. Λ, λ, tfor all Λ, n, λ, m, tand that Z f (., λ + y,.) dg (y) f (., λ,.) <. Lemma 3.2 Considering constants θ, ψ and γ such that θ 1, ψ 1 and γ, θ Nt exp { (θ 1) Λ t } ψ Mt exp γ λ t e t exp ρ 1 ψ ĝ γ e s ª ds (3.3) is a martingale. Proof. From (3.2), f (Λ,n,λ,m,t) has to satisfy Af =for f(λ t,n t, λ t,m t,t) to be a martingale. Trying θ n e φ Λ ψ m exp γ λe t e A(t) we get the equation and solving (3.4) we get A (t)+λφ + λ {θ 1} + ρ ψ ĝ γ e t 1 ª = (3.4) φ = {θ 1} and A (t) =ρ 1 ψ ĝ γ e s ª ds and the result follows. Let us examine how the generator A of the process (Λ t,n t, λ t,m t,t) acting on a function f(λ,n,λ,m,t) with respect to the equivalent martingale probability measure can be obtained. Lemma 3.3 Let v be a nonnegative constant. Assuming that f(λ,n,λ,m,t)=f (λ,t) for all Λ, n,m and that e v X t is a martingale with X t an adapted process. The generator A of the process (λ t,t) acting on a function f (λ,t) with respect to the equivalent martingale measure is given by A f (λ,t)= A ª f (λ,t) e v X t 7 e v X. (3.5)

Proof. The generator of the process (λ t,t) acting on a function f (λ,t) with respect to the equivalent martingale probability measure is A E [f (λ t+dt,t+ dt) λ t = λ] f (λ,t) f (λ,t) = lim. (3.6) dt dt e We will use v X t E(e v X t) as the Radon-Nikodym derivative to define equivalent martingale probability measure. Hence, the expected value of f (λ t+dt,t+ dt) given λ t = λ with respect to the equivalent martingale probability measure is E [f (λ t+dt,t+ dt) λ t = λ] = E f (λ t+dt,t+ dt) e v X t+dt λ t = λ E (e v X t+dt λt. (3.7) = λ) Since e v X t in (3.7) is a martingale, it becomes Set (3.8) in (3.6) then = E [f (λ t+dt,t+ dt) λ t = λ] (3.8) f (λ,t) e v λ + t+dt R t E Af(λ s,s) e v X s λ t = λ ds e v X. A f (λ,t)= 1 e v X lim dt t+dt Z t E Af(λ s,s) e v X s λ t = λ ds. (3.9) dt Therefore, from Dynkin s formula, (3.5) follows immediately. Now let us look at how the dynamics of process λ t and Λ t change after changing probability measure by obtaining the generator A of the process (Λ t,n t, λ t,m t,t) acting on a function f (Λ,n,λ,m,t) with respect to the equivalent martingale probability measure. This is the key result that we require to establish an arbitrage-free price under our equivalent martingale measure. As Dassios and Jang (23) have shown thechangeofdynamicsofprocessλ t and Λ t with respect to the equivalent martingale probability measure, we offer the theorem adopted from their studies (see theorem 3.5 in section 3). Theorem 3.4 Consider constants θ, ψ and γ such that θ 1, ψ 1 and γ. Suppose that ĝ γ e t <. Then A f(λ,n,λ,m,t) = f t + λ f Λ + θ λ {f (Λ,n+1, λ,m,t) f (Λ,n,λ,m,t)} λ f Z λ + ρ (t) f (Λ,n,λ + y, m +1,t) dg (y; t) f (Λ,n,λ,m,t) (3.1) where ρ (t) =ρψ ĝ γ e t and dg (y; t) = exp( γ e t y)dg(y) ĝ(γ e t ). Proof. See Dassios and Jang (23). Theorem 3.4 yields the following: (i) The intensity function λ t has changed to θ λ t ; (ii) Therateofjumparrivalρ has changed to ρ (t) =ρψ ĝ γ e t (it now depends on time); (iii) The jump size measure dg (y) has changed to dg (y; t) = exp( γ e t y)dg(y) ĝ(γ e t ) (it now depends on time). 8

In other words, the risk-neutral Esscher measure is the measure with respect to which N t becomes the Cox process with parameter θ λ t where three parameters of the shot noise process λ t are, ρ (t) =ρψ ĝ γ e t, dg (y; t) = exp( γ e t y)dg(y). ĝ(γ e t ) In practice, the banks and traders need to calculate credit derivatives prices using θ > 1, ψ > 1 and γ <. This results in banks and traders assuming that there will be a higher value of intensity itself, more primary events occurring in a given period of time and a higher value of jump size of intensity. These assumptions are necessary, as the banks and traders have to consider the risks involved in incomplete market. If θ =1, ψ =1, and γ =then non-arbitrage free credit derivatives price is calculated without considering any risks involved in incomplete market. However, as expected, we have quite a flexible family of equivalent probability measures by the combination of θ, ψ and γ. It means that the banks and traders have various ways of obtaining an non-arbitrage credit derivatives price (i.e. by changing equivalent martingale probability measures using the combination of θ, ψ and γ ). Now let us derive the Laplace transform of the asymptotic distribution of Λ t with respect to the equivalent martingale probability measure, i.e. E e t Λ. We will assume that the jump size distribution is exponential, i.e. g (y) =αe αy,y>, α > and that λ t is asymptotic. Therefore we can obtain that g (y; t) = α + γ e t exp α + γ e t y ª,y>, αe αy < γ and t< 1 ln ³ α γ since dg (y; t) = exp( γ e t y)dg(y) ĝ(γ e t ). Corollary 3.5 Let the jump size distribution be exponential. Consider constants ν, θ, ψ and γ such that v, θ 1, ψ 1 and γ. Furthermore if λ t is asymptotic, then E n e v(λ t 2 Λ t1 ) o = Ã γ e t 1 + αe (t 2 t 1 ) γ e t1 + α + θ ν Ã γ e t 1 + α + θ ν! ψ ρ 1 e (t 2 t 1) 1 e (t 2 t 1 ) γ e t 1 + αe (t 2 t 1 )! αψ ρ α+θ ν (3.11) where <t 1 <t 2 <t. Proof. From Theorem 3.4, (1.4) and (2.13), the result follows immediately. In order to obtain an arbitrage-free zero-coupon default-free bond price, we can employ the Girsanov theorem (Karatzas and Shreve 1991; Revuz and Yor 1991 and Protter 1992) to change measure. However for simplicity, we will use a zero-coupon default-free bond price at time with respect to the original measure. Hence from CIR (1985), assuming that c =1, we can easily obtain a zero-coupon default-free bond price at time, paying1 at time t, B(,t) = E exp r s ds r = E e Rt r " ( 2 1 exp a 2 +2σ 2 t ª ) # = exp a2 +2σ 2 + ξ? a + a 2 +2σ 2 a exp a 2 +2σ 2 t ª r 2 µ a 2 +2σ 2 exp ( a 2 +2σ 2 a) 2 t a2 +2σ 2 + a + a 2 +2σ 2 a exp a 2 +2σ 2 t 2b σ 2. (3.12) 4. Pricing of credit derivatives using the three building blocks Now let us look at the credit derivatives prices at present time, i.e. the price of defaultable fixedcoupon bond and the market credit default swaps (CDS) rate, assuming that there is an absence of arbitrage opportunities in the market. This can be achieved by using an equivalent martingale probability measure, Q = P P, within the expressions of the three building blocks in Section 1. Therefore, from (1.8), (1.9), 9

(1.1), (1.11) (3.11) and (3.12) the price of a zero-coupon corporate (defaultable) bond paying 1 (τ 1 >t) at time t is given by B Q (,t) = E Q exp r s ds 1 (τ 1>t) r = EQ exp (r s + λ s ) ds r = E Q e Rt e Λt r = E e R t r E e Λ t (4.2) and the value of a deterministic payoff 1 that is paid at t k+1 if and only if a default happens in ]t k,t k+1 ] is given by t k+1 Z e Q (,t k,t k+1 ) = E Q exp r s ds ³ 1 {Ntk =} 1 {N tk+1 =} r t k+1 Z k Z = E Q exp r s ds exp λ s ds exp = E ³e R t k+1 r ne e Λ ³ o t k E e Λ t k+1 and the price a defaultable fixed-coupon bond is given by C Q () = NX c n B Q (,t kn )+B Q (,t kn )+π and the market credit default swaps (CDS) rate is given by s Q =(1 π) k n P k N X t k+1 λ s ds r (4.3) e Q (,t k 1,t k ) (4.4) e Q (,t k 1,t k ). (4.5) NP (t kn+1 t kn )B Q (,t kn ) It has been assumed implicitly that the frequency and magnitude of primary events and time period needed to go back to the previous level of intensity immediately after primary events occur are the same among all firms. However some of these primary events might not affect at all to a specific firm e.g. AAA rating firm. Also even if primary events affect firms default intensities, their magnitude should be different to each firms. Time period needed to go back to the previous level of intensity also need to be discriminated among firms. Therefore we denote the survival probability of the firm i by ³ E e Λi t. Now now illustrate the calculations of defaultable fixed-coupon bond prices and the market credit default swaps (CDS) rates using the expressions derived above. and Example 4.1 The parameter values used to calculate (4.4) and (4.5) are r =.5, a=.5, b=.25 and σ =.8 for r t and ψ =1.1, γ =.1, θ =1.1, α i =1, i =.5 and ρ i =4for λ t 1

c =5% and π = 5% and N =2,t k =,t k1 =.5, t k2 =1. Then an arbitrage-free defaultable fixed-coupon bond price is given by Q C i () =.24357 +.3752 +.28753 =.68241 and an arbitrage-free credit default swaps (CDS) rate is given by µ s Q.5756 i =(1.5) =.5923 = 5, 92.3bp..48715 Example 4.2 We will now examine the effect on arbitrage-free defaultable fixed-coupon bond price and credit default swaps (CDS) rate caused by changes in the value of α i, i and ρ i. The calculation of arbitrage-free defaultable fixed-coupon bond prices and credit default swaps (CDS) rates are shown in Table 4.1 and Table 4.2 respectively, assuming other parameter values are the same as in Example 4.1. Table 4.1. Table 4.2. Q C i () α i =1.47337 α i =2.833 i =.1.47981 i =4.92659 ρ i =.99354 ρ i =8.55836 α i =1 α i =2 i =.1 i =4 ρ i = ρ i =8 s Q i 74, 28bp 2, 647.4bp 94, 499bp 718.74bp bp 15, 399bp 5. Conclusion Using the intensity-based framework, i.e. employing the Cox process with shot noise intensity, we examined how it could be used to calculate the price of defaultable fixed-coupon bond and the market credit default swaps (CDS) rate. In order to obtain an arbitrage-free prices, we changed the probability measure via the Esscher transform, where we showed how the dynamics of the shot noise process λ t and the aggregated process Λ t changed with respect to an equivalent martingale probability measure. We witnessed that there are various ways to quantify the risk involved when the market is incomplete. By discriminating of three parameters of the shot noise intensity, i.e. the frequency and magnitude of primary events and time period needed to go back to the previous level of intensity immediately after primary events occur for each firm, we illustrated the calculation of arbitrage-free defaultable fixed-coupon bond prices and the market credit default swaps (CDS) rates. References Artzner, P. and Delbaen, F. (1995) : Default risk insurance and incomplete market, Mathematical Finance, 5/3, 197-195. Bertoin, J. (1998) : Lévy processes, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Bielecki, T. R. and Rutkowski, M. (2) : Multiple ratings model of defaultable term structure, Mathematical Finance, 1/2, 125-139. Black, F and Scholes, M (1973) : The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of Political Economy, 3, 637-654. Brémaud, P. (1981) : Point Processes and Queues: Martingale Dynamics, Springer-Verlag, New-York. Cooper, I. and Martin, M. (1996) : Default risk and derivative products, Applied Mathematical Finance, 3, 53-74. 11

Cox, D. R. (1955) : Some statistical methods connected with series of events, J. R. Stat. Soc. B, 17, 129-164. Cox, D. R. and Isham, V. (198) : Point Processes, Chapman & Hall, London. Cox, D. R. and Isham, V. (1986) : The virtual waiting time and related processes, Adv. Appl. Prob. 18, 558-573. Cox, J. Ingersoll, J. and Ross, S. (1985) : A theory of the term structure of interest rates, Econometrica, 53/2, 385-47. Dassios, A. and Embrechts, P. (1989) : Martingales and insurance risk, Commun. Stat.-Stochastic Models, 5(2), 181-217. Dassios, A. and Jang, J. (23) : Pricing of catastrophe reinsurance & derivatives using the Cox process with shot noise intensity, Finance & Stochastics, 7/1, 73-95. Davis, M. H. A. (1984) : Piecewise deterministic Markov processes: A general class of non diffusion stochastic models, J. R. Stat. Soc. B, 46, 353-388. Duffie, D. (1998) : Defaultable Term Structure Models with Fractional Recovery of Par, GraduateSchool of Business, Stanford University. Duffie, D. and Singleton, K. J. (1999) : Modeling term structures of defaultable bonds, Review of Financial Studies, 12/4, 687-72. Duffie, D. and Singleton, K. J. (23) : Credit risk: Pricing, measurement and management, Princeton University Press, Princeton. Elliott, R. J., Jeanblanc, M and Yor, M. (2) : On models of default risk, Mathematical Finance, 1/2, 179-195. Gerber, H. U. and Shiu, E. S. W. (1996) : Actuarial bridges to dynamic hedging and option pricing, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 18, 183-218. Grandell, J. (1976) : Doubly Stochastic Poisson Processes, Springer-Verlag, Berlin. Jang, J. (24) : Martingale approach for moments of discounted aggregate claims, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 71/2, 21-211. Jang, J. and Krvavych, Y. (24) : Arbitrage-free premium calculation for extreme losses using the shot noise process and the Esscher transform, Insurance: Mathematics & Economics, 35/1, 97-111. Jarrow, R., Lando, D. and Turnbull, S. (1997) : A Markov model for the term structure of credit risk spreads, Review of Financial Studies, 1/2, 481-523. Jarrow, R. and Turnbull, S. (1995) : Pricing options on financial securities subject to credit risk, Journal of Finance, 5, 53-85. Karatzas, I. and Shreve S. (1991) : Brownian motion and stochastic calculus, Springer-Verlag, New-York. Klüppelberg, C. and Mikosch, T. (1995) : Explosive Poisson shot noise processes with applications to risk reserves, Bernoulli, 1, 125-147. Lando, D. (1998) : On Cox processes and credit risky securities, Review of Derivative Research, 2, 99-12. Madan, D. and Unal, H. (1998) : Pricing the risks of default, Review of Derivatives Research, 2, 121-16. Merton, R. (1974) : On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates, Journal of Finance, 29, 449-47. Protter, P. (1992) : Stochastic integration and differential equations, Springer-Verlag, New-York. Revuz, D. and Yor, M. (1991) : Continuous martingales and Brownian motion, Springer-Verlag, New- York. Rolski, T., Schmidli, H., Schmidt, V. and Teugels, J. L. (1998) : Stochastic processes for insurance and Finance, John Wiley & Sons, UK. Schönbucher, P. J. (23): Credit derivataives pricing models: Models, Pricing and Implementation, John Wiley & Sons, UK 12