Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 2013

Similar documents
Honors General Exam PART 1: MICROECONOMICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2013

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

Microeconomics, IB and IBP. Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Pauline is considering becoming a member of a CD club, which offers discounts on CDs. There is a membership fee of 100 but then each CD is only 10.

Midterm 1 - Solutions

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

ECS2601 Oct / Nov 2014 Examination Memorandum. (1a) Raymond has a budget of R200. The price of food is R20 and the price of clothes is R50.

ANSWERS TO PRACTICE PROBLEMS oooooooooooooooo

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

University of California, Davis Department of Economics Giacomo Bonanno. Economics 103: Economics of uncertainty and information PRACTICE PROBLEMS

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

There are 10 questions on this exam. These 10 questions are independent of each other.

Final. You have 2h to complete the exam and the nal consists of 6 questions ( =100).

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 1

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

ASHORTCOURSEIN INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS WITH CALCULUS. allan

Econ 210, Final, Fall 2015.

3. Other things being equal, a lump sum tax is at least as good for a consumer as a sales tax that collects the same revenue from him.

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks.

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Midterm 1 - Solutions

ECON 310 Fall 2005 Final Exam - Version A. Multiple Choice: (circle the letter of the best response; 3 points each) and x

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

X= ( B, D ) Y= ( B, D)

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid June Microeconomics Grade

(a) This implies that Dent s average cost is equal to. to On the graph below, plot the above curves, and also plot Dent s supply curve.

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2014 Answer any 7 of these 8 questions Good luck!

U(x 1. ; x 2 ) = 4 ln x 1

Final Examination: Economics 210A December, 2015

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

PhD Qualifier Examination

Midterm 2 (Group A) U (x 1 ;x 2 )=3lnx 1 +3 ln x 2

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Overview Definitions Mathematical Properties Properties of Economic Functions Exam Tips. Midterm 1 Review. ECON 100A - Fall Vincent Leah-Martin

(e) No matter what prices Sarah faces, the amount of money she needs to purchase a bundle indifferent to A must be (higher, lower) than the

1. The precise formula for the variance of a portfolio of two securities is: where

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY SPRING 2008 ECONOMICS 300/010 & 011 Midterm I March 14, 2008

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Income and Substitution Effects in Consumer Goods Markest

Intermediate Macroeconomics: Economics 301 Exam 1. October 4, 2012 B. Daniel

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Principles of Microeconomics Final Exam Wednesday, October 10th, 2007

Economics 502 April 3, 2008

Midterm #2 EconS 527 [November 7 th, 2016]

The supply function is Q S (P)=. 10 points

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Final Solutions ECON 301 May 13, 2012

b) The first secret of happiness is consuming on the Budget line, that is the condition That is

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Exam A Questions Managerial Economics BA 445. Exam A Version 1

Assignment 5 Advanced Microeconomics

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture X: Introduction to Game Theory

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

COMM 220 Practice Problems 1

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Kyunghun Kim ECN101(SS1, 2014): Homework4 Answer Key Due in class on 7/28

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

(0, 1) (1, 0) (3, 5) (4, 2) (3, 10) (4, 8) (8, 3) (16, 6)

Microeconomic Theory, Econ 323 Mostashari, Fall 2008 Exam 1 Version MAKEUP- KEY 50 minutes 100 Points Total. Name

Олимпиада НИУ ВШЭ для студентов и выпускников 2018 г. Направление: «Финансовая экономика»

Midterm 2 (Group A) U(C; R) =R 2 C. U i (C 1 ;C 2 ) = ln (C 1 ) + ln (C 2 ) p 1 p 2. =1 + r

EXTRA PROBLEMS. and. a b c d

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Please do not leave the exam room within the final 15 minutes of the exam, except in an emergency.

3. Other things being equal, a lump sum tax is at least as good for a consumer as a sales tax that collects the same revenue from him.

Consumers cannot afford all the goods and services they desire. Consumers are limited by their income and the prices of goods.

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible.

CS 798: Homework Assignment 4 (Game Theory)

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

Homework 1 Solutions

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Final Examination. Instructor: N. Schmitt

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 1 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2, Question 1

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis November 13, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 2

Transcription:

Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar. 2017 Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 201 1. The inverse demand function for apples is defined by the equation p = 214 5q, where q is the number of units sold. The inverse supply function is defined by p = 7 + 4q. (a) How many apples will be sold in equilibrium? Solutions: To find the number of apples sold, we equate the price paid by the buyers (p D ) and the pice received by the suppliers (p S ): 214 5q = 7 + 4q = 207 = 9q = q = 2. (b) A tax of $6 is imposed on suppliers for each unit of apples that they sell. How many apples will be sold after the tax is imposed? Solutions: In this case, the price received by the suppliers is $6 lower than the price paid by the consumers so that we have p S = p D 6 = 214 5q = 7 + 4q + 6 = 171 = 9q = q = 19. (c) A tax of $6 is imposed on consumers for each unit of apples that they buy. How many apples will be sold after the tax is imposed? Solutions: In this case, the price paid by the consumers is $6 higher than the price received by the suppliers so that we have p D = p S + 6 = 214 5q = 7 + 4q + 6 = 171 = 9q = q = 19. 2. On a tropical island there are 100 potential boat builders, numbered 1 through 100. Each can build up to 20 boats a year, but anyone who goes into the boat-building business has 1

to pay a fixed cost of $19. Marginal costs differ from person to person. Where y denotes the number of boats built per year, boat builder 1 has a total cost function c(y) = 19 + y. Boat builder 2 has a total cost function c(y) = 19 + 2y, and more generally, for each i, from 1 to 100, boat builder i has a cost function c(y) = 19 + iy. If the price of boats is 25, how many boats will be built per year? A builder will enter the market if it makes at least $0 profit. That happens when its average cost is lower than the price. For builder i to produce y units, its average cost is: AC i (y) = ci (y) y = 19 y + i. We notice two things about the average cost function: it is decreasing in y, and it is increasing in i. The first feature means that if a builder is to produce anything, he will produce the maximum number of units, which is 20, since producing more makes the average cost lower. The second feature means that if builder i is producing, then builder j with j < i is also producing, since j has a lower average cost. Hence we just need to find the highest i a boat builder produces, and the total supply is 20i. We need to have 19 20 + i 25 i 24 1 20. Hence the highest i is 24. The total supply is 20 24 = 480.. A monopolist is able to practice third-degree price discrimination between two markets, so it can charge different prices in the two markets and prevent resale. The demand function in the first market is q = 500 2p and the demand function in the second market is q = 1, 500 6p. The marginal cost is constant at c per unit of output. To maximize his profits, should he charge a higher price in the first market or the second market? 2

The monopolist will charge a price such that the marginal revenue is the same as the marginal cost in each market. For market 1, p 1 = 250 q 1 2 q 1 = 500 2p 1 T R 1 = p 1 q 1 = (250 q 1 2 )q 1 MR 1 = dt R 1 dq 1 = 250 q 1 = 250 500 + 2p 1 = 2p 1 250. For market 2, p 2 = 250 q 2 6 q 2 = 1500 6p 2 T R 1 = p 1 q 1 = (250 q 2 6 )q 2 MR 1 = dt R 1 dq 1 = 250 q 2 = 250 500 + 2p 2 = 2p 2 250. To maximize profit in both markets, we need to have MR 1 = MR 2 = c 2p 1 250 = 2p 2 250 p 1 = p 2. Hence, the monopolist needs to set the same price in both market. 4. Tina consumes apples (a) and butter (b). Apples cost p a and butter costs p b. Tina s

income is M. Her utility is given by u(a, b) = 2 ln a + ln b. (a) What is Tina s marginal rate of substitution between apples and butter? Tina s marginal rate of substitution between apples and butter is MRS = 2 a 1 b = 2b a. (b) Find Tina s optimal consumption bundle as a function of prices and income. Tina budget constraint is p a a + p b b = M. (1) Her optimal consumption bundle must satisfy Solve (5) and (6), we have MRS = 2b a = p a p b. (2) a = 2M p a b = M p b. (c) For apples, calculate Tina s price elasticity of demand. Tina s price elasticity of demand is ε p = 2M p 2 a p2 a 2M = 1. (d) What happens to Tina s demand for butter if p a doubles? When p a doubles, Tina budget constraint is 2p a a + p b b = M. () 4

Her optimal consumption bundle must satisfy Solve (5) and (6), we have MRS = 2b a = 2p a p b. (4) a = M p a b = M p b. Hence, TIna s demand for butter stays the same. (e) Now imagine that Tina is trapped on an island, with an allocation of 7 apples and lumps of butter. From now on, we assume that the price of apples is 1. The only income that Tina now gets is from selling her allocation of apples and butter. Calculate Tina s demand for butter as a function of p b. In this case, M = 7 + p b. Hence, Tina s demand for butter is b T = 7 + p b p b (f) Also on the island is Stanley. He has exactly the same preferences as Tina, but has 8 lumps of butter and 2 apples. Draw an Edgeworth box for this economy, and sketch both Tina and Stanley s indifference curves that pass through their initial endowment. (You need to label the axes, label the curves, and mark important points.) (omitted) (g) Write down Stanley s demand for butter as a function of p b. Stanley s income is 2 + 8p b. Hence, Stanley s demand for butter is b S = 2 + 8p b p b (h) What is the equilibrium price of butter in this economy? What are the equilibrium allocations for Tina and Stanley? 5

Tina and Stanley s demand for apples and butter are a T = 2(7 + p b) a S = 2(2 + 8p b) b T = 7 + p b p b b S = 2 + 8p b p b. Using the market-clearing condition, we have 2(7 + p b ) + 2(2 + 8p b) = 2(9 + 11p b) = 9. Hence, we have p b = 9 22 a T = 181 a S = 116 b T = 181 27 b S = 116 27. 5. Henry can work as many hours as he likes within a day at a wage rate of $40 per hour. Henry likes both consumption (C) and leisure (L), and leisure is defined as the hours within a day that he does not have to work. His utility function is given by: U(C, L) = C L The price of consumption is $1 and a day has 24 hours. (a) Suppose Henry has no other sources of income. Write down his budget constraint. Sketch his budget constraint, with leisure on the horizontal axis and consumption on the vertical axis. 6

Solution. His budget constraint is given by: C = 40 (24 L) = C + 40L = 960. Consumption 960 24 e (b) How many hours will Henry choose to work? Solution. By equalizing the MRS and the price ratio, we get: L C = 1 40 = C = 40L. Substitute that into the budget constraint, we get: C + C = 960 = 2C = 960 = C = 480. Hence, so that Henry will work: 480 = 40L = L = 12 24 L = 12 hours. (c) Now suppose that Henry s income gets taxed at 50% by the government. Write down his new budget constraint. Sketch his new budget constraint on another graph. 7

Solution. His new budget constraint becomes: C = 40(1 50%)(24 L) = C + 20L = 480. Consumption 480 24 e (d) How many hours will Henry choose to work? What is the substitution effect on leisure? What is the income effect on leisure? What is the total effect on leisure? Solution. By equalizing the MRS and the price ratio, we get: L C = 1 20 = C = 20L. Substitute that into the budget constraint, we get: C + C = 480 = 2C = 480 = C = 240. Hence, so that Henry will work: 240 = 20L = L = 12 24 L = 12 hours. Even though there is no change in the number of hours worked, it does not follow that both the income and substitution effects are zero. 8

If we want to make the old bundle (12, 480) affordable, his income needs to be: 20 12 + 480 = 720. At this compensated income, his budget constraint is: C + 20L = 720. By equalizing the MRS and the price ratio, we get: C = 20L = C + C = 720 = C = 60, L = 18 Hence the substitution effect increases L from 12 to 18, a change of 6 hours (since price for leisure goes down, he demands more leisure). In other words, the substitution effect DECREASES the number of hours worked by 6, and the income effect INCREASES the number of hours worked by 6 to get back to 12 hours. 6. Jennifer will earn income this period and next period and she needs to decide how much to consume this period and next period. She earns $200 in period 1 and $410 in period 2. The interest rate is constant at 10%. Her utility function is given by: u(c 1, c 2 ) = ln c 1 + 1 1.10 ln c 2, where c 1 and c 2 are her consumptions in period 1 and period 2, respectively. (a) Suppose Jennifer can save and borrow at the interest rate, 10%. What is Jennifer s intertemporal budget constraint? You do not have to simplify the expression. Jennifer s budget constraint is given by c 1 + c 2 1 + r = m 1 + m 2 1 + r = c 1 + c 2 1.1 = 200 + 410 1.1. (b) What is the optimal c 1, Jennifer s consumption in period 1? What about the optimal c 2, consumption in period 2? MRS Rule Approach: 9

Setting MRS equal to the price ratio, we have MU c1 = 1.1c 2 = 1.1 MU c2 c 1 1 = c 1 = c 2. (5) Plugging (5) into the budget constraint, we can solve for c 2 : c 2 + c 2 1.1 = 200 + 410 1.1 c 2 = 200 + 410 1.1 1 + 1 1.1 = 1.1 200 + 410 1.1 + 1 = 60 2.1 = 00. (6) Plugging (6) into the budget constraint: so that c 1 + c 2 1.1 410 = 200 + 1.1 = c 1 + 00 1.1 = 200 + 410 1.1 1.1c 1 + 00 = 1.1 200 + 410 = 1.1c 1 = 0 = c 1 = 00. Substitution Approach: From budget constraint, c 2 = (200 c 1 )1.1 + 410. Plugging (7) into utility function, u(c 1 ) = ln c 1 + 1 1.1 ln [(200 c 1)1.1 + 410]. 10

Then, take the first order condition (take the derivative and set to zero), u = 1 + 1 1.1 c 1 c 1 1.1 (200 c 1 )1.1 + 410 = 0 1 1 = = c 1 (200 c 1 )1.1 + 410 = c 1 = (200 c 1 )1.1 + 410 = 2.1c 1 = 200(1.1) + 410 = 60 = c 1 = 00 and plugging into the budget constraint, we also get c 2 = (200 c 1 )1.1 + 410 = (200 00)1.1 + 410 = 00. (c) Now suppose that Jennifer cannot borrow money from the future because no one is willing to lend her money. However, she is still free to save at an interest rate of 10%. What are the optimal choices for c 1 and c 2 now? Since Jennifer cannot borrow, we have the new constraint: c 1 m 1 = 200. And since the answer we found in part (b), c 1 = 00, was the only allocation that satisfied the first order condition and this allocation violates the new constraint, we know that our new constrained optimal bundle cannot satisfy the first order condition and hence has to be a corner solution. All we have to do is check the marginal utility with respect to c 1 at the corner (c 1 = 200). From before we had: u = 1 + 1 c 1 c 1 1.1 and plugging in c 1 = 200 we have 1.1 (200 c 1 )1.1 + 410. u = 1 c 1 200 + 1 410 > 0. So Jennifer would have more utility if she could consume marginally more c 1 than 200, but she cannot because she is credit constrained. However, this proves that setting c 1 = 200 is the best she can do and that leaves c 2 = 410. 11

7. Noah s utility function for money is given by u(x) = x. (a) What utility would Noah get if he received $100 for sure? What about if he had a lottery ticket that gave him $50 with a probability 2 and $200 with probability 1? Is Noah risk averse or risk loving? Noah s utility will be ū = 10 if he gets 100 for sure. For the lottery ticket, his expected utility is E(u) = 2 50 + 1 200 = 4 20 50 = 2 Note that the expected value of the lottery is $100, but so Noah is risk-averse. 20 2 < 10 (b) What is the variance of the outcomes of the lottery described in part (a)? The variance is 2 (100 50)2 + 1 (200 100)2 = 5000. (c) Noah s wealth is $90,000. However, he lives in Alaska, and there is a 1 6 probability that his house will be destroyed by a moose, which will cost his $50,000. Alternatively, he can buy insurance for an amount F, which will pay him $50,000 in the case of a moose destroying his house. What is the maximum amount (denoted by F max ) that Noah would pay for insurance? In order to solve for F max, we use Noah s indifference condition: Hence, we have 5 6 90000 + 1 6 90000 50000 = 90000 F max. ( ) 2 850 F max = 90000 = 87500. 9 12

(d) Following part (c), would the insurance company make positive or negative expected profit if it sold insurance at price F max? What is the least amount (denoted by F min ) that the insurance company would be willing to sell the insurance for (such that they make a non-zero profit)? The expected profit is 1 6 50000 + 87500 9 = 12500 9 > 0. The least amount that the insurance company would be willing to sell the insurance for is given by 1 6 50000 + F min = 0 = F min = 50000. 6 8. A small coffee company roasts coffee beans in its shop. The unroasted beans cost the company $2 per pound. The marginal cost of roasting coffee beans is $(150 10q+q 2 )/100 per pound when q pounds are roasted. The smell of roasting beans imposes costs on the company s neighbors. The total amount that neighbors would be willing to pay to have the shop stop roasting altogether is q2, where q is the number of pounds being roasted. 20 The company sells its output in a competitive market at $4.50 per pound. Assuming the coffee company owns the right to roast as much as they want, how much coffee will the company roast? What is the socially efficient amount of coffee for the company to roast? If the coffee company owns the right to roast as much as they want, they would roast to the point where MC = MR = p. We must have 150 10q + q 2 + 2 100 = 4.5 q 2 10q 100 = 0 q = 16.18 (we discard the negative root above) In order to be socially efficient, we need to take into account the social marginal cost, which is the sum of the private marginal cost and the externality marginal cost, which is 1

given by: d dq ( ) q 2 20 = q 10 Hence, we need 150 10q + q 2 100 + q 10 + 2 = 4.5 q 2 = 100 q = 10 (again, we discard the negative root) 9. Consider the market of used cars. p fraction of all used cars in the market are peaches and 1 p of them are lemon. Both sellers and buyers know the fraction p. There exists asymmetry in information on quality of cars: each seller knows the quality of the car which he sells, but buyers can not observe the quality of each used car. Assume that the value of a peach is $2000 for a seller and $2500 for a buyer and the value of a lemon is $1000 for a seller and $1500 for a buyer. (a) Derive the maximum price which a buyer will pay for a used car as a function of p. The expected value of a used car is 2500p + 1500(1 p) = 1500 + 1000p. This is the maximum price which a buyer will pay for a used car. (b) Derive the condition of p with which peaches will be sold in the market. Owners of peaches would be willing to sell their cars if 1500 + 1000p 2000 = p 1 2. (c) Describe the market situation clearly when the actual p does not satisfy the condition in (b). 14

If more than half of the cars in the market are lemons, that is, if p < 1, then owners 2 of peaches will not be willing to sell their cars so that the condition in (b) fails. (d) Now a seller of a peach offers a warranty which promises to pay the buyer some agreed upon amount if the car turned out to be a lemon. Explain how this warranty works as a signal. What is the equilibrium behavior of buyers and sellers given that the promised refund (if a car turns out to be a lemon) is sufficiently large? By offering the warranty, sellers of peaches are able to distinguish themselves from sellers of lemons. As long as the promised refund is sufficiently large, sellers of lemons will not be willing to offer this warranty because they would have paid the refund for each car they sell. In this way, since buyers know that only sellers of peaches are willing to offer this warranty, they are willing to pay a higher price. In the equilibrium, buyers are willing to pay $2500 if the seller offers a warranty, and only $1500 if the seller does not offer a warranty. In other words, sellers of peaches are able to signal their type by offering the warranty. 10. (Battle of the sexes) A couple can attend either a basketball game (B) or an opera performance (O) this evening. The husband would prefer basketball, while the wife would prefer opera. Both would prefer to go to the same place rather than different ones. If one goes to one s preferred place, he/she gets a payoff of while the other gets 2; if they can t agree, then they are going nowhere and both get 0. (a) Draw the payoff matrix. The payoff matrix is: Wife Basketball Opera Husband Basketball,2 0,0 Opera 0,0 2, (b) Identify all pure strategy equilibria, if any exists. The pure strategy (Nash) equilibria are (B,B) and (O, O). If either of the players changes behavior, he/she will get a lower payoff. (c) Identify all mixed strategy equilibria, if any exists. 15

We find the mixed strategy equilibrium by doing the following: for the husband, we let him play B with probability p and O with probability (1 p), so the wife will always get the same expected payoff regardless of what the husband does. The wife does so likewise. This will be a mixed strategy equilibrium, since given that the other player mixes the strategies in a way that it does not profit one player to change his strategy, he will not change his current strategy. From husband s point of view, what he needs is a p such that: 2p = (1 p) p = 0.6 The first equation needs a bit more elaboration. Given that the husband chooses B with probability p, if the wife chooses B, her expected payoff is 2p +0(1-p) = 2p, which is the LHS; if the wife chooses O, her expected payoff is 0p+(1 p) = (1 p), which is the RHS. 16